Introduction

Container ports have a prominent role in the container shipping supply chain (CSSC) [31]. The 2022 World’s Top 100 Container Ports Ranking (Lloyd’s [22], reported by Lloyd’s List which is the oldest shipping newspaper in the world, indicated that all current container ports are in a tough struggle for long-term development, including 28 ports in China. In 2021, the Shanghai port had a 47.03 million TEU container throughput, representing an 8.1% increase from the previous year, leading the world’s ports for 12 consecutive years; the second-ranking Singapore port completed a 37.47 million TEU container throughput, an increase of 1.6% from the previous year; the third-ranking Ningbo Zhoushan port completed 31.07 million TEU of containers, which was up 8.2% from the previous year. The container port throughput of the top 10 global container ports worldwide increased from 253.63 million TEUs in 2020 to 268.31 million TEUs in 2021, representing an annual growth rate of 5.8%.

Most container ports have entered a post COVID-19 pandemic recovery phase but are still facing rural tests [41]. In the short term, port shutdowns caused by the pandemic continued to occur [23]. In the long term, the labor shortages and industrial shifts generated by China’s vanishing demographic dividend will make its ports face increasingly difficult circumstances in the future [45]. According to Deloitte’s forecast, container traffic in global ports will grow 2.3% in 2022, indicating further slowdown. Amid the ongoing effect of the COVID-19 pandemic, tense multilateral relations, and uncertain trade relations, the future of container ports remains unknown.

With the advancing development of the CSSC, container terminals have motivations for collusion to guarantee their own interests and keep up with the pace of development. Xin et al. [36] solved the multiplayer non-zero-sum games with online mode-free integral reinforcement learning algorithm. Zhuang et al. [44] introduced an optimal iterative learning control algorithm for linear time-invariant multiple-input–multiple-output problems with nonuniform trial lengths under input constraints. Unlike the previous research [6], in this study, we explore the optimal dynamic strategies between the Port Authority and container terminals applying the evolutionary game (EG) model, under the premise that the container terminal’s net profits from collusion strategy are greater than those from non-collusion strategy.

Several research issues requiring investigation are examined in this study. (1) What are the optimal evolutionary stable strategies (ESS) in the long term of a container terminal and the Port Authority under different scenarios? (2) How can a long-term optimal strategy be adopted for the container terminal and the Port Authority? (3) Will social welfares improve if the optimal strategy is implemented? To answer these three questions, this study introduces an EG model, verifies the robustness of the analysis with numerical simulation, and provides proposed conclusions for advancing the CSSC.

The reminder of this paper is devised as follows. Sect. "Literature review" presents a literature review regarding the CSSC, EG theory, and government regulation of collusion. In Sect. "Model", we formulate the EG models in different scenarios. In Sect. "Evolutionary stability analysis", we conduct the ESS in an evolutionary stable analysis. In Sect. "Numerical simulation", we apply the model to a number of simulations. Finally, in Sect. "Conclusions", we summarize the conclusions of this study, and elaborate the shortcomings of this paper and our next research directions in the future.

Literature review

Container shipping supply chain

Some research has focused on and expanded the breadth and depth of knowledge regarding tacit collusion among the container terminals, upstream ports, downstream liner companies, and even shippers. For example, Tan et al. [30] introduced the strategic integration of inland ports and shipping services for ocean carriers in a vertical CSSC. Dong et al. [5] examined the effects of regional port collusion in a multiport region using a three-stage non-cooperative game model. Zhang et al. [40] examined regional transshipment ports using the structural hole theory.

Other scholars have explored collusion practices between carriers and pertinent enterprises such as inland freight forwarders and shipping lines [32, 33]. Paridaens and Notteboom [27] analyzed recent developments in the strategic routes of three shipping companies amid logistics integration and presented empirical findings. Zhou et al. [43] designed a hub-and-spoke network for the convenience of container ships’ movement in the CSSC. Jeong and Kim [15] also designed a robust network to model for ensuring the reliability of container operations. Dong et al. [6] determined the optimum strategies among container terminals and related liner companies using a game model. Nguyen et al. [26] explored the unknown risk situation for the CSSC. Fan et al. [8] focused on decisions related to investment in vessel trading and demolition in different CSSC submarkets.

Studies have also been conducted regarding the future directions of CSSC. For instance, Yang [38] argued that the CSSC can expect to adopt green transportation processes and supply chains,Cariou et al. [2] found that the CSSC can lower greenhouse gas emissions from international shipping as announced by the International Maritime Organization in 2018,Finally, Huang et al. [14] investigated the locating of hub ports and allocating of non-hub ports to hubs, to ensure high-level reliability of CSSC, which was facing increased exposures of unreliability in the post-COVID-19 pandemic era.

Evolutionary game theory

EG theory has been described in the context of a Hawk–Dove game [29] and is usually applied by scholars to analyze the relationships between different stakeholders or to forecast the long-term development of different industries using a two-sided or tripartite EG model, particularly in examining CSSC, as shown in Table 1.

Table 1 Studies of evolutionary games in different industries

Among the most useful analysis tools, EG theory has been widely applied by many scholars in investigating a variety of industries. For example, in the ride sourcing industry, Lei et al. [19] used a tripartite EG model to demonstrate the regulatory strategies for the sharing industry. For the energy industry, Wang et al. [34] introduced an EG model introducing the engagement of energy customers and government regulators and analyzed the ESS of each participant. In the business management industry, Hafezalkotob et al. [12] introduced a policymaking EG model between small and medium-sized enterprises during a pandemic recession to examine their remaining in the economic market at the end of the pandemic.

Particularly in the CSSC and related research areas concerning the maritime industry, a body of research has conducted a series of meaningful explorations. For instance, in the CSSC area, scholars examined the ESS of each participant, ensuring the sustainable development of the entire system. Jiang et al. [16] explored the different benefits among the government and liner companies in implementing China’s Emission Control Areas regulation. Lin et al. [21] introduced a perspective for shipping lines concerned with green maritime shipping using ESS. Zhang et al. [42] introduced a system EG model to examine the responses of tripartite participants to governance policies in different scenarios. Xu et al. [37] designed a tripartite EG model to investigate the effects of ESS on the growth of the electrical ship industry. Hu and Dong [13] used EG theory to describe the interaction between different container carriers in peak and off seasons. Regarding marine pollution, other studies have explored the ESS among different stakeholders. Meng et al. [24] introduced a tripartite EG model to analyze the evolution of each participant’s emissions reduction. Ye et al. [39] studied the ESS regarding the control of ballast water discharge from ships between flag and port states, determining that the results can be influenced by different participants’ decision sequences. Li and Jiang [20] established a tripartite EG model and analyzed participants’ interests to show how central governments affect the strategies of local governments and sea-using enterprises by developing maritime pollution control regulations. Xiao and Cui [35] showed that the shipping market demand can influence government’s carbon quota regulation.

Supervision of collusion

We next review the literature on government supervision of corporate collusion. Government supervision could advance the healthy functioning of the entire industry. Faure-Grimaud et al. [10] assessed the efficiency of supervision in centralized and decentralized organizations. Fang et al. [9] examined the impact of social relationships between senior managers on the quality of financial reporting. Lee et al. [17] explored various themes and identified the pivotal issues emerging in the sustainability of the maritime industry. Meng et al. [24] studied the probability of active government regulation to reduce carbon emissions. Xu et al. [37] showed the influence of ESS in the electric shipping industry.

Efficient supervision may also improve the effectiveness of the entire industry. Che et al. [3] showed a hierarchy with inadequate supervision, demonstrating that supervisors may collect incorrect signals about agent effort, identifying a new tradeoff between inefficient supervision and supervisor-agent collusion. Du et al. [7] researched the effect of a carbon tax policy implementation on altering the choices of low-carbon buildings. Mookherjee and Tsumagari [25] found that principals will not benefit from hiring supervisors.

Summary

This study aims to fill the gap in understanding the relationship between the Port Authority and container terminals under the premise that the container terminal’s net profits from collusion strategy are greater than those from non-collusion strategy. We examine the long-term development of container terminals in the CSSC under Port Authority supervision in different particular scenarios. Hence, we construct an EG model with two stakeholders based on EG theory, determine the optimal strategies through the evolutionary stability analysis, and confirm the robustness of the stability analysis using the numerical simulation, and finally summarize the conclusions and research directions.

The primary contributions of this study are threefold. (1) We explore the long-term effects of the Port Authority’s strict or lax supervision strategy on the container terminal’s collusion or non-collusion strategy; (2) we develop an EG model with two stakeholders based on the EG theory under the premise that the container terminal’s net profits from collusion strategy are greater than those from non-collusion strategy; and (3) We verify the stability of the collusion strategy and the robustness of the stability analysis using numerical simulation.

Model

Problem description

In this section, we consider a CSSC involving two stakeholders—a container terminal and the Port Authority. To maximize its profits in the long term, the container terminal will choose a collusion or non-collusion strategy with the liner companies or with other container terminals.

Meanwhile, the Port Authority will implement strict or lax supervision on the collusion strategy of the container terminal. According to the EG, the interactive behavior between the two participants is illustrated in Fig. 1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

The interactive behavior in the EG between the two participants

Basic hypotheses

Hypothesis 1

Both the container terminal and the Port Authority have bounded rationality, choosing their strategy according to maximizing profits [13, 37].

Hypothesis 2

This EG model includes a container terminal and the Port Authority. If the proportion of the collusion strategy of a container terminal is \(x\), then, the proportion of the non-collusion strategy of a container terminal is \(1 - x\). In addition, the proportion of the strict supervision strategy of the Port Authority is \(y\), and the proportion of the lax supervision strategy of the Port Authority is \(1 - y\) [16, 42].

Hypothesis 3

When choosing the collusion strategy, the container terminal’s profit is \(I_{c}\), and its cost is \(C_{c}\); when choosing the non-collusion strategy, the container terminal’s profit is \(I_{n}\), and its cost is \(C_{n}\). Meanwhile, the difference between \(I_{c}\) and \(C_{c}\) is greater than that between \(I_{n}\) and \(C_{n}\) (i.e., \(I_{c} - C_{c} > I_{n} - C_{n}\)) [4].

Hypothesis 4

When choosing the strict supervision strategy, the Port Authority will fine the container terminal, receiving \(F\) as the profit. If the container terminal chooses the non-collusion strategy, it will bring an increase in social welfare \(W\), and the Port Authority will give the container terminal a discount in tax or subsidy (\(S\)), and the Port Authority will spend workforce, material, and financial resources to maintain strict supervision at a cost of \(C_{g}\). If the Port Authority chooses lax supervision when the container terminal chooses a collusion strategy, the cost is 0; otherwise, the benefit is \(W\). All notions and their descriptions are presented in Table 2 [19, 28].

Table 2 Notations and descriptions

Replicated dynamic equation

Considering the limited rationality of the container terminal and the Port Authority, we formulate the payoff matrix between the two participants based on EG theory, as presented in Table 3.

Table 3 Payoff matrix between the Port Authority and the container terminal

When the container terminal chooses the collusion strategy, its expected profit is \(U_{T}^{C}\), when the container terminal chooses the non-collusion strategy, its expected profit is \(U_{T}^{N}\), then, its average expected profit is \(U_{T}\). The container terminal’s average expected profit is the expected profit regardless of the collusion strategy.

$$ U_{T}^{C} = y(I_{c} - F - C_{c} ) + (1 - y)(I_{c} - C_{c} ) $$
(1)
$$ U_{T}^{N} = y(I_{n} + S - C_{n} ) + (1 - y)(I_{n} - C_{n} ) $$
(2)
$$ U_{T} = x[y(I_{c} - F - C_{c} ) + (1 - y)(I_{c} - C_{c} )] + (1 - x)[y(I_{n} + S - C_{n} ) + (1 - y)(I_{n} - C_{n} )] $$
(3)

Likewise, when the Port Authority chooses the strict supervision strategy, its expected profit is \(U_{P}^{S}\), when the Port Authority chooses the lax supervision strategy, its expected profit is \(U_{P}^{L}\), then, its average expected profit is \(U_{P}\). The Port Authority’s average expected profit is the expected profit regardless of the supervision strategy.

$$ U_{P}^{S} = x(F - C_{g} ) + (1 - x)(W - S - C_{g} ) $$
(4)
$$ U_{P}^{L} = (1 - x)W $$
(5)
$$ U_{P} = y[x(F - C_{g} ) + (1 - x)(W - S - C_{g} )] + (1 - y)(1 - x)W $$
(6)

Above all, the replicated dynamic equation (RDE) of collusion strategy chosen by the container terminal and the RDE of strict supervision strategy chosen by the Port Authority are {F(x), F(y)} as follows [1]:

$$ F(x) = \frac{{{\text{d}}x}}{{{\text{d}}t}} = x(U_{T}^{C} - U_{T} ) = x(1 - x)(U_{T}^{C} - U_{T}^{N} ) = x(1 - x)[y( - F - S) + I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} ] $$
(7)
$$ F(y) = \frac{{{\text{d}}y}}{{{\text{d}}t}} = y(U_{L}^{C} - U_{L} ) = y(1 - y)(U_{L}^{C} - U_{L}^{N} ) = y(1 - y)[x(F + S) - S - C_{g} ] $$
(8)

Evolutionary stability analysis

To solve the partial derivative of \(F(x)\) and \(F(y)\) with respect to \(x\) and \(y\), we obtain the Jacobian matrix (\(J\)) of the above RDEs as follows [18]:

$$ J = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{\partial F(x)}{{\partial x}}} & {\frac{\partial F(x)}{{\partial y}}} \\ {\frac{\partial F(y)}{{\partial x}}} & {\frac{\partial F(y)}{{\partial y}}} \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {J_{11} } & {J_{12} } \\ {J_{21} } & {J_{22} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$
$$ J_{11} = (1 - 2x)[y( - F - S) + I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} ] $$
$$ J_{12} = x(1 - x)( - F - S) $$
$$ J_{21} = y(1 - y)(F + S) $$
$$ J_{22} = (1 - 2y)[x(F + S) - S - C_{g} ] $$

The EPs of the RDEs are \(E_{1} = (0,0)\), \(E_{2} = (0,1)\), \(E_{3} = (1,0)\), \(E_{4} = (1,1)\), and \(E_{5} = (x_{0} ,y_{0} )\), in which \(x_{0} = \tfrac{{S + C_{g} }}{F + S}\),\(y_{0} = \tfrac{{I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} }}{F + S}\).

Substituting the five EPs into the Jacobian Matrices, we obtain the following:

$$ J(0,0) = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} } & 0 \\ 0 & { - S - C_{g} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$
$$ J(0,1) = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - F - S + I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} } & 0 \\ 0 & {S + C_{g} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$
$$ J(1,0) = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - I_{c} + C_{c} + I_{n} - C_{n} } & 0 \\ 0 & {F - C_{g} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$
$$ J(1,1) = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {F + S - I_{c} + C_{c} + I_{n} - C_{n} } & 0 \\ 0 & {C_{g} - F} \\ \end{array} } \right] $$
$$ J(x_{0} ,y_{0} ) = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 & {\tfrac{{C_{g} - F}}{F + S}(S + C_{g} )} \\ {(1 - \tfrac{{I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} }}{F + S})(I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} )} & 0 \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

The eigenvalue (Eig) and determinant (Det) of the Jacobian Matrix \(J\) are obtained in different scenarios. Referencing Friedman [11], the EP is an ESS while the EP of the RDE satisfies the condition that det J = ad − bc > 0, tr J = a + d < 0; otherwise, the EP is a saddle point while det J < 0.

Proposition 1

When the fine is less than the Port Authority’s cost, the ESS will be collusion and lax supervision, regardless of the magnitude between the sum of the fine and subsidy and the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy.

Proof

A. When \(F - C_{g} < 0\), we can obtain \(\tfrac{{S + C_{g} }}{F + S} > 1\); thus \((\tfrac{{S + C_{g} }}{F + S},\tfrac{{I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} }}{F + S})\) is not the internal EP, then, (0,0), (0,1), (1,0), and (1,1) are the local EPs of the system. Moreover, from Hypothesis 3, it is clear that \(I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\); thus, there are two scenarios for a container terminal:


Scenario 1: When \(F + S > I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(F < C_{g}\), at \(E_{1} = (0,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} = I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} = - S - C_{g} < 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J < 0\), and \(E_{1}\) is a saddle point. Similarly, at \(E_{2} = (0,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J > 0\), and \(E_{2}\) is a saddle point. At \(E_{3} = (1,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} < 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J < 0\), and \(E_{3}\) is an ESS point. At \(E_{4} = (1,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J > 0\), and \(E_{4}\) is a saddle point. These conditions are presented in Table 4.

Table 4 Stabilities of the EG between the Port Authority and the container terminal in scenarios 1 and 2

Scenario 2: When \(0 < F + S < I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n}\) and \(F < C_{g}\), at \(E_{1} = (0,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} = I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} = - S - C_{g} < 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J > 0\), and \(E_{1}\) is a saddle point. Similarly, at \(E_{2} = (0,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J > 0\), and \(E_{2}\) is an instability point. At \(E_{3} = (1,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} < 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J < 0\), and \(E_{3}\) is an ESS point. At \(E_{4} = (1,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J < 0\), and \(E_{4}\) is a saddle point. These conditions are presented in Table 4.

Proposition 2.

When the fine is greater than the Port Authority’s cost, the ESS will be collusion and strict supervision as the sum of the fine and subsidy is less than the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy. There is no ESS as the sum of fine and subsidy is greater than the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy.

Proof

The welfare of the collusion strategy provides the container terminal with motivation to choose a collusion strategy, and the Port Authority will choose a strict supervision strategy to improve social welfare, but the high cost will hinder the Port Authority’s positivity of supervision, and the Port Authority will select lax supervision strategy, then the container terminal will have the motivation to select the collusion strategy, and this cycle will continue over and over again. Therefore, there is no ESS as the sum of the fine and subsidy is greater than the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy.

When \(F - C_{g} > 0\), we can obtain (0,0), (0,1), (1,0), (1,1), and \((x_{0} ,y_{0} )\), which are the local EPs of this system. Moreover, from Hypothesis 3, it is clear that \(I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\); thus, for the container terminal, there are two scenarios as follows:


Scenario 3: When \(F + S > I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n}\) and \(F > C_{g}\), at \(E_{1} = (0,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} = I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} = - S - C_{g} < 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J\) is not available, then, \(E_{1}\) is a saddle point. Similarly, at \(E_{2} = (0,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J\) is not available, and \(E_{2}\) is a saddle point. At \(E_{3} = (1,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J\) is not available, and \(E_{3}\) is a saddle point. At \(E_{4} = (1,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} < 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J > 0\), and \(E_{4}\) is a saddle point. At \(E_{5} = (x_{0} ,y_{0} )\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} < 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J\) is uncertain, and \(E_{5}\) is a saddle point. These conditions are presented in Table 5.

Table 5 Stabilities of the EG between the Port Authority and the container terminal in scenarios 3 and 4

Scenario 4: When \(F + S < I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n}\) and \(F > C_{g}\), at \(E_{1} = (0,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} = I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} = - S - C_{g} < 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J\) is uncertain, then, \(E_{1}\) is a saddle point. Similarly, at \(E_{2} = (0,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J > 0\), and \(E_{2}\) is an instability point. At \(E_{3} = (1,0)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} > 0\); thus, det \(J < 0\) and tr \(J < 0\), and \(E_{3}\) is a saddle point. At \(E_{4} = (1,1)\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} < 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} < 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J < 0\), and \(E_{4}\) is an ESS point. At \(E_{5} = (x_{0} ,y_{0} )\), we can obtain \(\lambda_{1} > 0\) and \(\lambda_{2} < 0\); thus, det \(J > 0\) and tr \(J = 0\) is uncertain, and \(E_{5}\) is a central point. These conditions are presented in Table 5.

Numerical simulation

The results are calculated using the simulation platform MATLAB R2012a in four simulations with a computer with 8G RAM, 6G discrete NVIDIA GTX2050 graphics card, an Intel i5-12540 processor, and a 64-bit WIN11 operating system. These simulation experiments replicate the behavior of the model when collusion strategies are considered, with insufficient attention to the illegal behavior of container terminals in different initial scenarios. The results of these simulation experiments are described below.


Simulation 1: When \(F + S > I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(F < C_{g}\), the initial condition is set as follows: \(F = 1\), \(C_{g} = 2\), \(S = 2\), \(I_{c} = 5\),\(C_{c} = 2\), \(I_{n} = 4\), and \(C_{n} = 2\). Considering the different probabilities of the collusion and supervision strategies under the initial conditions, the dynamic route of the EG between the two participants is illustrated in Fig. 2. The simulation results indicate that the only ESS point is (1, 0), that is, the container terminal tends to select collusion strategy, and the Port Authority tends to choose lax supervision strategy.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Dynamic route of the EG (\(F < C_{g}\))

In the early stage of the new policy implementation regarding collusion in CSSC, the government supervision over container terminals is in the mapping stage, and not effectively put into practice. Excessive supervision costs cause the Port Authority to ignore collusion in container terminals, leading to its prevalence. This situation is exceptionally unconducive and unhealthy to the sustainable development of the CSSC.


Simulation 2: When \(0 < F + S < I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n}\) and \(F < C_{g}\), we set \(F = 0.5\), \(C_{g} = 2\), \(S = 0.4\), \(I_{c} = 5\),\(C_{c} = 2\), \(I_{n} = 4\) and \(C_{n} = 2\). The dynamic route of the EG between the two participants is presented in Fig. 2b, which considers different probabilities of collusion and strict supervision strategies under the initial conditions. The simulation results indicate the same as in Fig. 2a that the only ESS point is (1, 0), that is, the container terminal tends to select collusion strategy, and the Port Authority tends to choose lax supervision strategy.


Simulations 1 and 2 have also proved the truth of Proposition 1.


Simulation 3: When \(F + S > I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n}\) and \(F > C_{g}\), we set \(F = 3\), \(C_{g} = 2\), \(S = 2\), \(I_{c} = 5\), \(C_{c} = 2\), \(I_{n} = 4\), and \(C_{n} = 2\). The dynamic route of the EG under the initial conditions between the two participants is presented in Fig. 3a, which considers different probabilities of the collusion strategy and strict supervision strategy. The simulation results show that there is no ESS point.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Dynamic route of the EG (\(F > C_{g}\))

Due to a lack of experience, and the Port Authority may have no more human, material and financial resources to select the strict supervision, the Port Authority can only occasionally maintain a strict supervision strategy, which contributes to the prevalence of collusion. The container terminals restrain intensive collusion when the strict supervision strategy is in place and the Port Authority dynamically adjusts its stringency according to the ratio of container terminals’ collusion strategy. Subsequently, the strategies of the container terminals and the Port Authority are dynamic along with changes in related market conditions.


Simulation 4: When \(F + S < I_{c} - C_{c} - I_{n} + C_{n} > 0\) and \(F > C_{g}\), we set the initial condition as follows, \(F = 0.5\), \(C_{g} = 0.2\), \(S = 0.4\), \(I_{c} = 5\), \(C_{c} = 2\), \(I_{n} = 4\) and \(C_{n} = 2\). Considering the different probabilities of collusion and supervision strategies under the initial conditions, the dynamic route of the EG between the two participants is shown in Fig. 3b. The simulation result indicates that the only ESS point is (1, 1), that is, the container terminal tends to select collusion strategy, and the Port Authority tends to choose strict supervision strategy.

Simulations 3 and 4 have also verified the conclusion of Proposition 2.

Conclusions

When the fine is less than the Port Authority’s cost, regardless of the magnitude between the sum of the fine and subsidy and the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy, the ESS will be collusion and lax supervision. When the fine is greater than the Port Authority’s cost, the ESS will be collusion and strict supervision, as the sum of the fine and subsidy is less than the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy. There is no ESS as the sum of fine and subsidy is greater than the welfare difference from the container terminal’s collusion strategy, as the welfare of collusion strategy provides the container terminal with the motivation to choose the collusion strategy, and the Port Authority will choose strict supervision to improve social welfare. Still, the high cost will harm the Port Authority’s positivity of supervision, and the Port Authority will choose the lax supervision strategy. The container terminal will have the motivation to select the collusion strategy, and this cycle will continue over and over again. These theoretical and simulation conclusions can guide and benefit relevant stakeholders in advancing the sustainable development of the CSSC. Finally, it should be noted that, future empirical research will be conducted in expanded directions.

The action of the two participants is not synchronized, either the container terminal’s action lags behind the Port Authority, or the Port Authority’s action lags behind the container terminal. The uncertainties are not only internal, but also external. The choosing of strategy not only depends on market environment, but also on participants themselves. Also, as the complex environment, this paper only takes into account the Port Authority and the container terminal, next, the future research will take into account more participants, for example, the liner enterprise, the freight forwarder, even the shipper.