1 Introduction

Network industries are among the fastest-developing sectors of advanced modern economics. Typical examples of network goods are telephone and software: it is natural to observe that the utility of a particular consumer from using a telephone or a piece of software increases with the number of other telephone or software users. The large-scale expansions of mobile devices such as smartphones and tablets exemplify the increasing significance of those industries in day-to-day life.Footnote 1

In general, network goods are products in which the utility derived by one consumer/user increases with the number of other consumers/users of those goods, that is, the total sales of the goods enhance the welfare of each consumer (Katz and Shapiro 1985; Amir and Lazzati 2011). In addition, the number of other consumers/users of the product may directly affect the demand for the network goods also because it may speak for the product quality and availability of after-sale services for long-lasting consumers. Therefore, the consumers’ expectations about the total sales of the goods may in principle be affected by different mechanisms of output decisions and different production costs and thus by different labour market institutions.

Indeed, a central issue of labour market institutions in advanced economies is the selection of the bargaining agenda between firms and unions. Because of the interconnections between labour and product markets, the subject takes on considerable importance both for labour economics and industrial organization. The unionised firm literature presents the classical result that, when firms bargain only over wage and choose employment, i.e. according to the right-to-manage (RTM) model (e.g. Nickell and Andrews 1983), profits are higher than when they bargain also over employment, either simultaneously as in the efficient bargaining (EB) model (e.g. McDonald and Solow 1981) or sequentially as in the sequential efficient bargaining (SEB) model (Manning 1987a, b).

Dowrick (1990) first analysed the issue of the more profitable negotiation agenda in the context of unionised industries; this author has found “that profits under the Right-to-Manage model exceed those under Efficient Bargaining” (Naylor 2003, p. 59). Moreover, the negotiation outcomes of the RTM and SEB agendas have also been compared, and the conventional result of the established literature argues that “under unionized monopoly, the firm will prefer to keep employment off the bargaining agenda, whatever the degree of union influence over employment. In other words, the Right-to-Manage outcome generates higher profits than either the efficient or sequential bargains, for a given level of union influence over the wage” (Naylor 2003, p. 61). This is true particularly regarding a unionised monopoly in which strategic competitive effects are absent and thus wage costs (depending on the specific alternative bargaining arrangements) can never be used as a strategic device. Here, we first consider the monopoly case in which the network effects on the preference of the agenda cannot be obfuscated, with regard to the firm, by indirect strategic competitive effects.Footnote 2 Second, we analyse the case of monopoly with the threat of entry in which the network effects influence the preference of the agenda also through the strategic effects due to potential competition in both the product and labour markets.

The effects of firms’ strategic interaction and market entry on preferences over the bargaining agenda have been recently investigated by Bughin (1999), Vannini and Bughin (2000), Buccella (2011), (Fanti 2014, 2015) and Fanti and Buccella (2015). Moreover, it is natural to think that the choice of bargaining agenda may exert some influence on the behaviour of incumbents and entrants, although the investigation of this theme is rather scant. Nonetheless, the link between the presence of labour unions and the market structure and, consequently, the market entry, is rather relevant both on empirical (e.g. Chappell et al. 1992)Footnote 3 and theoretical grounds. In fact, from a theoretical perspective, a few articles have dealt with the presence of labour unions and entry such as Dewatripont (1987, 1988a, b), Ishiguro and Shirai (1998), Pal and Saha (2008), Mukherjee and Wang (2013). However, none of them have studied the choice of the bargaining agenda as an entry deterrence tool. Exceptions are Bughin (1999), Buccella (2011) and Fanti and Buccella (2015), in which the result that RTM dominates EB can be considered to be conventional in the pure monopoly, while in a monopoly with threat of entry, EB is predominant as a Nash equilibrium.

However, despite their relevance, all of those authors abstract from the possibility that goods in unionised industries present positive consumption externalities. Indeed, the presence of network effects is not innocuous. For instance, a recent growing body of literature has shown that network externalities may alter many established results of the industrial organization literature obtained basically by assuming non-network goods, especially in relation to oligopolies with managerial delegation (e.g. Hoernig 2012; Bhattacharjee and Pal 2014; Chirco and Scrimitore 2013).

The paper aims to consider the impact of the network effects on the preferences over the bargaining agenda first in the pure monopoly case (i.e., in the short run in the absence of firm competition) and then, in the long run, on the monopoly with the threat of entry when the strategic effects of potential competition are taken into account. In particular, the present paper attempts to answer the following questions: does the conventional result, that under pure monopoly a firm always prefers RTM to EB and SEB (with a corresponding conflict of interests between firm and union), hold true in the presence of network effects? What happens if there is the threat of market entry in the industry? May the incumbent still strategically select the EB agenda to deter entry? What are the consequences in terms of social welfare? The answers to these questions reveal that network effects may alter the established results of the previous literature.

As regards monopoly, our novel findings show that network effects matter. In fact, in contrast to the established result that a monopolist always prefers RTM, a SEB agreement is preferred, provided that the network effects are sufficiently intense (and the union’s bargaining power is not too high). Because the union and consumers always prefer the SEB agenda, the presence of network effects may solve the traditional conflict of interests between parties and achieve a Pareto-superior societal outcome.

We identify the following three effects of the network externalities related to the analysis of entry. First, when these externalities are sufficiently strong, the entry deterrence effect is always weakened, regardless of the bargaining agenda and the size of the fixed costs the entrant has to face. Second, as network externalities intensify, the entry deterrent agenda shifts from EB/SEB (in the case of low/high fixed costs of entry) to RTM. Third, for sufficiently high union bargaining power, a no univocal role of the network effect emerges. In fact, on the one hand, the presence of network effects allows the exploitation of the bargaining agenda for medium values of the network intensity; on the other hand, both relatively low and high values of the network effect facilitate the elimination of the agenda as a barrier to entry.

With regard to social welfare, the main results are as follows. The duopoly under the SEB agenda is always the most preferred bargaining institution from the society viewpoint. Nonetheless, the possibility that the bargaining agenda can be used as an entry deterrence tool impedes the achievement of the first-best social welfare. In this case, the role of the network effect is extremely various. In fact, if the intensity of the network is extremely high, the achievement of the desirable social welfare outcome is possible. However, if the network effect is of medium intensity, the entry is more likely to be deterred under the RTM agenda, which leads to the unwelcome result of reaching the least social welfare level.

Moreover, a number of testable hypotheses emerge from our analysis. In industries with sizable network externalities: (1) without the threat of entry, monopolists should prevalently choose an efficient bargaining arrangement, and (2) in the case of threat of entry: (2.1) when unions are strong, more competitive market structures should be prevalent both for low and high network effects; on the other hand, if the network effects are sufficiently strong but not too strong, a monopolistic structure should be relatively more often present, irrespective both of the size of the fixed costs and the type of bargaining agenda; (2.2) when unions are not strong, a monopolistic structure should be less common when network effects are very strong; and (2.3) the RTM should be the predominant bargaining agenda, especially when the fixed costs of entry are high.

The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the basic monopoly-union bargaining model. Section 3 analyses the issue of potential entry and discusses the welfare implications. Finally, the last section summarises the main results and suggests directions for further research on the subject.

2 The Model

The simple mechanism of network effects here assumed is that the surplus that a firm’s client obtains increases directly with the number of other clients of this firm (i.e. Katz and Shapiro 1985). Following Hoernig (2012), Battacharjee and Pal (2014) and Chirco and Scrimitore (2013), the monopolist firm faces the following linear direct demand:

$$\begin{aligned} q=a-p+ny \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where q denotes the quantity of the goods produced, y denotes the consumers’ expectation about monopolist’s equilibrium production,Footnote 4 and the parameter \(n\in [0,1)\) indicates the strength of network effects (i.e., the higher the value of the parameter the stronger the network effects). The inverse demand function is:

$$\begin{aligned} p=a-q+ny \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where p is the price of goods. The monopolist’s profit function is:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi =(p-w)q, \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where w is the wage per unit of output.

The efficient bargaining may be either simultaneous over wage and employment (EB) (McDonald and Solow 1981) or sequential, first over wage and then over employment (SEB) (Manning 1987a, b). In the cases of RTM and SEB, monopolist’s decisions are made in two stages. In the first stage, in the cases of both RTM and SEB, the monopolist-union unit bargains over wages w to maximise the Nash product. Then, following Katz and Shapiro 1985 and the above mentioned literature, we impose the additional “rational expectations” conditions, that is, consumers fulfil their expectations at equilibrium (i.e. \(y= q)\), in the second stage. In the third stage (1) with RTM, the monopolist chooses the quantity q (alternatively, the price p) to maximise profits and (2) with SEB, the monopolist-union unit negotiates over the quantity q (alternatively, the price p) to maximise the Nash product. On the other hand, under EB, the monopolist-union unit bargains simultaneously over wages w and quantity q to maximise the Nash product. As usual, our equilibrium concept is the subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium, and we solve this game using the backward induction method. Figure 1 summarises the timing of the game for each bargaining arrangement.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Timing of the game, monopoly

The union utility function is \(V=(w-w^{\circ })l\) (e.g. Pencavel 1985), where l is employment and w \(^{\circ }\) the reservation wage. Given the standard assumption of constant returns to labour, \(q=l\), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} V=(w-w^{\circ })q. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

The bargaining solution is modelled by the following generalized Nash product

$$\begin{aligned} N=( \pi )^{1-b}( V)^b. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Using Eqs. (1)–(4) and solving the Nash product in Eq. (5), direct computations produce the expressions in Table 1. The Appendix provides the extensive derivations.

Based on the equilibrium outcomes for the alternative bargaining agendas in Table 1, we analyse the impact of the network effects in consumption.

Table 1 Monopoly outcomes under the three bargaining agendas

Result 1 In a network industry:

the monopolist always prefers to bargain sequentially rather than simultaneously in the case of efficient bargaining. Moreover, it

  1. 1)

    prefers SEB rather than RTM provided that the network effect is sufficiently high, and the lower the union’s power, the more likely a monopolist will be to prefer SEB;

  2. 2)

    as expected, the union always prefers SEB rather than RTM. Otherwise, it may prefer SEB rather than EB, provided that its union’s power is high enough.

Proof

Given the outcomes in Table 1, we have:

  1. 1)

    \(\Delta \pi ^{RTM/SEB}=(\pi ^{RTM}-\pi ^{SEB})=\frac{b(b-n(2-n))(2-b)^2(a-w^{\circ })^2}{4(2-n-b)^2(2-n)^2}\) from which it is directly obtained that \(\Delta \pi ^{RTM/SEB}\frac{<}{>}0\;\Leftrightarrow \;1>n>n_1 =1-\sqrt{1-b} \); or, equivalently, that \(\Delta \pi ^{RTM/SEB}\frac{<}{>}0\;\;\Leftrightarrow \;1>b>b_1 =1-(1-n)^2\), with \(\frac{\partial n_1 }{\partial b}>0\), \(\frac{\partial b_1 }{\partial n}>0\). It follows that the monopolist’s profit ranking is as follows: \(\pi ^{RTM}>\pi ^{SEB}\ge \pi ^{EB}\;\,\) \(if\;n=0; \quad \pi ^{RTM}>\pi ^{SEB}>\pi ^{EB} \quad if\;b>1-(1-n)^2;\pi ^{SEB}\ge \pi ^{RTM}>\pi ^{EB} \quad if\;b\le 1-(1-n)^2\);

  2. 2)

    \(\Delta V^{RTM/SEB}<0;\;\Delta V^{EB/SEB}\frac{>}{<}0\;\Leftrightarrow b\frac{<}{>}\frac{2(2-n)}{4-n}\). It follows that the union utility ranking is: \(V^{SEB}\ge V^{EB}>V^{RTM}\;\, \quad if\;b\ge \frac{2(2-n)}{4-n};\) \(V^{EB}>V^{SEB}>V^{RTM}\;\, \quad if\;b<\frac{2(2-n)}{4-n}\).

Corollary 1

When network effects are sufficiently intense, the monopolist and the union agree on the SEB agenda.

Proof

From Result 1, it directly follows that, if \(1-(1-n)^2\ge \;b\ge \frac{2(2-n)}{4-n}\), the monopolist and the union prefer the SEB agenda. \(\square \)

Lemma 1

RTM and SEB wages are equal and lower than EB wages. Moreover, RTM and SEB wages are independent on n, while EB wages are increasing with n.

Proof

By simple inspection of the expressions for \(w^{RTM}\), \(w^{SEB}\) and \(w^{EB}\) in Table 1. \(\square \)

Result 1 and Lemma 1 contrast with the case of goods with no network effects in which the monopolist always gains larger profits with RTM rather than SEB and EB (Dowrick 1990), and profits under efficient bargaining are the same, regardless of whether the timing is sequential or simultaneous (Naylor 2003).

The economic intuition behind the above findings is that, in the presence of network externality, the profits with SEB are higher than EB, because the consumers’ expectations on the market size are not “known” when the wage is bargained at the first stage; thus, the SEB wage is independent of n. On the other hand, in the EB game, where the wage and employment are concurrently determined, the consumers’ expectations are so far realised, and the externality effect has a positive impact on the bargained wage. The economic rationale for this positive effect can be explained as follows. In contrast to SEB and RTM, under EB, the union knows the output (and, therefore, the employment) level inclusive of the externality effect on consumption. This is because consumers’ expectations are already realised when the wage is negotiated. As the consumption externality is simply the employment level itself (multiplied by n), then the union is able to negotiate a higher wage because the employment level is higher due to the network effect. Of course, the higher n is, the higher the employment and, thus, the bargained wage. As a consequence, it follows that \(w^{EB}>w^{SEB}\).

Figure 2 graphically illustrates Part 1 in Result 1, which reverses the conventional result with regard to the preferred agenda by firms and is worth to be commented more in detail. At first glance, the finding that \(\Delta \pi ^{RTM/SEB}\frac{<}{>}0\) seems to be puzzling, because \(w^{RTM}=w^{SEB}\) while \(q^{RTM}<q^{SEB}\). Moreover, it is also valid that \(p^{RTM}>p^{SEB}\) in the [n,b]-space. Closer analytical inspection reveals that the monopolist, in equilibrium, produces at a point on the demand curve where the price elasticity of demand is larger under RTM than SEB, that is, \(\varepsilon ^{*RTM}(n,b)>\varepsilon ^{*SEB}(n,b)\). Depending on the values of [n,b], the elasticity (and mark-up) differential may increase or decrease; as a consequence, the price effects may dominate or not the quantity effects on the monopolist revenues. Figure 2 tells us that when \(\Delta \pi ^{RTM/SEB}>( <) 0\), the price effect dominates (is dominated by) the effect on quantity variation.Footnote 5

Result 2 Consumers and society always prefer SEB rather than EB and RTM.

Proof

Simple comparison of the payoffs in Table 1 leads to the following rankings: \(CS^{SEB}>CS^{EB}>CS^{RTM}\Leftarrow \;n>0;SW^{SEB}>SW^{EB}>SW^{RTM}\Leftarrow \;n>0.\) \(\square \)

Result 3 Provided that the network effect is sufficiently high, the SEB arrangement is Pareto-superior (i.e. monopolist, workers and consumers prefers it). The proof directly follows from the previous results.

To sum up, network effects may be responsible for the elimination of undesirable conflicts regarding the bargaining agenda between parties and the occurrence of a Pareto-superior outcome.

3 Monopoly with Threat of Entry

In the previous subsections, we have analysed the preferences over the bargaining agenda of the monopolist and its union; however, we have considered the monopoly as the given market structure. In the following, we investigate the topic of the bargaining agenda selection in the context of market entry under consumption externalities.

In the traditional case of standard goods (i.e. without network effects) the strategic choice of the bargaining agenda for different market structures, namely duopoly vs. (pure or threatened) monopoly, has been studied by Bughin (1999), Buccella (2011), and more recently Fanti and Buccella (2015). Bughin (1999) and Buccella (2011) consider that the institutional arrangements in the labour market are the EB and the RTM agenda. They analyse different entry modes and constraints on the choice of bargaining scope: (1) committed bargaining, in which the incumbent firm chooses the bargaining agenda, and then the entrant “joins the pack” and adopts the agenda of the incumbent, and (2) flexible bargaining, in which the entrant freely chooses the agenda. Fanti and Buccella (2015) extend the previous literature to different timing specifications of the bargaining game.

The key results of Bughin (1999) are as follows: (1) in a duopoly with committed bargaining, firms prefer to bargain under RTM rather than EB, in clear conflict of interest with unions; (2) in the case of potential entry with committed bargaining, the incumbent can choose EB over RTM to deter the market entry of a potential competitor if the union has adequately low bargaining power. Using a conjectural variation model, Buccella (2011) confirms the results of Bughin (1999). Moreover, in a Cournot duopoly extended to the SEB agenda, Fanti and Buccella (2015) additionally find that SEB can also be used to deter entry in the case of committed bargaining.Footnote 6

In the present paper, we consider the three institutional arrangements of RTM, EB and SEB as in Fanti and Buccella (2015); however, for simplicity, we restrict the analysis to the case of monopoly with threat of entry with committed bargaining. We extend the previous work to the presence of consumption externalities (network effects) to investigate how those externalities modify the possibility that the bargaining agendas may be effective as a strategic deterrence tool.

3.1 Game Framework

Let us first consider the game’s framework and structure. The game, as usual, is solved via backward induction to derive sub-game perfect Nash equilibria. The first three stages are common to each arrangement. In the first stage, the incumbent firm-union unit chooses the bargaining agenda to introduce (RTM, SEB or EB). In the second stage, the entrant, taking into consideration its fixed costs, decides whether to enter the industry. Whenever entry is allowed, in the third stage, the entrant firm-union pair “joins the pack” and adopts the agenda of the incumbent pair. In the last stages, depending on the agenda, the sequence of moves is as follows. In the case of RTM and SEB, in the fourth stage, each firm-union bargaining unit simultaneously negotiates over wages, and then, in the fifth stage of the game, consumers fulfil their expectations. In the sixth and last stage of the game, firms compete in the product market and simultaneously select their output level (given the optimal wages bargained with the unions). However, under SEB, each union-firm pair bargains the employment level, taking into consideration the optimal wage previously bargained with the union and the market interaction with the rival firm. In the case of EB, in the fourth stage, consumers fulfil their expectations and, in the fifth and last stage of the game, each union-firm unit simultaneously negotiate the wages and employment, taking into account the product market interaction with the rival. Note that, under EB, in contrast with both RTM and SEB cases, the wage bargaining occurs contingent on the knowledge of the fulfilment of the consumers’ expectations in the preceding stage. Figure 3 summarises the timing of the game for each bargaining arrangement.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Timing of the game, duopoly

We define firm 1 as the incumbent and firm 2 as the potential entrant. In duopoly, the demand function becomes

$$\begin{aligned} p=a-q_1 -q_2 +n(y_1 +y_2 ) \end{aligned}$$
(6)

The firms’ profit functions are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _1 =(p-w_1 )q_1 \end{aligned}$$
(7)
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _2 =(p-w_2 )q_2 -E \end{aligned}$$
(8)

for the incumbent and the entrant, respectively. The term E represents an exogenous fixed cost that the entrant faces.

On the other hand, the union utility function is

$$\begin{aligned} V_i =(w_i -w^{\circ })q_i ,\;i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

The bargaining solution is now modelled by the following generalized Nash product:

$$\begin{aligned} N_i =( {\pi _i })^{1-b}( {V_i })^b,\;i=1,2. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Using Eqs. (6)–(9) and solving the Nash product in Eq. (10), straightforward calculations provide the expressions in Table 2. The Appendix provides the extensive derivations.

Table 2 Duopoly outcomes under the three bargaining agendas

3.2 The Selection of the Agenda as Barrier to Entry

Let us consider the incumbent’s selection of the bargaining agenda as a strategic deterrence tool. To deter entry, the incumbent compares its monopoly profits with the duopoly profits after entry under the alternative agendas, taking into consideration the fixed costs of the competitor in the industry. Table 3 reports the payoffs. A closer analytical observation leads to the following result.

Table 3 Firms’ payoffs, monopoly and duopoly outcomes under the three bargaining agendas

Result 4 The firm’s payoffs in Table 3 generate Fig. 4, characterised by thirteen regions in the relevant [n,b]-space.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Firm’s payoff regions in the [n,b]-space. The graphs are drawn for a = 1, w\(^{\circ }\) = 0.

Proof

See the Appendix

Following the reasoning of Bughin (1999), Buccella (2011) and Fanti and Buccella (2015), in the case of monopoly with threat of entry under “committed bargaining”, the incumbent firm (M) can strategically choose the bargaining agenda as an entry deterrence tool.

In the subsequent analysis, we impose the following restriction on the size of the fixed costs the entrant has to face.

Restriction 1 \(\max \pi _1^{i/D} {>}E{>}\min \pi _1^{j,k/D} ,\;i,j,k={} { RTM,SEB,EB}\; i\ne j,k\).\(\square \)

The economic meaning of Restriction 1 is straightforward: in fact, if \(\min \pi _1^{i/D} >E\), the fixed costs are extremely low, such that there is always free entry in the industry; in contrast, if \(E>\max \pi _1^{i/D} \), the size of the fixed costs is severely high for the potential competitor for which the market entry is always blockaded. Given Restriction 1, the incumbent firm strategically chooses the use of a precise bargaining agenda to deter entry if the following conditions apply:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} a) \pi _1^{i/M} >E>\pi _1^{i/D} \;\;i=\textit{RTM}, \textit{SEB} ,\textit{EB}; \\ b) \pi _1^{i/M} >\pi _1^{j,k/D} \quad i,j,k=\textit{RTM}, \textit{SEB}, \textit{EB}\quad i\ne j,k; \\ c) \text{ if } i,j \text{ satisfy } a,b \text{ then }\max (\pi _1^{i/M} ,\pi _1^{j/M} ) \text{ is } \text{ selected } i,j=\textit{RTM}, \textit{SEB}, \textit{EB}\quad i\ne j. \\ \end{array}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Let us discuss conditions (a)–(c) in (11). Condition (a) simply states that, with committed bargaining, if the incumbent negotiates with the union under a precise agenda, fixed costs are higher than the duopoly profits under that agenda to block the potential competitor, because entry would be not profitable. Condition (b) specifies that the duopoly profits with the alternative agendas do not have to be larger than the monopoly profits of the selected agenda because, otherwise, the incumbent finds it more profitable to select one of the alternative agendas and accommodate entry. Condition (c) determines that, if more than one agenda complies with (a)–(b), the incumbent selects the agenda, which ensures the highest profits.

Application of conditions (a)–(c) in (11) under Restriction 1 to Result 4 leads directly to Result 5.

Result 5 The following holds:

  1. a)

    depending on the size of the fixed costs E , the incumbent firm in an industry with network effects may use at least one bargaining agenda to deter entry unless the union bargaining or the network effects are adequately high;

  2. b)

    if the union bargaining power is not too high and E is sufficiently low, the incumbent in an industry with network effects may use the EB agenda to deter entry for a wide range of the network externalities. However, the higher the network externality, the lower the possibility is to use the EB agenda;

  3. c)

    if E becomes adequately high, the EB agenda as an instrument to deter entry is replaced by SEB for low-medium and RTM for medium-high values of the network effects.

Proof

See the Appendix. \(\square \)

Figure 5 graphically depicts Result 5, which call for some brief comments. First, the incumbent can no longer strategically select a bargaining agenda to block entry to intensive network effects. This result is independent of the fixed costs’ size. Second, depending on the size of E, different bargaining agenda can strategically be used as a deterrence tool. In the case of low fixed costs (see left box, Fig. 5), EB prevails to prevent entry; however, it is not the unique agenda that can be exploited. In fact, there are two regions in the parameter space where also SEB and RTM can deter market entry. On the other hand, in the case of high fixed costs (see right box of Fig. 5), although EB might be potentially used as a barrier to entry, the incumbent never selects EB because it always finds it profitable to commit to SEB (for low-medium values of the network intensity) and RTM (for medium-high values of the network intensity) negotiations as deterrence tools.Footnote 7

Fig. 5
figure 5

Bargaining agendas as entry deterrence tools in the [n,b]-space. Left box low E. Right box high E; in bold the selected agenda when two agendas can deter entry. The graphs are drawn for a = 1, w\(^{\circ }\) = 0.

Thus, the presence of the network effects strongly enriches and modifies the core results of Bughin (1999), Buccella (2011) and Fanti and Buccella (2015), according to which EB is the sole agenda to be used as an entry deterrent: in fact, on the one hand, the effectiveness of using EB to block entry in a unionised industry decreases as the network externality increases, and on the other hand, the RTM agenda may also be a strategic deterrence tool. More in general, the role of the network effect is to weaken the strategic use of the negotiation agendas as a barrier or even to eliminate any agenda as an entry barrier for low levels of the union’s power.Footnote 8

Therefore, this analysis evidences a crucial role of the network externalities. In particular, three major effects of the network externalities need to be highlighted. First, regardless of the size of the entry costs the potential competitor has to face, the network externalities always work in the direction of reducing the strength of the deterrence effect. Second, the strengthening of the network effects implies that the blocking agenda switches from EB/SEB (for low/high fixed costs of entry) to RTM. The rationale for this finding can be explained as follows. In general, more intensive network effects work in the direction of making the EB/SEB monopoly profitability (for low/high fixed costs of entry) higher than the RTM duopoly. In fact, the monopoly wage under SEB is independent of the parameter n, while network externalities have a higher positive impact on RTM than EB wages. However, when network externalities are not too intense, the EB/SEB duopoly profits are lower than RTM. This result occurs because the positive impact of the network effects on EB/SEB duopoly prices does not overcome those effects on wages. As a consequence, the critical value of the fixed cost for the entrant under RTM is higher than EB/SEB, and the incumbent can strategically commit to the latter agendas to deter entry. This status changes when the network effects become sufficiently high; their positive impact on EB/SEB duopoly prices overcome that on wages, and the overall profitability of those agendas is higher than that on RTM. Therefore, the fixed cost threshold for the entrant under EB/SEB increases, and the incumbent can strategically select RTM to deter market entry.

Third, for adequately high values of the union bargaining power, a no univocal role of the network externalities arises. In fact, relatively low/high values of the network effect act in the opposite direction and eliminate the possibility of using the negotiation agenda as a tool to create a barrier to entry while the network effects allow the use of the bargaining agenda to deter entry only for medium values of the network intensity.

To sum up, network effects play an important role on entry.Footnote 9

3.3 Welfare Considerations

Let us consider the welfare effects of the proposed model. A wide characterisation of the effects of the network externalities on social welfare was largely unexplored. Given the social welfare payoffs in Tables 1 and 2, a straightforward analytical inspection reveals the following result.

Result 6 A duopoly with SEB always leads to optimal social welfare outcome.

Proof

See the Appendix. \(\square \)

Let us first consider the welfare effects of the entry game with committed bargaining.Footnote 10

Result 5 states that, in an industry with consumption externalities, the monopolist can strategically select the appropriate bargaining agenda to deter entry except for values sufficiently high of the union bargaining and network effects. Figure 6 shows the social welfare regions generated by Result 6. Figure 7 overlaps the parameters’ space in which Results 5 applies (i.e. Fig. 5) at the social welfare regions of Fig. 6 (bold lines). In the case of low fixed costs, EB deters entry for low-medium values of the union bargaining power. However, the presence of network effects reduces the opportunity to block entry with respect to standard goods. A straightforward graphical inspection of Fig. 7 reveals that, in the presence of low fixed costs of entry, the region in which EB blocks entry falls in Regions IV and V, reported in the proof of Result 6 in the Appendix and graphically depicted in Fig. 6.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Plot of the social welfare regions in the [n,b]-space. The graphs are drawn for a = 1, w\(^{\circ }\) = 0

Fig. 7
figure 7

Social welfare regions (solid lines) and entry deterring agendas Regions (dash-dot lines) in the [n,b]-space. Left box low E. Right box high E. The graphs are drawn for a = 1, w\(^{\circ }\) = 0.

Consequently, the society ends up with the second-last welfare level. In the area where SEB blocks entry, which partially covers Regions I–V of the social welfare ranking in the proof of Result 6 reported in the Appendix, the entry deterrence is not strictly welfare detrimental (the monopoly profits under SEB are higher than the duopoly profits under EB and RTM), except for the small welfare detrimental triangle area, which falls into Region V. In fact, SEB allows reaching either the second-best (Regions II and III)Footnote 11 or the third-best outcome (Region IV). On the other hand, when the fixed costs are high, the area in which EB blocks entry is replaced by SEB/RTM for low-medium/medium-high values of the network intensity.

These findings confirm and broadly extend the insight of Fanti and Buccella (2015), who challenge the idea that the efficient bargaining agenda, both in the simultaneous and sequential mode, is socially efficient due to its potential deterrence effect in a long-run perspective; i.e. when potential entry is allowed. In this respect, Fig. 8 depicts the rather complicated area representing the parameter space in which the strategic use of the bargaining agendas is welfare damaging in the presence of low/high fixed costs.

Fig. 8
figure 8

The bargaining agendas’ social welfare detrimental area in the [n,b]-space. Left box low E. Right box high E. The graph is drawn for a = 1, w\(^{\circ }\) = 0.

Footnote 12

From Result 5 we also know that there are two areas in which the incumbent cannot strategically select any negotiation agenda to deter entry: when the union bargaining power is sufficiently high (with enlarging ranges of n as b approaches the unity) and when network effects are relatively intense (with enlarging ranges of b towards the extreme values when n approaches the unity). From Result 6, the government has a clear indication in those areas; a duopoly with SEB ensures the overall highest welfare level.

Thus, we observe that the role played by the network effect on welfare is not unambiguous. In fact, if the network effect is extremely high, the most desirable social welfare outcome can be attained. However, if the network effect is of medium intensity, the RTM agenda may deter market entry, especially in the presence of high fixed costs, therefore leading to the unwelcome result of reaching the least social welfare level. In particular, from a social welfare point of view, a range exists of medium-high levels of the network effects around the value of \(n=.7\), such that the monopolist can virtually always deter entry with the RTM agenda for every value of the union bargaining power, thus entrapping the economy in the least social outcome.

Note that the welfare-damaging parametric area is slightly reduced in the case of high fixed costs (as easily seen by observing the left and right boxes of Fig. 8).Footnote 13

4 Conclusions

In this paper we have examined the issue of the bargaining agenda in the presence of network goods. First, we have analysed a unionised pure monopoly, and then a monopoly with the threat of entry when the strategic effects of potential competition are taken into account. The key message is that different labour market institutions add to the other known devices used as a barrier to entry in network industries (i.e. capacity investment, patents, limit prices and so on).

With regard to pure monopoly, we have shown that the monopolist’s preferred agenda depends crucially on the strength of the network externality. While without network effects profits under the RTM arrangement are always higher than EB/SEB (both modes yield the same bargaining outcome), we show that the monopolist prefers the SEB agenda with network externalities, especially when the union bargaining power is low. This result is due to the sequential negotiation for which the consumers’ expectations on the market size are not already realised in the long run; i.e. in the first stage of wage determination. Moreover, given that the union and consumers always prefer the SEB agenda, network externalities may partly solve the traditional conflict of interests between the bargaining parties and lead to the Pareto superior equilibrium.

With regard to monopoly with the threat of market entry under “committed bargaining”, we have shown that, if the incumbent can choose the negotiation agenda, it may commit to different agendas to prevent the entry of a potential competitor. The choice crucially depends on the size of the fixed costs the entrant has to face, the strength of the network externality and the union bargaining power. In particular, when the fixed costs are sufficiently low, the incumbent may use EB to block entry for a wide range of the network externalities and the union bargaining power. For medium-high values of the union power (and increasing values of the network externalities), SEB can be used as an entry deterrent, while, for medium-high values of network effects (and values tending to the extremes of the union power), RTM prevails. If the fixed costs are sufficiently high, SEB for low-medium and RTM for medium-high values of the network effects replace EB as an entry deterrent instrument. However, regardless of the fixed costs’ size, when the network effects are adequately intense, no agenda deters entry, eliminating the barrier to entry.

With regard to social welfare, we have shown that the duopoly under SEB leads always to the most desirable social welfare level. However, the possibility of the monopolist of using the bargaining agenda as an entry deterrent harms the achievement of the social optimum outcome. The role of the network externalities is not clear cut. In fact, if the network intensity is high, it is possible to attain the desirable social welfare outcome. On the other hand, for medium intensity of the network effect, the entry is more likely to be deterred under the RTM agenda with welfare-detrimental outcome effects. On the whole, the SEB agenda seems to ensure, in most of the cases, the best affordable welfare outcomes.

These findings offer the policy implication that decision makers should pay attention both to the bargaining agenda and the intensity of consumption externalities. Thus, to achieve the highest welfare level, in terms of policy, the governments should operate to introduce and further encourage SEB agreements in network industries only if unions and the network effects are very strong. Otherwise, our findings have shown all of the other parameters’ combinations that lead to sub-optimal (for instance, third-best and even least) welfare outcomes associated with the bargaining agendas and the relative market structures that arise in equilibrium. Moreover, the governments have to promote, if possible, the increase of the network effects beyond a certain high threshold (especially when unions are not too strong) to allow a more competitive industry structure.

A reasonable further step for future research would be to analyse whether a monopoly firm should hire a manager to bargain with the union and, if it is the case, how the findings of this paper may change. The entry game should be extended, allowing for the “flexible” commitment. Finally, an interesting extension of this analysis could be to investigate from a game-theoretic perspective the selection of the bargaining agenda in a duopoly market structure with price competition and differentiated products.