1 Introduction and Theoretical Underpinnings

This paper examines how banking supervisors influence credit at the local level—in our case the Italian geographical area defined by the province—by charging fines to banks in breach.

Enforcement actions by bank regulators—in our case the Bank of Italy (BI)—occur typically in the aftermath of on-site inspections and may include pecuniary fines, prompt corrective actions, temporary cease and desist orders, and moral suasion initiatives. Most of these measures are kept strictly confidential, while a few are publicly disclosed and available to researchers. We restrict the domain of enforcement actions to published pecuniary bank fines and estimate their overall effects on Italian provinces for the period 2005–2016. In contrast to previous bank-level studies, we use aggregate data to capture both the direct impact of the sanctioning process on the fined bank and the indirect effect emanating from other banks’ reactions. The latter is crucial for the analysis of the local credit market because with several banks serving the same local market, the indirect effect may dominate the direct one.Footnote 1 The macro approach, furthermore, offers two statistical advantages. First, it reduces the sample selection distortion and biased estimates resulting from severely unbalanced bank-level panel data. Second, it does not suffer from the efficiency loss due to the increase in the number of estimated variables and reduction in the number of usable observations that instead affect unbalanced bank-level panel data.

We hypothesize three transmission channels from pecuniary bank fines to provincial credit. The first is a balance sheet effect. Say an inspection reveals a breach in the classification of loans; the fine may come with a correction to shift some loans from the “good” category to the impaired loan category. The consequence of this action is an additional write-down due to the higher non-performing loans (NPL). If the bank absorbs the pecuniary fines charged to the management through higher compensation or more insurance protection, the cost of the fines affects the bank’s capital ratios and income account.

If, instead, the inspection reveals a systematic management strategy of supporting friendly “zombie” firms, the fine will generate effects that go beyond an accounting adjustment: the bank in breach will be obliged to reduce its loan portfolio to lower its risk-weighted asset indicator to restore the prescribed capital and financial ratios. This second transmission mechanism of asset repricing and resizing will be larger in provinces with a concentrated banking sector, and smaller in provinces with more competitive credit markets. The indirect effects of the fine will include the reaction of rival banks with similar asset allocation of the offending bank, but yet not found in breach by the regulator; the rival banks will be induced to act preemptively by making adjustments in the classification of loans and write-downs. In time, a more transparent credit procedure would promote a more diversified allocation of resources that, in turn, would raise bank efficiency and lead to an expansion of credit, for the same level of risk or a reduction of overall risk for the same level of credit. We call the second transmission mechanism the (provincial) reallocation effect.

The third transmission channel involves the role of borrowers. A sanctioned bank loses reputation; as a result, part of the demand for its loans is diverted elsewhere. If the market believes that the sanctioned practice is specific to the fined bank, the provincial loan supply will not change: the loss of credit suffered by the sanctioned bank will be compensated by the gain in credit supplied by other banks. But, if the market suspects that other banks may have followed the practice of the sanctioned bank, the provincial demand for credit would decline. We call this demand-side driven reaction to bank fines the reputational effect. In sum, we have three channels—balance sheet, reallocation, and reputation—that occur at different times after an inspection assessing a bank fine. With our annual data, we can disentangle the impact on provincial credit of each of the three distinct channels (through separate estimated coefficients), but not their timing sequence. In the empirical part of the paper, we will see that only the reallocation channel is statistically significant; the other two are not. Therefore, as a practical matter, the importance of the timing sequence of the three channels becomes less important.

The motivation for focusing on the Italian provincial credit market stems from the fact that the Italian economy, with its emphasis on small and medium-sized firms, is extremely dependent on bank credit: numerous small local banks and large national banks compete at the provincial level.Footnote 2 The spatial overlap of small local banks and national banks in the provincial credit markets provides a suitable environment to study the effects of bank fines and their spillovers along the lines outlined with the three transmission channels. On the other hand, bank competition in Italian provinces works against our hypothesis of the effectiveness of bank fines because credit supply adjustments tend to be smaller in competitive markets, whereas our hypothesis tests for their presence. Low pecuniary fines and high NPLs also work against our hypothesis because bank fines are spread over multiple provinces, which further reduce their impact on local credit supply, and the effects of the corrections to NPLs are harder to detect at the provincial level. Lastly, we use total loans as the dependent variable because the data on NPLs, our preferred choice, have many missing values.Footnote 3 As many accounting adjustments occur between good and impaired loans, it also works against our hypotheses. In brief, our hypothesis faces headwind forces; to the extent that Italy represents a tough case for our hypotheses, our findings are more likely to hold also in other, less competitive, environments.

The selection of the sample period was determined by data availability and institutional reforms. In particular, the starting year of 2005 coincides with a reclassification of accounting items; the choice of the terminal date of 2016 is due to the approval of three main institutional and legal reforms that altered the governance structure of popular and cooperative banks and reorganized the whole sanctioning process; see section II below.

This paper contributes to the related literature in several respects. The first is that our empirical results at the local credit market level refute the literature on the negative effects of enforcement actions on bank performance. Our findings are close to the most recent papers, such as Leuz and Granja (2019) and Hirtle et al (2019), corroborating that bank loans expand after a bank sanction. We find that provincial credit supply is sensitive to the frequency of fines, but not to the amount of the fines. The imposition of fines, after an initial change in loan classification, can induce sanctioned banks and other banks in similar situations to revisit their lending and risk management practices, in turn leading to credit reallocation and loan expansion. The second contribution is that the paper identifies three potential effects of bank fines on local credit—balance sheet effect, the reallocation effect, and the reputational effect—and suggests a specific empirical strategy to identify them. The third contribution recognizes that the reallocation effect is the dominant one, whereas no evidence was detected for the other two effects. Finally, the impact of bank fine frequency on provincial credit is sensitive to the size of the provincial banking sector, but not to bank governance or to the crisis period of 2008–2012.

Our findings have policy implications. Supervisors may differentiate the frequency of fines among different types of banking institutions. Italian regulators have historically made a distinction between one-member-one-vote mutualistic banks and larger national joint-stock banks (Giordano 2007). Our paper finds no evidence of a similar distinction in bank governance on the effects of supervision. Instead, breaches interact negatively and significantly with bank size, the implication being that provinces with a large bank sector require a higher frequency of bank fines than provinces with smaller bank sectors to offset the drag on provincial bank credit due to larger bank size. With an average provincial bank size of €4.1 billion, 80% of Italian provinces find that the positive effect of fine frequency on provincial credit is actually more than compensated by the negative impact on credit due to provincial bank size. Our simulation shows that if fine frequency were to rise by 25%, its positive impact on credit would dominate the negative impact due to bank size in all provinces. The inference is that the fine mechanism acts as a salutary monitoring device that spurs efficiency: bank supervision acts more as a good housekeeping seal of approval than as a policeman.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the literature. Section 3 describes the sanctioning process. Section 4 deals with the adopted methodological approach and hypotheses. Section 5 presents data sources and descriptive statistics. Section 6 discusses the empirical strategy and our findings. Section 7 deals with robustness checks and presents the results of a simulation exercise that evaluates the contrasting forces at work in the empirical findings. Conclusions are drawn in Sect. 8.

2 Related Literature

The literature on the effects of banking supervision on local credit markets is of relatively recent vintage and is not very extensive. We group studies according to our three transmission channels: the balance sheet effect, the reallocation effect, and the reputational effect.

A first strand of the literature takes a microeconomic perspective in analyzing the effects of bank supervision on bank performance. The empirical works typically focuses on supervisory output data, such as on-site inspections, and resulting formal enforcement actions, which estimate the effectiveness of bank supervision more precisely than earlier research based on supervisory input indicators. Using US data, Peek and Rosengren (1995) investigate the direct link between supervisory actions carrying civil penalties and the dynamics of loans in bank dependent sectors: banks subject to formal enforcement actions shrink credit activity at a faster rate than those with no enforcement actions. This is consistent with our balance sheet effect. Delis and Staikouras (2011) examine whether supervisors inspecting banks more regularly and adopting stricter enforcement are better positioned to restrain banks' risk-taking appetite, an issue we take up in our empirical work. The authors, in line with our balance sheet channel, find that the impact of on-site examinations on their measures of bank risk is non-linear with a relatively high threshold level of audits beyond which their relationship with risk becomes negative. Agarwal et al. (2014) note that stricter supervision in the US, due to the mandatory rotation between state and federal regulators, leads banks to deleverage and achieve higher capital ratios. Similarly, but for euro area banks, Eber and Minoiu (2016) study the effects of stricter supervision scrutiny on bank balance sheets and find that European banks adjust to stricter supervision by shrinking assets—especially securities—rather than raising capital. Based on a US sample, Delis et al. (2017) assess the effect of formal enforcement actions directly in relation to core financial safety and soundness. Their findings suggest that enforcement actions reduce risk-weighted assets, principally through less lending and NPLs.

A second strand of the literature follows an aggregated approach in analyzing the impact of supervisory actions on macroeconomic variables. Bassett et al. (2015) show that elevated supervisory stringency has a noticeable dampening effect on future lending activity. The authors estimate the relationship between changes in CAMELS ratings and changes in small businesses lending and find that small banks with rating downgrades during 2007–2010 exhibit lower lending growth to small businesses compared with banks with unchanged ratings. For Germany, Berger et al. (2016) show how supervisory actions disrupt liquidity creation. Danisewicz et al. (2017) use a macro approach to examine at the level of US counties how enforcement actions on banks and liquidity creation exert negative effects on per-capita income growth, the number of establishments and unemployment with the identified macro-financial linkages operating through reductions in bank lending. However, these adverse effects on the real economy seem to be temporary and typically last 1 year. Finally, analyzing the Italian case, Caiazza et al. (2018) focus on spillovers of enforcement actions on non-sanctioned banks under the assumption that sanctions serve the twin objectives of penalizing the offending banks and warning other banks. The authors find that credit risk-related fines assessed on Italian banks reallocate lending in a way that non-sanctioned banks tend to behave more similarly to sanctioned bank, evidence bearing on our reallocation effect channel.

Apart from the last paper, all cited studies tend to associate closer supervision with bank deleveraging and adopting tighter criteria in making new loans, a finding that tends to support the balance sheet effect, operating through significant asset resizing. Moreover, stricter supervision seems to have a disciplinary impact upon sanctioned banks through more effective market discipline, which in turn could trigger the reputational effect resulting from public disclosure of audits' findings and more transparent financial reporting.

The above negative relationship between enforcement actions and lending activity growth raises a welfare concern about the effectiveness of banking supervision: does stricter supervision have a negative effect on credit growth and economic activity? On this question, the literature is far from being conclusive. A few recent papers corroborate the prevalence of the reallocation effect over the balance sheet and reputational effect, suggesting that stricter supervision can boost credit growth. For example, Leuz and Granja (2019) show for the US that the transition from a more to a less tolerant supervision raises the amount of loans disbursed to small business, suggesting a positive value added by more demanding supervisors. Their findings also suggest that stricter supervision can overcome frictions in bank management and raise the amount of loans, indirect evidence in favor of the dominance of the reallocation effect. Echoing Leuz and Granja, Hirtle et al. (2019) underscore the positive contribution of supervision in mitigating banking sector risk. Exploiting the structure of the US supervisory system, the paper finds that Federal Reserve examiners spend proportionally more time at the largest banks in their district, and those banks hold less risky loan portfolios and are less sensitive to industry downturns, without experiencing adverse consequences on their growth or profitability. While the authors do not discuss the specific channel which may account for their findings, they posit that more attentive supervision may assuage principal-agent problems and hence promote a more careful risk-taking assessment. For example, a recent contribution by Bonfim et al. (2020) finds that on-site inspections of bank credit portfolios by Portuguese bank supervisors reduce future lending to "zombie" firms. This positive outcome, furthermore, lasts when inspectors are long gone. The implication is that either sanctioned banks learn from the supervisors or they take into account the threat and the costs of future inspections. Both explanations are consistent with the idea that on-site supervision can affect future bank lending decisions providing additional evidence of the role played by the reallocation effect.

Another successful impact from enforcement actions is provided by the analysis of the syndicated loans sector by Deli et al. (2019), where a causal effect emerges of financial penalties on the cost of borrowing: the cost of loans originated after a bank receives a fine is significantly lower compared to loans originated before the fine. This finding can be attributed to competitive and reputational effects: a fine makes the sanctioned bank less reputable and consequently may induce management to apply better lending terms to retain customers. According to the authors, this effect persists for about four years after the sanction has been levied and constitutes a strong welfare case for enforcement actions.

Our brief review of the literature highlights a variety of outcomes on the impact of enforcement actions on bank credit. We have seen that sanctions affect not only the behavior of the offending banks, but also that of the non-sanctioned banks. In our paper, the effects on these two groups of banks emerge indirectly because our key variable is provincial credit, where both sanctioned and non-sanctioned banks operate. In sum, whether less lenient supervision reduces or boosts lending and the economic activity remains an empirical issue. We note that, apart from Danisewicz et al. (2017), published papers have not analyzed the local aggregate impact of bank fines. Passalacqua et al. (2020) apply a diff-in-diff estimation to a proprietary (Bank of Italy) dataset on a subset of Italian banks, banche di credito cooperativo (BCC). Their working paper finds that bank inspections exert a negative, temporary, balance sheet effect on inspected banks (by forcing write-offs) and a positive reallocation spillover for healthy firms (by squeezing zombie lending). These results suffer, however, from identification and endogeneity problems that the authors mitigate by using bank subsamples, thus reducing the general validity of their findings.Footnote 4 Yet, the authors use the results on BCCs to provide a more general interpretation of their findings.

Our paper applies data from the Italian banking universe to a growth model of credit, and it estimates the overall impact of bank supervision on the real economy at the provincial level. By design, this approach does not suffer from selection bias because we consider all the banks. We address endogeneity issues with instrumental variables. Our work, in sum, intends to fill the gap in the literature on the connection between bank supervision and local (provincial) credit.

3 Institutional Background

BI is the supervisory authority of the Italian banking sector, jointly with the European Central Bank (ECB) since 2012. The sanctioning process of BI is regulated, at the primary level, by law and, at the secondary level, by various norms issued by BI.Footnote 5 Within this legal framework, BI has been empowered to levy administrative fines to banks in breach of regulations designed to protect the sound and prudent management of banking activity, the correctness and transparency of conduct, and the prevention of money laundering. The main entities subject to the sanctioning procedure are people in bank administration, management, and control, and auditing entities.Footnote 6

Recently, a major revision of the sanctioning process was undertaken at the European level. It started in July 2011 with the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) and the Capital Requirements Directive (CRD IV) and it was aimed at defining in more detail, among other things, the sanctioning process for banks. The maximum fines were set, in principle, at a dissuasive level, that is to nullify the incentive perpetrators may derive from a breach. The same objective was set for other measures, such as public reprimands, orders to cease, and temporary suspensions of functions. In May 2016, the Italian regulatory framework was made compatible with the European one, a change that has no direct bearing on our research given that 2016 is the end of our sample period.Footnote 7

We recall that Italy has a dual banking system, where a significant number of mutual banks coexist alongside few national banks. In addition to serving local markets, mutual banks differ from joint-stock banks in that their depositor-members can cast only one vote irrespective of the amount of their capital shares; so member-based governance is also another characteristics of mutual banks.

The two main groups of local banks are banche popolari (BP) and banche di credito cooperativo (BCC). A 2015 law restructured BPs to alter the traditional governance principle (Visco 2018). According to this law, BPs with total assets in excess of €8 billion had either to convert into a joint stock legal structure or reduce their size below €8 billion. A 2016 law restructured BCCs with the objective of increasing economies of scale and scope and improving the quality of management. Each BCC had the option of either becoming a joint-stock company (and thus give up the one-member-one vote governance) or joining a group of BCCs anchored to a joint-stock parent bank. The intent of the law was to engineer consolidation, risk diversification, and reduce opaque or friendly lending (Coccorese and Shaffer 2018). Both laws, whose draft proposals were debated for years, accelerated the process of bank consolidation through the formation of holding group structures.Footnote 8 The ensuing consolidation process was largely anticipated by banks and could have reduced differences in governance way before 2016.

Our paper focuses on the outcome of the supervisory process leading to fines levied by BI, the only information in the public domain. We collected data on pecuniary fines over the period 1998–2014 from the BI Monthly Supervision Bulletin and for 2015–2016 from BI's website. For each fine we also collected the monetary amount disaggregated by the area of infringement, and for sanctioned people. Breaches related to credit risk disclosure and management, internal controls, conflict of interest and governance were aggregated under the rubric of credit and credit-related violations (BC), whereas breaches related to money laundering, salary and compensation, transparency, and controls exercised by the Supervisory Board were grouped under the rubric of non-credit violations (BO). Our classification is somewhat similar to that by Caiazza et al (2018) but differs in that we have a more expansive list of breaches.Footnote 9 Furthermore, in our empirical work we treat fines both as dummy variables and pecuniary values, whereas Caiazza et al. (2018) use only dummy variables.

Our annual data do not allow to estimate the timing of the effects of our three transmission channels. However, the overall duration of the sanctioning process is crucial to determine the lag structure of the empirical model. Three factors are at play: the duration of the inspections culminating in a fine, the impact of the fine on the bank in breach, and the spillovers from the fined bank to other banks operating in a province. The duration of an inspection depends on various factors such as the type of inspection, its results, and the size of the bank. According to Passalacqua et al. (2020, p 14), on-site inspections last, on average, 66 days, but there is a great spread around this average. Within 90 days from the end of the inspection, inspectors submit their findings and observations to the management of the inspected bank. The recipients have up to 30 days to respond (BI 1999, Titolo VI, Capitolo 4, Sezione II). If the inspectors uncover a sanctionable infraction, BI has 90 days to notify the sanction to the bank and relevant parties; these are given 30 days to respond. The final decision on the sanction, taken by BI, can take up to 240 days (BI 1999, Titolo VII, Capitolo 1, Sezione II; BA 2012, Sezione II). The two procedures, inspection and sanctioning, can well stretch beyond a year. To that one must add the time related to the impact of the fine on the activities of the bank in breach and the time required for the spillovers to unfold from the bank in breach to other banks operating in a given province.Footnote 10 In sum, the timing of the effects of the three transmission channels across the inspection process, the bank in breach, and spillovers to other banks is such to justify a dynamic specification of our empirical model.

4 Methodology and Hypotheses

For our empirical investigation we use a credit model at the provincial level built around a standard economic growth model (Barro 1991; Mankiw et al 1992; King and Levine 1993; Levine et al 2000; Law and Singh 2014). The growth of gross provincial bank credit (ΔlnCRj,t) depends on the log of its lagged level (lnCRj.t-1), a demand factor given by the current growth of per-capita GDP (ΔlnYpcj,t) and a supply factor given by a set of lagged provincial control variables (CTRLj,t-1). These include a measure of bank liquidity captured by the ratio of bank liquidity to total bank assets (LRj,t-1), a measure of bank leverage captured by the ratio of total bank assets to bank equity (LEVj,t-1), a measure of bank concentration captured by the Herfindahl Index of bank branches in the province (HIj,t-1), and a measure of bank profitability given by the ratio of bank profits to bank total assets (ROAj,t-1).

According to different specification of the model, we augment our model to include a measure of bank fines frequency, BCn, and a measure of bank fines amount, BCa. The full model and the relative testable implications are summarized in the following equation:

$$ \Delta lnCR_{{j,t}} = \alpha _{0} + \alpha _{1} lnCR_{{j,t - 1}} + \alpha _{2} \Delta lnYpc_{{j,t}} + \alpha _{3} CTRL_{{j,t - 1}} + \theta _{t} + \mu _{j} + \varepsilon _{{jt}} \;\left( {{\text{base}}} \right) $$
(1a)
$$ ~~~~~~ + \gamma _{1} BCn~_{{j,t - 1}} + ~\gamma _{2} BCa~_{{j,t - 1}} + \gamma _{3} BCn~_{{j,t - 1}} \Delta lnYpc~_{{j,t}} \;\left( {{\text{HYP 1}} - {\text{3}}} \right)~~~ $$
(1b)
$$ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ + \delta _{1} BCn_{{j,t - 1}} X_{{jt}} + \delta _{2} BCa_{{j,t - 1}} X_{{j,t}} .\;\left( {{\text{HYP 4}} - {\text{5}}} \right)~~~ $$
(1c)

BCn works through a credit reallocation process: the bank is sanctioned because of risky and non-transparent practices skewed towards higher-risk loans. The discovery of the breach, followed by a fine, lowers the bank manager’s risk-taking preference and raises his or her incentive to achieve a more diversified, efficient, and transparent loan portfolio, i.e. with fewer loans to zombie firms. Other banks, in a similar situation, could preemptively adjust their loan portfolio to dodge a fine. The aggregate impact is affected by the distribution and exposure of banks operating in the provinces. The testable implication is that receiving fines has a positive impact on bank credit due to the reallocation effect; this is HYP 1: \({\gamma }_{1}>0\). Its alternative is that supervision is driven by political goals and aims at making zombie firms survive.

The second fine variable, BCa, acts as a pecuniary cost borne by the sanctioned bank. Even if the provincial impact is proportional to the exposure of the fined bank in a province, competing banks, in a similar situation, could also expect a fine and decide to raise pre-emptively reserves. The testable implication is that this cost has a negative impact on the bank’s balance sheet and hence on bank credit; this is HYP 2: \({\gamma }_{2}<0\). The alternative is that a fined bank takes more risk because it relies on an implicit safety net.

The third effect arises with the public losing trust in banking when an individual bank is fined. The stigma can either be limited to the sanctioned bank or generalized to other banks at the provincial level. In such a case, the banking system as a whole loses credibility and borrowers switch to other sources of financing. The testable implication is that bank credit will be less sensitive to a demand variable like Ypc and that the interaction between Ypc and bank fines will affect bank credit negatively; this is HYP 3: \({\gamma }_{3}<0\). The alternative is that the breach raises confidence and trust in the banking system because the “bad” bank was identified and punished. The three hypotheses appear in the second line of Eq. (1).

Finally, we test for possible asymmetric effects due to the dominance of different types of bank governance or bank size in the province. Differences between banks reflect the specific nature of mutual or community banks and large joint-stock banks. These two types of banks may differ in terms of governance: ownership staff management and board of directors are always locally based in the case of mutual banks (Fonteyne 2007; Kim and McKillop 2019) and size affects the capacity to obtain and process hard and soft information (Alessandrini et al 2010). Banks interaction at the provincial level could show aggregate effects beyond the bank level. HYP 4 tests whether the provincial impact of fines may be sensitive to bank size, measured as the logarithm of total credit, rather than to bank governance (see the third line of Eq. 1). In particular, our hypothesis is that fines to large banks are geographically less specific than fines to small banks; hence they send a weaker signal and have a smaller impact to the local credit market; this is HYP 4: \({\delta }_{1}<0\). Assuming that banks do not anticipate the reforms, HYP 5 proposes an alternative to HYP 4, namely that the provincial impact of fines discriminates between mutual banks (noSPA) and joint-stock banks (SPA). In this case, in sympathy with the extended literature on positive effects of mutual and community banks on local credit, our hypothesis is that bank fines to large banks have smaller negative effects on local credit; this is HYP 5: \({\delta }_{2}<0\).

In a nutshell, our null hypotheses can be summarized as follows:

Null Hypothesis

Description

HYP10:\({\gamma }_{1}>0\)

Reallocation effect hypothesis

HYP20:\({\gamma }_{2}<0\)

Balance sheet effect hypothesis

HYP30:\({\gamma }_{3}<0\)

Reputational effect hypothesis

HYP40:\({\delta }_{1}<0\)

Bank size hypothesis due to weaker local effects of large banks

HYP50:\({\delta }_{2}<0\)

Bank ownership hypothesis due to weaker local effects of joint-stock banks

5 Descriptive Statistics

Our dataset includes 989 supervisory interventions leading to 1930 pecuniary fines. Figure 1 shows the evolution of BC and BO expressed in euro amounts from 1998 to 2016. The early years, 1998–2004, display a relatively minor sanctioning activity; we omitted them from the sample. To arrive at a homogeneous sample, we chose 2005 as the starting year of our analysis because in that year a new accounting classification was introduced. In the same vein, we selected 2016 as the terminal year because relevant changes occurred in the legal banking framework (and institutional change in mutual banks’ governance and a new sanctioning process). As to the size of bank fines, Fig. 1 underscores that BC fines are higher than BO fines. The two series, on the other hand, are positively correlated. In the empirical work, we use BC as a determinant of bank credit, whereas BO is employed as an instrument to handle potential endogeneity between bank credit and BC. The intuition is that the absence of non-credit fines signals to the regulator a general disposition of legality in the banks operating in the province, whereas the absence of credit-related fines is a manifestation of legality in a specific sector.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Bank fines, 1998–2016

Concerning the remaining data, we drew accounting data of Italian banks from Associazione bancaria italiana (ABI). All data—accounting and fine data—have an annual frequency and were transformed from individual-bank data to provincial-level data. This transformation was done by multiplying balance sheet data for each bank by the ratio of its provincial branches to its total branches at the national level. The final dataset is obtained by summing each variable of interest at the provincial level; see Appendix for further details.

Tables 1 and 2 presents descriptive statistics both at the bank level and at the provincial level respectively. In Table 1 (bank level), the first five variables –credit, liquidity, total assets, equity and profits– are in thousands of euros whereas the next three variables are ratios; LR is liquidity as a ratio of total assets, LEV is leverage measured as total assets divided by equity; ROA is return on assets. The next group of variables—SPA, noSPA, BCC, BP and CRISIS—are dummy variables. In particular, CRISIS is a dummy equal to 1 from 2008 to 2012 capturing both the great financial crisis and the Italian debt crisis. The final group of variables reports credit-related and non-credit related fines in euros.

Table 1 Bank-level descriptive statistics, sample 2005–2016
Table 2 Provincial-level descriptive statistics, sample 2005–2016

Some aspects of the statistics are worth mentioning. ROA is extremely low with a mean value of 0.22%. Its distribution is extremely wide, ranging from a minimum of – 66.9% to a maximum of 19.3%; there is a high number of outliers and the frequency distribution has a left tail. Regarding the corporate structure, 70% of Italian banks are either credit cooperative banks or popular banks; the remainder 30% are joint-stock banks. Bank fines average €7032 for credit-related breaches and €1700 for non-credit related breaches. The highest bank fine in the sample was €7,154,200. These amounts appear, at first sight, to be too small to expect a significant material impact on bank behavior. Our fine variable has a high number of outliers and its frequency distribution is leptokurtic.

Table 2 presents descriptive statistics at the provincial level. The number of observations in most cases is 1293. The first five variables of the table are provincial data collected by ISTAT: per-capita GDP (Ypc); the net number of firms in the Chamber of Commerce registry (Firm_ENR); the labor participation rate (Partrate); the share of cooperative firms as a proxy of social capital (Cooprate); the number of thefts (Robrate). All other variables are obtained by the noted transformation from bank-level data to provincial data using our weighting scheme based on shares of banks’ provincial branches. In particular, BCa is the amount of the provincial euro pecuniary fine for credit-related breaches. Its average is €37,494 and its median its €3404 implying that few provinces receive relatively high fines, while most are penalized with extremely low euro amounts; cf. the values of the kurtosis, 330.6, and skewness, 14.60. BCn gives a continuous number ranging from 0 to 1: individual bank-in-credit-breach dummy values are summed over all banks with weights based on branch shares. BCn = 1 would occur if all banks operating in a given province receive a fine. In our sample, the highest provincial value for BCn is 0.81; most values are below the average; cf. the kurtosis,12.24, and skewness, 2.48.

6 Empirical Strategy and Results

Our empirical strategy goes as follow. We estimate Eq. (1) first with fixed time and provincial effects (FE) and then with fixed effects and instrumental variables (FEIV) applying two-stage least squares (2SLS) so as to address endogeneity problems.Footnote 11 Three right-hand side variables of Eq. (1) potentially suffer from endogeneity: per-capita income, Ypc, and the two measures of fines, BCn and BCa. Income and credit are positively related. When income starts growing credit tends to move in the same direction, but it is also the case that when credit grows income follows. Hence, we cannot exclude bidirectional causality. A similar argument applies to the relationship between credit and credit-related fines. While the paper starts with the premise that BC has an impact on CR, one cannot exclude that, as business conditions and credit deteriorate, supervisors increase their activity and discover more breaches. After all, deficiencies and malfeasance tend to emerge especially in times of distress. We treat the endogeneity issue by utilizing four sets of instruments in the first stage. As in Danisewicz et al. (2017), we include as instrument the non-credit related fines. The reason, as mentioned previously, is that, in addition to following the literature, BO signals the banking legal provincial disposition. We also add indicators of business activity, indicators of social capital, and indicators of criminal activity, all at the provincial level. These variables capture the ease with which one can start and maintain a business in a specific province, a factor that influences the local demand for credit. Apart for the non-credit related fines, the choice for the other instruments was dictated by data availability. Potentially better instruments lacked sufficient coverage or were unavailable at the provincial level. Furthermore, other instruments with a sufficient data coverage turned out to be statistically insignificant and failed to pass basic IV tests; or, if they marginally passed them, the estimated coefficients were not different from those obtained under fixed effects. Our instruments pass endogeneity test (Wooldridge 1995), reject overidentification test (Sargan 1958), and show statistically significant estimated coefficients. For brevity, we report only FEIV estimates using instruments that: (i) have a sufficient data coverage in term of years and provinces (i.e. data availability); (ii) pass basic IV tests suggesting that FEIV estimates are better than straight FE estimates; and (iii) generate statistically significant coefficients that are different from those estimated by FE estimates. In sum, FEIV estimates are more efficient and consistent than FE estimates, but we report both for comparison purposes. We follow the standard procedure to use the residuals of the first stage as regressor in the second stage equation.

Table 3 shows the estimate of Eq. (1) using bank size as the heterogeneity discriminant (i.e., HYP 1–4). Estimates are run under the assumption that banks anticipate the reforms on mutual banks and adjust pre-emptively. The first five columns of the table refer to FEs estimations and the second three refer to FEIV estimations. Column 1 displays the regression of the standard growth model: lnCRt – 1 is negative and highly significant; the impact of demand, ΔlnYpc, is positive with marginal statistical significance; liquidity (LRt – 1), concentration (HIt – 1), and ownership (SPA) are three among bank supply factors that are statistically significant. Column 2 shows that the provincial fine frequency, BCnt – 1, has the expected positive impact on the growth of provincial credit (HYP1), while the provincial pecuniary fine, BCat – 1, exerts the opposite effect on the growth of provincial credit (HYP2). On the other hand, ΔlnYpc vanishes in statistical significance. Column 3 shows that there are no reputational effects (HYP3). Column 4 tests for asymmetries due to differences in bank size (HYP4). These asymmetric effects cannot be rejected when bank size (lnCRt – 1) interacts with the frequency of bank fines (BCnt – 1) but are rejected when bank size interacts with the pecuniary fine. These findings are consistent with the proposition that the frequency of breaches is doing the bulk of the work, by triggering a strong “positive” credit adjustment mitigated by a minor “negative” credit adjustment due to the interaction with the bank size; on the other hand, the puny size of the fine does not affect bank behaviour. Column 5 adds reputational terms to the specification of column 4. These terms are not statistically significant; in contrast, the significance of the bank-size asymmetries is confirmed.

Table 3 Impact of bank fines on local credit; asymmetries due to bank size

Columns 6 through 8 display the corresponding FEIV regressions of the FE regressions of columns 3 through 5. The number of endogenous variables ranges from five of column 6 to seven of column 8; the number of exogenous variables ranges is 15. While there is a clear case of over-identification, the Sargan’s test shows that the additional instruments are valid: the endogeneity test passes the hurdle. The key outcome is that the FEIV estimation corroborates the FE estimation. The asymmetric effects due to bank size are restricted to the frequency of breaches; the pecuniary fine appears to be irrelevant: all the BCa coefficients are statistically insignificant (see column 7). When fine variables are combined with reputational terms, the latter vanish, and the former remain significant at the 5% level (see column 8). Table 3 can be summarized as follows: fine frequency triggers credit reallocation that are sensitive to bank size; pecuniary fines are irrelevant, for which the best explanation is that fines are too small to do the job they are intended to do.

Table 4 considers asymmetries due to bank ownership (HYP5). It implicitly assumes that banks are unable to correctly predict the consequences of reforms on mutual banks or that these reforms are not credible. The structure of the table is similar to Table 3, except that the first two specifications are omitted for brevity. Bank ownership is identified by the two dummy-based variables, SPA and noSPA that interact with BCnj,t-1 and BCaj,t-1. As SPA and noSPA are complementary by design, of the triplet BCnj,t-1, BCnj,t-1*SPA, and BCnj,t-1*noSPA, and the corresponding triplet involving BCaj,t-1, only two are independent. In Table 4, we have dropped the fine variable from the triplet. Therefore, the interaction terms capture the combined direct effect of the fine variable and the indirect effect through the interaction with SPA or noSPA. In column 1, with FE estimation, BCnj,t-1*SPA exerts a positive impact on provincial credit growth, whereas BCaj,t-1*noSPA pulls in the opposite direction. The interaction terms have high statistical significance. On the other hand, the corresponding interaction terms with noSPA are not statistically significant at the 10% confidence level. Column 2 adds the reputational term, which is statistically irrelevant. The story changes sharply under FEIV estimations in Columns 3 and 4, in the sense that none of the four interaction terms are statistically significant.Footnote 12 The economic and statistical significance of bank fines disappears when banks are distinguished according to type of ownership and governance. The popular notion that breaches and fines penalize unduly community banks is not confirmed with this dataset.

Table 4 Impact of bank fines on local credit; asymmetries due bank ownership

In sum, breaches exert an impact on credit reallocation through the signal emanating from its frequency and working through the size of the bank.

7 Robustness Checks and Counterfactual Exercises

In this section, we present some robustness checks and two counterfactual exercises that simulate the effects of changes in the frequency of fines and in the size of the provincial banking sector. On robustness of our findings, we perform two econometric exercises. The first consists of adding to specification (1) an additional bank supply variable, the return on assets (ROA). In the second, we add the crisis dummy variable CRISIS, which is equal to one for the years 2008 through 2012. We recall from our discussion of descriptive statistics that a key characteristic of Italian banks was a very low level of efficiency (profitability). ROA has a sample average of 0.22% and a frequency distribution spanning from a minimum of – 67.9% to a maximum of 19.8%. As to CRISIS, Italy was particularly penalized by the Great Recession of 2008–2009 and the subsequent sovereign debt turmoil (Bofondi et al 2018). The CRISIS dummy replaces time dummies. In sum, both ROA and CRISIS are good candidates for a robustness exercise.

In Table 5, the 1-year lag of ROA is added in Model 3 and Model 4 of Eq. (1). Model 3 includes the core specification, the two fine variables, and the asymmetries due either to bank ownership or bank size; model 4 adds the reputational term to model 3. The models are estimated, as in the previous two tables, first with FE and then with FEIV. The key result of the table is that ROA does not alter the findings of Tables 3 and 4. ROA then is replaced with CRISIS in Table 6. The difference between the two tables is that CRISIS is very significant, whereas ROA is not. For the rest, the two tables corroborate the findings of Tables 3 and 4.

Table 5 Robustness analysis: adding ROA
Table 6 Robustness analysis: adding CRISIS

For the counterfactual scenario, we use the estimate of column 7 in Table 3 to simulate the impact of the statistically significant fine variables on provincial bank credit. We prefer column 7–8 because its specification is more parsimonious. For the simulation, we change the fine frequency, BCn, by ± 25% and the provincial banking sector size, CRj,t-1, by ± 50%. We then calculate the average marginal effects under each scenario. The purpose of the exercise is to compare the two opposing forces acting on provincial bank credit, the push of fine frequency and the pull of bank size. Figure 2 displays nine maps of Italian provinces; the maps code changes in provincial credit according to three colours and their intensity: green for a positive change, white for no change, and red for a negative change. For each row, as we move from west to east provincial bank size changes (– 50%, 0, + 50%), for a given provincial fine frequency. For each column, as we move from north to south, provincial fine frequency changes (– 25%, 0, + 25%), for a given provincial bank size. The key result is that as we move from the center map (row 2, column 2) to the north eastern map, the color changes from white to predominantly red, and as we move from the center map to the south western map, the color changes to predominantly green. A change in the number of fines exerts an amplification effect on provincial lending activity. This result is in line with Rezende and Wu (2014) who find that, given the minimum frequency of examinations required by US regulation, those banks that are exempted from examination show lower profitability resulting from increasing loan losses and delinquencies. In essence, an increase in provincial bank credit can be obtained by raising the frequency of bank fines; it supports the notion that fines act more like a good housekeeping seal of approval than a penalty on the banking sector.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Simulations of the impact of bank fines, annual average 2005–2016. Low Frequency = -25%; High Frequency =  + 25%. Smaller Bank Size = − 50%; Larger Bank Size =  + 50%. Same Frequency, Same Bank Size represents predicted values of column (7) of Table 3

Figure 3 shows the provincial distribution of the impact of bank fines. The left panel of the figure, based on the estimate of column 7 in Table 3, shows that given the existing local banking sector size, the impact of fine frequency on provincial credit is negative in about 83% of Italian provinces. Everything else equal (in particular bank size), a 25% increase in BCn would shift the distribution sufficiently to the right by making a positive increase in provincial bank credit in all provinces. In sum, fine frequency has a sizeable economic impact on provincial credit.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Impact of bank fines on provincial credit, annual average, 2005–2016

8 Conclusions

Fines are an important enforcement mechanism of bank supervision, and naturally one would expect that they would exert an impact on the credit market. Yet, these actions have received scarce attention in the literature. This paper has examined the nexus between bank fines and provincial bank credit. Theoretically, fines trigger a reputational effect on the demand for credit, and credit reallocation and balance sheet effects on the supply side. Using a dataset of Italian banks over the period 2005–2016, we estimate these effects using a fixed effect model and instrumental variables to remove potential endogeneity problems. The three testable implications are: a negative effect on provincial bank credit due to pecuniary fine reducing banks’ net income; a positive effect on provincial bank credit due to fines triggering a more efficient and transparent resource allocation; and a reduction of provincial bank credit due to a stigma effect associated with a bank fine. Our key findings are that provincial total bank loans expand following the decision of a fine but are insensitive to the size of the fines.

Compared with the findings in the literature, the novel result of our paper is that bank fines can induce changes in bank management that streamline and increase lending activity at the provincial level. Furthermore, the impact of bank fine frequency on local credit is sensitive to the size of the provincial banking sector but not either to differences in types of bank governance/ownership or to the crisis period of 2008–2012. One explanation for the insensitivity to bank governance/ownership is that banks may have anticipated the policy reforms of 2016. Finally, we find no evidence of either reputational or other balance sheet effects. Our policy recommendation is that it would behoove bank supervisors to raise the frequency over the size of bank fines. The latter seem to work more like a good housekeeping seal of approval, enhancing transparency and effective banking practices, and less like a penalty.