1 Introduction

If Leo Tolstoy had written about innovation, his work might have started with “all innovation success stories are alike; each innovation failure fails in its own way”.Footnote 1 Much scholarship has been written about the institutional failure of patents in developing countries.Footnote 2 Almost nothing has been done about Russia.Footnote 3 However, what is distinctive about the Russian innovation case is that it does not fit the category of a developing country. Russian innovation fails in its own way. On the one hand, Russia is a sophisticated technological power that demonstrated that it is capable of producing innovation. Russian human capital in mathematics and information technologies is among the best in the world.Footnote 4 Russia leads in world exports of nuclear power plants.Footnote 5 Recently, Russia manifested its innovation capacity in the pharmaceutical industry despite it being primarily generic and critically dependent on imported medicines.Footnote 6 The 2020 surprise that came with the development of the Sputnik vaccine echoed the 1957 surprise from the Sputnik satellite, reminding the world once again that Russian technological power should not be underestimated.

On the other hand, the Sputnik vaccine is an outlier. Its development is a response to the health crisis and not an outcome of the market-based institutions for innovation. Behind the development of the Sputnik vaccine is the Gamaleya Institute, which for 100 years has been at the forefront of solving fundamental problems in microbiology, immunology, and virology and organizing mass vaccinations.Footnote 7 Similarly, KoviVac, another Russian vaccine against Covid-19, was developed by the Chumakov Centre which successfully introduced the polio vaccine nearly 80 years previously.Footnote 8 Russia’s breakthrough in Covid-19 vaccines development is the legacy of the alternative regulation of knowledge production that existed in the Soviet Union. Both the Gamaleya Institute and the Chumakov Centre developed Covid-19 vaccines relying on an extensive knowledge base accumulated long before Russia introduced market-based patent rules. But what might modern Russian pharmaceutical innovation be like if it could only be managed by institutions that make the best use of the Russian innovation capacity? Is Russia capable of advancing its domestic generic industry to an innovative level that will produce new molecules steadily?

Throughout its history, Russia has often experimented with institutions for innovation.Footnote 9 Some experiments have been successful; others have failed. The institutional experiments of the Soviet period turned its innovation system into one of the two most productive innovation systems in the world up until the late 1980s.Footnote 10 The Soviet period was a peak moment of Russian innovation. The number of inventions in the USSR was on par with the number of inventions in the U.S.Footnote 11 And the Soviet pace of industrialization and economic growth has had few equals in world history.Footnote 12

After the break-up of the Soviet Union, Russia once again experimented: it transplanted the globalized institution of patents and by doing this introduced high barriers to entry in innovation markets.Footnote 13 Since then, its innovation performance has been declining. The number of inventions in modern Russia has plummeted and currently lags behind the number of inventions in the U.S. approximately ten-fold.Footnote 14 The Russian economy has narrowed itself down to resource export: it is not diversified and is hugely dependent on world prices for oil and gas.Footnote 15 At the moment, Russia finds itself squeezed between the resource curse and its unrealized potential to innovate. In other words, Russian innovation has entered the moment of what venture capitalists describe as “the death valley curve”.Footnote 16

Russia needs to emerge from the other side of “the death valley curve”, and this matters both for the Russian people and for the rest of the world. For the Russian people, overcoming the innovation decline would result in economic and ideological gains: not only would Russians get a more sustainable model of economic growth, one more consistent with goals of sustainability, but they would also regain the image and pride of a nation capable of producing world-class innovation. For the rest of the world, Russian innovation capacity is important because it is a potential source of a more diversified economy and a tool for lifting Russia out of crony capitalism.Footnote 17 A Russia free from the resource curse and crony capitalists would become a more stable international partner.

As mentioned, the most recent big experiment that Russia has undertaken with institutions for innovation has been to transplant the globalized institution of patents. Patents create barriers to entry in innovation markets. Sometimes these barriers are justified because they incentivize competition, but sometimes they are not because they stifle it. The difference between these outcomes lies in the broader institutional context, such as the presence or absence of well-functioning markets. The article argues that the globalized institution of patents has been compromised in Russia because the barriers to entry that patents create are not justified in the absence of well-functioning markets. The article demonstrates that the danger of the institutional mismatch is the lost opportunities for Russia to grow knowledge and to diversify its economy. The crony capitalist state will magnify the social harms of the patent system. Western property rights in innovation in the hands of crony capitalists can lead to a paradoxical effect of more concentrated control of innovation by the network of cronies which is a threat both for national welfare and the rest of the world.

The rest of the article is structured as follows. Section 2 explains the institutions for innovation that Russia had in the Soviet period before it entered the moment of “the death valley curve”. The main practical idea behind the Soviet innovation system was to make knowledge flow. This idea was realized through the alternative to patents, the system of inventor’s certificates, and the safeguards against the lock on future innovation. Section 3 examines the introduction of a new institution for innovation, the globalized institution of patents, and evaluates the dangers it engenders in the Russian context. Patents have created high barriers to entry in innovation markets and overruled the previous principle of free knowledge flow. The institution of patents is examined in the context of Russian crony capitalism. Section 4 paints optimistic and pessimistic scenarios of how Russia could deal with its moment of crossing (or not) “the death valley curve”. Section 5 concludes.

2 Soviet Institutions for Innovation and Free Knowledge Flow

The Soviet innovation system, as mentioned, was one of the two most productive innovation systems in the world. Despite being isolated from foreign knowledge flows, the Soviet economy was able to make big jumps forward, such as the rapid transformation of an agricultural economy into an industrial one and ensuring self-sufficiency in heavy industry production.Footnote 18 How was the Soviet Union able to make such big jumps?

Soviet scholars agreed with their Western counterparts that technological innovation was important for economic and societal progress. They disagreed however on the point of how knowledge flow should be organized in the economy: Soviets argued that the economy should be organized in a way to allow the free flow of inventions.Footnote 19 There was a clear understanding in the Soviet Union that it would not be able to catch up with the West unless it lifted legal restrictions on knowledge flow. To put this idea into practice, the Soviets introduced an alternative to the patent system, the system of inventor’s certificates, as well as safeguards against the lock on future innovation which included broad exceptions to patentability and rules of discoveries.

2.1 Inventor’s Certificates

The key characteristic of the Soviet innovation system was managing two parallel legal institutions for inventions: inventor’s certificates and patents. Soviet inventors could choose which of these legal institutions to use. Most applied for inventor’s certificates.Footnote 20 The criteria for the grant of inventor’s certificates and patents were similar: the standard of invention was common for both legal institutions and consisted of novelty, industrial application, and from 1959 also usefulness.Footnote 21 What was distinctive about inventor’s certificates in comparison to patents was that the former incentivized inventors to transfer the exclusive right in an invention to the state. In return, inventors received guaranteed monetary rewards and social benefits such as priority rights for promotion, education, accommodation, etc.Footnote 22 In contrast, by applying for a patent, an inventor preserved the exclusive right but was not entitled to the mentioned benefits. The Soviet regulation of patents resembled the market-based regulation, in which a patent does not confer a reward but rather allows its holder to exploit the right to obtain the reward.

2.1.1 Liability Rule Instead of Exclusivity Rule

The transfer of an exclusive right to the state through the inventor’s certificate activated the rule known as the “liability rule”. Patents, on the other hand, activated the “exclusivity rule”. The distinction between liability rule and exclusivity rule is to be found in the classic article by Calabresi and Melamed.Footnote 23 The liability rule underlying the inventor’s certificates meant that an inventor could not exclude third parties from using the invention but had to be compensated for such use. In the Soviet system, compensation took the form of material rewards and social benefits. The size of the material reward depended on the economic usefulness of the invention which was defined according to the government’s methodology.Footnote 24 The measure was extensively implemented: by 1970, more than 76 million inventors and efficiency experts were rewarded.Footnote 25 In contrast, the exclusivity rule underlying patents allowed the patent holder to exclude anyone from the use of the invention. No reward was guaranteed because the patent holder had to put the invention into production in order to obtain a reward. In this case, the size of the reward depended on the capacity to exploit the patent.

The same Soviet inventor could not benefit from both legal institutions on different inventions. If the inventor held both the patent and inventor’s certificate, the material rewards and social benefits of the latter were withdrawn. Such strictness could be explained by the need to protect knowledge flow from attempts to play the system, for example, by compromising the openness of some parts of a technology by keeping other parts exclusive. And the system generally was framed in such a way as to make the liability rule the preferred choice of inventors. Enforcing the liability rule underlying inventor’s certificates ensured faster and easier knowledge flow to the public domain.

2.1.2 Active Diffusion of Inventions

Inventor’s certificates eliminated legal restrictions on the use of knowledge. From the moment an inventor’s certificate was issued, any Soviet enterprise could implement the invention in their production.Footnote 26 Nevertheless, although most inventions were free from legal restrictions on their use, the Soviets thought that passive knowledge flow was not enough. Their idea was to have knowledge actively diffused in the economy. For this purpose, in addition to state economic planning, the Soviets planned innovation.

In broad terms, the innovation cycle in the Soviet Union can be described as follows. Inventors, depending on whether they were employed or not, disclosed their initial idea to the enterprise or the NGO of All-Union Society for Inventors and Rationalizators (Efficiency Experts). This was the first step. The role of the first step was to help inventors technically (for example, to run experiments and develop a prototype) and legally (to draft and submit an application for an inventor’s certificate). Within enterprises, such work was done by bureaus for rationalization and inventiveness. These bureaus had to be established in each enterprise employing more than 500 people.Footnote 27 The bureaus accumulated knowledge and competence relevant to their industry by cooperating with similar bureaus in other enterprises and R&D institutes and by monitoring new inventions in the industry.Footnote 28 Many Soviet enterprises had in-house scientific-research laboratories (in 1967, there were 33,000 laboratories), and large enterprises established R&D institutes.Footnote 29 The role of bureaus and R&D institutes was crucial: as Kojevnikov points out, in the Soviet Union production was subordinated to research institutes and not vice versa.Footnote 30

The second step was the issuing of an inventor’s certificate by the Committee on Inventiveness. Formally, the Committee on Inventiveness was a predecessor of the modern Russian Patent Office, but the Committee’s role was much broader. In addition to examining applications for inventor’s certificates, the Committee on Inventiveness evaluated the usefulness of inventions. Usefulness was determined based on cumulative feedback that the Committee gathered from any enterprise or R&D institute.Footnote 31 The Committee on Inventiveness also coordinated the mentioned bureaus within enterprises.

The third step was to include a new invention in state planning. The Committee on Inventiveness sent the information about the issued inventor’s certificates to the State Committee on Science and Technology.Footnote 32 Relying on this information and also on the scientific findings of R&D institutes, the State Committee on Science and Technology sent their recommendations to the State Planning Committee. Then, every three months, the State Planning Committee sent plans for implementing new useful inventions to industrial ministries. These ministries converted these plans into specific assignments for the subordinated enterprises.Footnote 33 This is how Soviet enterprises both contributed to and benefited from the free flow of inventions.

What the Soviet system of inventor’s certificates created was the public domain of inventions. One can also see it as an example of networked open source cooperation, one that anticipated the development of open source innovation in the West. The Soviet public domain was, however, different from the Western system of publication of patents. The Soviet public domain grew faster because inventions became available for broad use immediately after the inventor’s certificate was issued. The Western public domain was then and continues to be rather an informational public domain: it signalled about new inventions but also about the legal restrictions which accompany them. The Soviet system of inventor’s certificates was an active public domain, whereas the Western system of patents has been a passive public domain. Soviet scholars considered the inventor’s certificates to be a better institutional solution than patents because the former allowed broader and faster diffusion of inventions in the economy.Footnote 34 The rate of diffusion of Soviet inventions was indeed high: in 1960, about 64% of all inventions and efficiency proposals were implemented in Soviet production, and there was constant pressure to increase this rate.Footnote 35

In summary, the Soviet system of inventor’s certificates incentivized inventors to transfer the exclusive right to the state. The underlying rule of inventor’s certificates was the liability rule. This rule prevented inventors from excluding third parties from the use of the invention but ensured that the inventor received compensation in the form of material rewards and social benefits.Footnote 36 Inventions under the system of inventor’s certificates entered the public domain almost immediately.Footnote 37 A complex infrastructure was set up to actively diffuse knowledge among all the Soviet enterprises.

One might ask: if the system of inventor’s certificates functioned so well, why were patents still an alternative legal institution for inventions in the Soviet Union? A plausible explanation could be that the Soviets wanted to preserve a legal institution that would facilitate the import of foreign technology. For foreign inventors, preserving the exclusive right was more familiar than navigating the deeply national inventor’s certificates system.

2.2 Safeguards Against the Lock on Future Innovation

2.2.1 Broad Exceptions to Patentability

In addition to the system of inventor’s certificates, ensuring free knowledge flow required a set of safeguards that prevented the lock on future innovation. Among the safeguards, there were broad exceptions to patentability. These were many, even though the share of patents in comparison to inventor’s certificates was very low. Exceptions in the pharmaceutical and IT industries were probably the biggest contrast with the modern globalized regulation of inventions. For instance, between 1924 and 1991, no product patents on pharmaceutical inventions were issued.Footnote 38 This exception cleared the path for other inventors to innovate around pharmaceutical invention and to figure out more efficient processes for producing the same substance. Not allowing patents on pharmaceutical products was a practice that was followed by many countries in the 20th century. In the IT industry, exceptions to patentability extended to algorithms and business methods.Footnote 39

2.2.2 Rules of Discoveries

Another safeguard against the lock on future innovation was a standalone legal institution of discoveries.Footnote 40 Discoveries were defined as “the establishment of the unknown before, objectively existing regularities, characteristics, and phenomena of the material world”.Footnote 41 The purpose of the legal institution of discoveries was to distinguish scientific advancements from inventions. A certificate of discovery, similar to an inventor’s certificate, entitled its holder to material rewards and social benefits, but no one obtained the exclusive right, including the Soviet state itself. The regulation of discoveries targeted the problem of “dual-use inventions” which embodied findings of basic science and industrially useful innovation.

In pursue of exporting an open knowledge culture, the Soviet Union was the principal advocate in the WIPO for the conclusion of an international treaty on discoveries.Footnote 42 The proposal faced some hesitation because the majority of the countries did not provide protection of discoveries. Eventually, the Geneva Treaty on the International Recording of Scientific Discoveries was adopted in 1978, although with an explicit reservation that the registration of discoveries will be voluntary without any legal effect (e.g. on conferring economic rights to authors of discoveries except the fact of recognition).Footnote 43 Discoveries recorded under the Treaty could be used without any restriction. The Treaty, therefore, became the first multilateral agreement facilitating access to scientific information.

To conclude, the key practical idea of the Soviet innovation system was an emphasis on knowledge flow. Under the system of inventor’s certificates, inventions entered the public domain faster and were used simultaneously by more enterprises than under the patent system. Broad exceptions to patentability and the regulation of discoveries created safeguards against the lock on future innovation. The Soviet innovation system was deeply national and was subordinated to the logic of the state-planned economy. After the break-up of the Soviet Union, Russia started to transition to a market economy and joined the processes of liberalization of world trade. Part of the deal to join the world trade club required Russia to transplant the globalized institution of patents which stood the cornerstone of its innovation system on its head.

3 Russian Institutions for Innovation and Entering “the Death Valley Curve”

The break-up of the Soviet Union was a shock to its innovation system. The established links between R&D institutes and enterprises were broken as a result of chaotic privatization. The logic of state planning of innovation was abandoned. The country’s innovation performance plummeted. The Soviet idea of free knowledge flow was substituted by the idea of having property rights in innovation. It has now been 30 years since Russia introduced patents as the only legal institution for inventions. This section focuses on this change and analyses the role of patents in the current Russian context, which includes malfunctioning markets and crony capitalism.

3.1 The Process of Legal Transplantation

In this section, I address how and why Russia substituted the idea of free knowledge flow with the idea of property rights in innovation. The break-up of the Soviet Union happened at a time when the world was engaged in the process of regulatory globalization. Regulatory globalization was framed as a condition for the liberalization of international trade under the WTO framework. Before concluding the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property,Footnote 44 the U.S. reached bilateral agreements with many countries aiming to raise their standards of intellectual property protection before the formal multilateral negotiations at the WTO. This process is well documented in the literature.Footnote 45 The bilateral agreements and the TRIPS Agreement became the source of legal transplantation of intellectual property rules.Footnote 46

Russia was no exception to this process.Footnote 47 In 1990, when the Soviet Union still existed, the bilateral agreement with the U.S. required the Soviet Union to issue both product and process patents in all areas of technology.Footnote 48 The “patents without discrimination” rule would later become the cornerstone of the TRIPS Agreement.Footnote 49 Agreeing to this rule for the Soviet Union meant that it had to discard the system of inventor’s certificates and narrow down the exceptions to patentability which had included product patents in pharmaceuticals, algorithms and business methods patents.

After the break-up of the Soviet Union, Russia maintained the course that the U.S.–USSR bilateral agreement set out. Russia, similar to other post-Soviet countries, started wholesale legal reforms introducing market institutions. The U.S., in order to accelerate these reforms, promised to grant the most-favoured-nation principle if countries implemented legal reforms fast.Footnote 50 In 2006, the U.S. concluded a bilateral agreement with Russia requiring it to “ensure that any changes in its laws, regulations and other measures made prior to its accession to the WTO … do not result in a lesser degree of consistency than exists on this date with the provisions of the TRIPS Agreement”.Footnote 51 As a result, Russia adopted the standards of intellectual property protection that the TRIPS Agreement required long before its formal accession to the WTO which happened only in 2012. One of the key standards was introducing the globalized institution of patents which creates strong property rights in innovation with narrow exceptions.

3.2 The Globalized Institution of Patents

Although patents existed in the Soviet Union as an alternative legal institution for inventions, their share in the overall numbers of inventions was marginal. As a result of the legal transplantation mentioned above, patents became the only legal institution for inventions in Russia. Introducing patents in what used to be the active public domain of inventions had retrospective and prospective effects. The retrospective effect was that the Soviet system of inventor’s certificates was abolished, and it became possible to exchange the inventor’s certificates which were still in force for patents.Footnote 52 When such exchange occurred, it led to erecting barriers to entry where previously there were none.Footnote 53

The prospective effect was that all new inventions became subject to property rights which delayed entry of knowledge to the public domain. The duration of the exclusive right was prolonged from 15 to 20 years.Footnote 54 A broader subject matter became patentable: “a technical solution in any field that refers to a product (in particular, device, substance, microorganism strains, cell culture of plants or animals) or a process (a process of affecting a material object using material means)”.Footnote 55 Such an extended scope of patentable subject matter cancelled the Soviet exception of not allowing product patents in pharmaceuticals. From 2014, in addition to product and process patents, “use patents” started to be issued.Footnote 56 The further extension of the scope of patentable subject matter creates more barriers to entry and favours, in particular, patent holders in the pharmaceutical industry. They can accumulate large patent portfolios consisting of product, process, and now also use patents, all of which can relate to the same molecule. Patent portfolios create much higher barriers to entry than a single patent.

Soviet rules which prevented the lock on future innovation were erased. For instance, besides product patents in pharmaceuticals, patents on algorithms and business methods also started to be issued. The new rule only excludes patents on business methods and software if the patent application concerns these subjects as such.Footnote 57 The way out, as the rule itself suggests, is to draft patent applications where these subjects are embedded indirectly, for example, in the form of a feature of a device. The legal institution of discoveries was also eliminated. Without discoveries, the line between basic science and commercially useful innovation became blurred. “Dual-use” innovation was gated by barriers to entry too.

In sum, when Russia transplanted the globalized institution of patents, it introduced barriers to entry in innovation markets. The extended term and scope of exclusivity, together with the narrowed exceptions to patentability, strengthened these barriers to entry. Under the new patent system, knowledge does not flow to the public domain until the exclusivity expires (potentially up to 20 years plus the patent term extension for pharmaceutical products). And successive patents on minor variations of an invention may prolong this beyond the term of any single patent. The public domain of knowledge thus grows much more slowly than under the system of inventor’s certificates.

Patents create barriers to entry in innovation markets.Footnote 58 This is because patents, in fact, are rights which give monopoly pricing power and ability to prevent the follow-on innovation. Patent systems put a price on access to knowledge. The discussion then comes around to what extent such barriers to entry are necessary for innovation. If barriers to entry are too high, they hamper competition because the cost of entry rises and can become prohibitive.Footnote 59 To date, there is no econometric evidence that the institutions that the TRIPS Agreement created have increased innovation.Footnote 60 Patents are only one of the institutions for innovation and cannot be analysed outside the context of other institutions. The effectiveness of patents depends, as Maskus has noted, on other market factors.Footnote 61 For example, it is reasonable to assume that barriers to entry are justified only if they are placed in well-functioning markets. Well-functioning markets are those where there is strong and dynamic domestic competition. In Russia though, markets are anything but well-functioning as the rest of the article demonstrates. The economy is not diversified and is governed by networks of crony capitalists. In these institutional settings, the role of barriers to entry can become especially dangerous, a fact that has been ignored in the arguments for patents.

3.3 The State of Russian Innovation

The main problem of the Russian innovation system, which is recognized both inside and outside of Russia, is the “mismatch of the innovation cycle”. In other words, the government funding of R&D is used inefficiently, universities produce results unrelated to industrial needs, and the industry itself demonstrates little interest in innovation. The Russian 2016 Strategy for Scientific and Technological Development signals the weak cooperation between research and business and the lack of coordination between national, regional, industry-specific and corporate levels of funding of R&D.Footnote 62 The 2016 Global Innovation Index Report also underlines the Russian problem of “fragmentation and lack of contingency between the components of the innovation system”.Footnote 63 Poor interaction of key actors of the national innovation system is what precludes Russia from creating high-tech value chains. Taken independently, the actors of Russian innovation system are not weak, but what prevents them from interacting efficiently with each other is the environment of poorly functioning markets.

Well-functioning markets indeed did not spring up overnight after the system of state innovation planning was abolished. Most of the Soviet innovation infrastructure ceased to exist. The Soviet value chains were broken as a collapse of one enterprise launched a “domino effect”, leading to the collapse of associated laboratories and research institutes.Footnote 64 As a result of privatization, new owners, having obtained discretion to decide on an enterprise’s structure, decided to liquidate bureaus for the facilitation of inventiveness, laboratories, and research institutes which had lost their purpose in a system of mismatched social practices and new formal rules.Footnote 65 This is what happened at the level of enterprise.

At the level of government, the key Soviet organizations responsible for state planning of innovation were abolished (these include the State Committee on Science and Technology, the State Planning Committee, and the industrial ministries). The role of the few organizations that remained was narrowed down. For example, the NGO of the All-Union Society for Inventors and Rationalizators (Efficiency Experts) lost most of its members (from 14 million in 1988 to 100,000 in 2019).Footnote 66 Today, it is rather a sad artefact of the past and no longer plays a visible role in the innovation cycle. Another example of narrowed organizational functionality is the Russian Patent Office, which formally is the successor of the Soviet Committee of Inventiveness. This Soviet body, as mentioned, used to coordinate the network for facilitation of inventiveness, to examine the usefulness of inventions, and to submit inputs for state planning of diffusion of inventions in the economy. In contrast, the functions of the Russian Patent Office are much narrower. It examines patent applications and issues patents, but it no longer plays a role similar to that of its predecessor in the innovation cycle.

The elimination of most Soviet organizations responsible for state innovation planning and narrowing down of their successors’ functionality were seen as necessary measures to create space for market-based innovation. However, the expectation that business would quickly take the state’s place in innovation markets was an illusion. Russian innovation could not operate in the vacuum fuelled only by the ideology that the market would sort out all the problems. Russian innovation needed real institutions which create the market dynamic. In an attempt to introduce such a dynamic, the Russian government started to borrow the Western models of organizations for development: technology parks, accelerators, and venture capital funds. These organizations for development are old wine in a new bottle. Funded and controlled by the state, they are the resurrection of the state-dominated innovation system, albeit with what is often seen as a poorer design than its Soviet predecessor.Footnote 67

For example, Skolkovo, modelled on the Silicon Valley, was founded and fully funded by the Russian government. Its main function is to provide legal and business consulting services to the selected participants. The limited outreach of Skolkovo created “a gated community … almost closed-off to outsiders”.Footnote 68 In regard to the venture capital market in Russia, as noted by Trofimova, its large share is associated with the state capital.Footnote 69 One example is the Russian Venture Company which is 100% state-owned.Footnote 70 Another example is the Internet Initiatives Development Fund, the capital of which is, presumably, a donation of a large oil and gas corporation.Footnote 71 The donation followed soon after President’s Putin call for “looking together for the sources to fill the fund”.Footnote 72 Today the Internet Initiatives Development Fund has grown to be one of the biggest players in the Russian venture capital market: it accounts for nearly half of venture transactions in Russia.Footnote 73

Despite the similar appearance of Russian and Western organizations for development, the similarities are only superficial. What Russia does in practice through these organizations is to distribute state grants. In December 2020, the Russian government adopted an Act with a telling title: “On some issues of implementing state support of innovation activity, including by venture and (or) direct financing of innovative projects …” (emphasis added).Footnote 74 The act introduces rules to evaluate the efficiency of state funding of innovation. One of the assessment indicators is the number of intellectual property rights, including patents, obtained as a result of the innovation projects funded by the state.Footnote 75 However, the act shows no interest in who obtains these intellectual property rights. No requirements such as the local use of the invention or reasonable licensing terms are imposed on a patentholder who benefited from state funding. The efficiency of state funding is thus measured by the number of created barriers to entry in innovation markets. No attention is paid to who is behind those barriers and whether they are justified.

The patent system, as observed by Mazzucato, makes it possible to socialize costs and at the same time to privatize profits from innovation.Footnote 76 Russia is no exception. The Russian grant system through the organizations for development has limited outreach and does not contribute much to the market dynamic. What it does instead is socializing costs of innovation while imposing no restrictions on extracting private profits. But the Russian problem is bigger than that. What happens if barriers to entry in innovation markets end up in the hands of crony capitalists?

3.4 Russia in the Hands of Cronies

“Crony capitalism” defines situations when business elites operate relying on close personal ties with political elites.Footnote 77 Cronyism usually implies corruption and rent-seeking associated with such businesses as oil and gas.Footnote 78 Modern Russia is often characterized as a crony capitalist state.Footnote 79 In 2016, Russia was ranked first in the Economist’s index of crony capitalism.Footnote 80 The index captures the share of rent-seeking businesses in a country’s wealth. Forbes publishes the annual list of the world’s wealthiest public companies called “The Forbes Global 2000”.Footnote 81 Russia’s top five companies in this list are from the oil and gas industry.Footnote 82 There is a well-established literature documenting the Russian resource curse and how it affects the country’s capacity to develop market institutions.Footnote 83

Patents were discussed earlier as barriers to entry in innovation markets. Crony capitalism is an institutionalized form of barrier to entry because new market entrants are normally excluded from the established crony networks by all means. Unlike patents, there is no term of expiry on a crony network. If exceptions are ever made, a new entrant is expected to reinforce the cronies’ network.

What is the role of property rights in crony capitalism? It seems natural to think that crony capitalism devastates the demand for property rights protection and other market institutions. However, the evidence does not support this assumption because there is a wide disparity in the levels of property rights protection in crony capitalist countries.Footnote 84 In some countries, the high export prices on oil and gas even result in strengthening and consolidating property rights.Footnote 85 In fact, cronyism in developed countries is part of the formal economy while in developing countries it is part of the shadow economy.Footnote 86 Cronies in developed countries, and Russia is no exception, seek to legitimize their status by consolidating property rights. As Pistor argued, it is legal coding that generates wealth in assets.Footnote 87 To apply her argument to Russian settings, it is legal coding that can legitimize the wealth of cronies. Patents are one of the tools which can protect cronies’ major concentrations of power.

The International Property Rights Index gives Russian patent protection a grade of 7.6, on the scale from the lowest (0) to the highest (10) levels, which globally positions Russia as the 45th country out of 129.Footnote 88 Going back to Mazzucato’s argument, patents are often used to socialize costs and privatize profits which leads to value extraction. Value extraction is the ultimate goal of crony capitalists. The rational actor model would imply crony capitalists using patents not only to generate even bigger profits but also to slow down the development of innovation that threatens the stability of their business models. Diversifying the economy is a threat to crony capitalists, and this is where patents as an institution of public welfare can be dangerously compromised in Russia.

By now it should be clear that the case of Russian innovation is particular due to the rampant introduction of entry barriers in innovation markets and the emergence of crony capitalists who can make use of these barriers for their own benefit. Such a combination entails two big dangers. The first danger is lost opportunities for Russia to grow knowledge. In the absence of well-functioning markets, property rights in innovation have created unjustified barriers to entry in innovation markets. Under the new patent system, the knowledge does not flow as fast as it did in the Soviet system of inventor’s certificates. The stifled knowledge flow prevents the Russian economy, which is critically dependent on natural resources export, from diversifying. Russia cannot exercise the full potential of its highly qualified human capital and make use of its innovation capacity. The second danger is that strong property rights in innovation can be used to preserve the power of crony capitalist elites. This, again, not only hampers the Russian capacity to diversify the economy but also poses a military danger to the rest of the world. It is one thing when cronies extract rents from oil and gas, but it is entirely another thing when they use those rents to develop dual-use technologies such as artificial intelligence.Footnote 89

Among the countries on top of the crony capitalist index, only Russia has the legacy of one of the two most productive national innovation systems in the world. This legacy combined with the unjustified barriers to entry in innovation markets can lead to the high concentration of ownership of innovation. The globalized patent rules that Russia transplanted into its law are likely to be used to reinforce the power of a dangerous form of crony capitalism in which political elites extract rents through an innovation agenda. As a result, the high concentration of ownership of knowledge will hinder the development of open and effective competition that could otherwise resist the proliferation of cronyism. In a crony capitalist state, social harms of the patent system are prone to amplify.

4 Scenarios for the Future

Finding itself in a “death valley curve” moment, Russian innovation faces two scenarios, one optimistic and the other pessimistic. The positive scenario is that Russia overcomes the curve with regained pride, a diversified economy, and a promise of international stability. To do so, Russia has to adjust its patent system to grow and diffuse knowledge. Russia cannot go back to the Soviet system of inventor’s certificates but what it can do is to minimize the introduced barriers to entry in innovation markets. Minimizing barriers to entry would require, among other things, the broadening of exceptions to patentability, strengthening of the standard of invention, and preventing unjustified prolongation of the exclusive right. The goal of readjusting the Russian patent system should be to allow knowledge to grow and to flow. Those barriers to entry which Russia would decide to preserve should be re-evaluated against the other market institutions.

It has not been uncommon in the past for countries to readjust their patent systems multiple times following their progress of technological catch-up. Japan, for example, between 1950 and 1980 placed a great emphasis on knowledge flow and domestic competition. Its laws required Japanese firms which imported foreign technologies to share them with other domestic firms.Footnote 90 It was only after this policy helped Japan to increase its innovation capabilities, that it was ready to strengthen its patent system to face a patent race with other technological powers.Footnote 91 Although under the TRIPS Agreement the adjustments of a similar scope are no longer possible, countries still have some regulatory sovereignty in managing their patent systems.Footnote 92

The pessimistic scenario is that Russia remains stuck in “the death valley curve”. Strengthening or simply preserving the existing barriers to entry in innovation markets in Russian settings would lead to conserving the crony elites who would use patent rights to legitimize their wealth. Patents in the hands of cronies magnify the tragedy of private value extraction at the cost of the public. For the Russian people, preserving the current system means the lost opportunity to grow knowledge and diversify the economy. The longer Russia stays in “the death valley curve”, the more it loses. While knowledge grows exponentially elsewhere, Russian barriers to entry in innovation markets stifle its capacity to innovate. The innovation gap between Russia and the developed countries widens, “the death valley curve” deepens, and it becomes harder to get out. These are the consequences for Russia. For the rest of the world, they are bitter too. At the first glance, one could see little value in saving the dying “Russian Bear” which for many was an irritation and threat during the Cold War. However, the danger is that barriers to entry in the hands of cronies have the potential to make the “Russian Bear” even more brutal. The Western system of property rights could lead to an unexpected effect of more concentrated control over innovation by the networks of Russian cronies, helping to reinforce their extractive business models and, consequently, conserve their power.

5 Conclusion

The article has demonstrated why and how the Russian innovation system entered the moment of “the death valley curve”. Its predecessor, the Soviet innovation system, had been on another side of the valley, and its innovation performance was on par with other developed countries. The main idea of the Soviet innovation system was to make knowledge flow by relying on the system of inventor’s certificates and safeguards against the lock on future innovation. After modern Russia introduced patents as the only institution for inventions, it created high barriers to entry in innovation markets. These barriers to entry are not justified in the absence of other institutions like well-functioning markets. The article argued, therefore, that the globalized institution of patents has been compromised in Russia.

The danger of the institutional mismatch is the lost opportunities for Russia to grow knowledge and to diversify its economy. Another danger is that in the context of Russian crony capitalism, Western property rights in innovation can end up in the hands of cronies who use them to legitimize their wealth. These institutions thus can conserve crony elites but do not serve the Russian people. What the Russian innovation system does now is providing the opportunity to extract rents for multinationals and local cronies. Apart from reinforcing the rent-seeking activities, Western property rights in the hands of crony capitalists can magnify the social harms of the patent system by slowing down Russia’s technological progress and repressing the development of a more diversified economy.

To have a better future, Russia has to lift itself out of crony capitalism. Russia has no choice: it cannot return to the Soviet system, nor can it stay in “the death valley curve”. To climb out of the valley, with regained pride and the image of a nation capable of producing world-class innovation, Russia has to ask itself how to make knowledge flow in the system. A way to do so is to minimize the unjustified barriers to entry in innovation markets. The case of Russian innovation is worth keeping an eye on because, depending on what happens, it can be either a source of major negative disruption or positive stability for the rest of the world.