FormalPara Key Points for Decision Makers

Our study provides a comprehensive overview of recent cost-effectiveness thresholds, and contains information on Central and Eastern European countries, which are cited less frequently in the literature.

Cost-effectiveness thresholds in relation to GDP per capita in Central and Eastern European countries, and particularly in Hungary, are higher compared with Western European countries.

The baseline cost-effectiveness threshold in Hungary was proposed to be lowered and equity considerations regarding severity and rarity of the diseases were recommended to be introduced.

1 Introduction

Policy makers all over the world are struggling with developing transparent and verifiable approaches to allocate scarce healthcare resources to the most valuable technologies. Several countries have adopted mandatory cost-effectiveness analysis to inform coverage decisions, where health gains are expressed as quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs). Incremental cost-effectiveness ratios without a cost-effectiveness threshold (CET) cannot determine whether the gain from a new technology is worth paying for, as decision-makers need to know the maximum amount of incremental financial resources that is considered appropriate to pay for one additional unit of health gain [1].

To manage increasing demands is a particular challenge in countries with limited financial resources compared with more affluent countries in Western Europe or North America. Although Hungary implemented mandatory health technology assessment (HTA) methodologies starting from 2004, including cost-effectiveness analysis to support pricing and reimbursement decisions of new pharmaceuticals and later expanded this to medical devices as well [2], the potential to support efficient resource allocation has not been fully realised.

In the initial period only an implicit CET was applied in Hungary, then in the 2011 update of the methodological guidelines the conventionally used two to three times the gross domestic product (GDP) per capita per QALY gained threshold was published by the Ministry of Human Resources [3]. From 2017, the lower threshold was eliminated from the methodological guidelines, and only the single CET of three times GDP per capita (44,845 € in 2019) has been applied [4]. With the economic growth in Hungary, the actual threshold has grown over the years, and has even surpassed the constant thresholds in Western European countries. To put this into context, the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) in England has used an explicit and constant CET of between 20,000 and £30,000 GBP per QALY gained [5], which has not been changed with the growth rate of the British economy. The NICE thresholds correspond to 22,785 € and 34,178 € in 2019 in actual exchange rate, the lower bound is 51% and the upper bound is 76% of what is used in Hungary for coverage decisions (see Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source of exchange rates: [6]

Actual value of the Hungarian CETs compared to the general UK NICE CETs between 2011 and 2019 in Euro. CET cost-effectiveness threshold, NICE National Institute For Health and Care Excellence.

This difference between the two countries is particularly striking when we also take into account that per capita GDP in Hungary was 40% of that in the UK in average between 2011 and 2019. It is worth noting that the Hungarian policy-making practice of reducing the number of CETs goes against the international trends and even the UK practice. In the UK end-of-life criteria were introduced in 2009 and the practice has led to the application of a maximum weight of 2.5 from a starting point of £20,000 per QALY [7, 8]. In 2017 further thresholds were introduced for highly specialised technologies (HST), treatments for very rare conditions and fast-track medicines (£100,000 per QALY—320% of the GDP per capita), which can be increased up to £300,000 (960% of the GDP per capita) in case of curative therapies with over 30 QALY gain [9]. A comparison of the Hungarian and UK CETs between 2011 and 2019 is shown in Fig. 2.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source of GDP per capita: [10]

Hungarian and UK NICE CETs between 2011 and 2019 relative to the GDP per capita. CET cost-effectiveness threshold, EoL end-of-life, HST highly specialised technology, NICE National Institute For Health And Care Excellence.

Setting the appropriate CET is challenging. If the threshold is set too low, treatments with good value for money will be rejected, resulting in a loss of health for the society [1]. On the other hand the very high CET leads both to the inefficient allocation of resources [11] and to a suboptimal functioning of HTA in supporting coverage decisions, as technologies might easily meet the cost-effectiveness criteria but will still not be reimbursed [12] or will be reimbursed with hidden restrictions [13, 14] due to unaffordability caused by the budget constraints, the primary cause of patient access limitations [15]. Therefore, CET needs to be better aligned with the country's financial resources to help meet the payer's requirement to maximise health from the budget available for the introduction of new technologies.

The other concern with the Hungarian CET is that the application of a rigid single threshold does not allow the use of the HTA framework for adopting highly specialised technologies (e.g., orphan medicines for treating ultra-rare diseases), which are very expensive and likely cannot meet the cost-effectiveness criterion. Consequently, in Hungary these technologies are reimbursed without any judgement on the value-based price often on a named patient basis [16].

Due to the expiry of the current guidance at the end of 2020, the College of Healthcare Professionals established a Guideline Revision Committee (VB, IB, ZK, AZ and eight other non-author members) to update the “Guideline for Economic Evaluations in Healthcare in Hungary” [4]. Members were appointed by the College of Healthcare Professionals (institution of Health Care State Secretariat of the Ministry of Human Capacities) representing academia, National Health Insurance Fund, and the national HTA agency in Hungary. The head of the national HTA Agency chaired the Committee. As part of this work, the Committee asked the Hungarian Health Economics Association (ISPOR Hungary Chapter) to lay out new recommendations for a revised CET in Hungary.

The current study is a summary of the work of the Association's Threshold Working Group (SK, BN, DE, AZ and two other non-author members) to provide a scientifically sound basis for developing recommendations. The objective of this work was threefold. The main aim of this work was to provide recommendations for a new CET to be used for evaluating cost-effectiveness in the Hungarian healthcare system. In order to develop an informed proposal, it was necessary to know the practices of other countries in setting thresholds. Therefore, the second aim of the work was to collect the explicit values of CETs from the CEA guidelines in the European countries and assess how these relate to the countries' GDP per capita, a proxy for economic constraints on health spending. In this way, we can assess how the Hungarian threshold compares with thresholds in other European countries. The other aim was to review what additional factors were taken into account when assessing the cost-effectiveness of a technology, represented by the criteria used to apply multiple CETs.

2 Methods

2.1 Identification of Guidelines

We identified HTA agencies in Europe using a list from a recently published review [17]. For each HTA agency, we searched the websites, looking for publicly available methodological guidance (in any language), either as guidelines or as methodological advisory documents. For countries where such documents were not available, local experts were asked to provide references for documents describing the value of CET. The participants were identified in an iterative process in which the professional networks of the Threshold Working Group were used. The main selection criteria were familiarity with cost-effectiveness thresholds and HTA in their own country. Overall, nine experts from the Czech Republic, Denmark, Ireland, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Slovenia and Slovakia contributed to the process.

2.2 Document Review and Data Extraction

After identifying the relevant documents, the following data were extracted for each country: (1) name, year and website location of the guidance document, (2) language of the document, (4) text related to CETs, (5) text on the criteria for multiple thresholds, and (6) values and units of CETs. A data-extraction form was developed and tested by two authors (SK and AZ) on a sample of documents in English and Hungarian to check the feasibility of the process and to ensure that the data collected was suitable and sufficient for the aim of the study. Members of the Thresholds Working Group between May and July 2020 then used the revised extraction form. Two senior reviewers (AZ, SK) then compared the extracted data with the original documents. The threshold values used in 2019 were converted to Euros based on the annual exchange rate in 2019. GDPs of the countries in 2019 were extracted from EUROSTAT and OECD databases. The review of the guidelines was complemented by a review of scientific articles on CETs in European countries to gain a deeper understanding of current trends in the evolution of CETs in this region and an explanation on the rationale for changes. As our aim was to analyse CETs from original sources, we present the results of the data obtained from the guidelines only.

2.3 Development of Recommendations

The development of the proposal for the Hungarian CET was carried out in four consecutive steps. First, the Threshold Working Group summarised the findings of the review of guidance documents, agreed on principles to be considered, and proposed options for the use of the CETs. Participants were senior health economists from university centres and pharmaceutical companies with extensive experience in conducting economic evaluations.

Second, the results of the review and the proposed options for CETs were presented and discussed in detail at a public forum of the Hungarian Health Economics Association in June 2020. Attendees were voluntary experts representing multiple stakeholder groups, including academia, institutes in the public sector, the healthcare industry and market access consultants. The presentation was followed by an open discussion, where participants made comments and suggestions on what preferences should be considered when setting the value of CETs. These were then summarised by the Threshold Working Group and used to describe the key principles to be considered when developing alternative options for the new CETs. The summary document was made publicly accessible on the Association’s website (www.metaweb.hu).

In a third step, the proposed principles and options were presented to the Guideline Revision Committee, which held three online meetings between July and September 2020, where members shared their views, suggested further options, requested additional data analysis, and made textual recommendations on the content of the text related to CETs. The trade-offs of the alternative options were then carefully considered. Reaching consensus was facilitated by the chair of the Working Group (the president of the Hungarian Health Economics Association), who produced a single working document that reflected the advantages and disadvantages of each approach. The working document was presented to the group, iteratively discussed, and narrowed down to one approach until full consensus was reached within the group. Historical data on QALY gains were analysed: the absolute and relative differences in QALYs were calculated based on all HTA dossiers at the national HTA agency in the last 12-month period (i.e., between July 2019 and June 2020) and the distribution of health gains for those recently assessed technologies was examined to simulate the impact of introducing health gains as a criterion for using different levels of CETs. After evaluating the results of the simulations, the recommendations for the CETs were further refined by consensus of the Committee participants.

Fourth, the draft recommendations were then shared in a report format with the representatives of 12 organizations in November 2020, who were invited based on their expertise or involvement in HTA processes. These included HTA and reimbursement decision-makers, pharmaceutical and medical device manufacturers, healthcare providers, consulting companies, and patient organizations. A second public forum was held to clarify stakeholder questions on the draft recommendations. Ten out of the 12 major associations of these stakeholders submitted written feedback as part of the public consultation. These were then evaluated by the Revision Committee and a decision was made by consensus as to which recommendation should be accepted, accepted with changes, or rejected. The final responses were provided to each stakeholder group in written form.

3 Results

3.1 Review of Guidelines

The search of HTA agencies’ websites and the information provided by local experts led to the review of CETs from 26 countries. No guidelines could be found in six of the countries examined (Croatia, Denmark, Greece, Malta, Romania, Spain) and there were eight countries (Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Portugal, Switzerland), where no explicit values for the CET were given in the guidelines. In the latter group of countries, CET is either implicit or they use different approaches to support reimbursement decisions (e.g., clinical effectiveness, market price, budgetary impact, etc.). Twelve countries provided information on the CETs in guidelines for the economic evaluation of health technologies. These are summarised in Table 1. More detailed information on the original sources of CETs can be found in the Electronic Supplementary Material S1.

Table 1 Thresholds stated in official guidelines (both single and multiple thresholds)

3.2 Threshold Relative to GDP

CETs should be related in some way to the health budget, whether it is fixed or flexible, and the health budget is mainly determined by the economic constraints of the country, for which GDP per capita is a good proxy indicator. CETs in relation to the GDP per capita were compared to benchmark with regard to how much the economic constraints of the countries differ and to what extent the thresholds follow these ratios.

While all (5/5) of the higher income countries (i.e., higher GDP per capita than the EU-28 average in 2019, 28,610 € [28]) use multiple level thresholds, most (6/7) of the countries with lower GDP per capita (i.e., lower GDP per capita than the EU-28 average) tend to use a single CET (except for Lithuania). In Central and Eastern European (CEE) countries the CET in relation to the GDP per capita tends to be higher compared with higher income countries (see Fig. 3).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Cost-effectiveness thresholds per GDP per capita (including multiple thresholds) vs. GDP per capita. Note: Black dots represent either the single CET or the lowest value of CET if multiple thresholds are used. GBR United Kingdom, HUN Hungary, IRL Ireland, LTU Lithuania, LTV Latvia, NLD The Netherlands, NOR Norway, POL Poland, SVK Slovakia, SVN Slovenia, SWE Sweden

The current CET in Hungary is not only higher in nominal value than the threshold applied by NICE and SMC in the UK, but it is one of the highest among European countries relative to GDP per capita (except for the highest threshold used in Lithuania, under certain conditions). The high value of the CETs in most of the CEE countries is especially noticeable if we depict the lowest levels of the CETs used in each country (black dots in Fig. 2). Above these levels, reimbursement is not guaranteed. The assessment of the cost-effectiveness of a technology is judged against criteria that apply to the use of higher-level CETs (such as in the Netherlands, Norway, Lithuania, etc.). This suggests that CEE countries (and Hungary in particular) have set minor barriers to technologies to meet the requirement of proving to be cost-effective.

3.3 Use of Multiple Thresholds

Several countries have adopted the idea that it would be inappropriate to use a single threshold to decide whether to include new technologies in the reimbursement scheme [29], incorporating equity considerations in their funding decision. Therefore, they have proposed the use of multiple-level thresholds or scales of ceilings as references for the ICER (see Table 2). Main factors considered for using higher thresholds were: burden of the disease, expressed as absolute or proportional shortfall of QALYs; rare disease designation; and end-of-life treatment status. This means that some societies' willingness to pay for an additional QALY is likely higher for direct life-saving treatments than for interventions that target milder diseases or that slightly reduce the risk of an otherwise healthy population. However, definite conclusions on this can only be made after a thorough investigation of the preferences of the members of societies.

Table 2 Countries with multiple thresholds

The lower limits of multilevel thresholds range from 0.3 to 1.8 times the GDP per capita, while the highest boundaries are between 0.7 and 5.0 times (10.2 for rare diseases) the GDP per capita. Thresholds higher than 1.8 times the GDP per capita are only used when the relative (or absolute) health gain is high. Therefore, those who are more seriously ill are guaranteed a greater share of the resources.

3.4 Proposal for the Hungarian Cost-Effectiveness Threshold (CET)

Based on the results presented in Sects. 3.2 and 3.3, the Threshold Working Group identified two major problems related to the Hungarian CET, which need to be addressed: (1) it is too high compared to other European countries, 2) it does not reflect other healthcare priorities.

3.4.1 Considerations Related to the Level of Hungarian CET

The review revealed that CET in Hungary is not only higher than that of the UK, but relative to the GDP per capita, it is higher than explicit CETs in most of the other European countries. The health expenditure as a share of GDP in Hungary in 2019 is only about 6.4%, far below the EU 27 average of 8.3% [30]. Given that health expenditure as a share of GDP is already low in Hungary, a high threshold to the GDP per capita (i.e., three times the GDP per capita) leads to an unfair spending structure. This is because although new technologies might be nominally 'cost-effective' according to the CET criterion, not every new technology that achieves this will be affordable, and decisions are ultimately made based on lobbying by certain interest groups. In order to take into account the resource constraints, the Revision Committee concluded that Hungarian CET should be reduced for the majority of health technologies and therefore suggested to set the reference CET to 1.5 times the GDP per capita, which is in nominal value (22,422 EUR) similar to what is used in Western European countries (see Table 2), hence it would be difficult to challenge its acceptance by different stakeholder groups.

3.4.2 Equity Considerations

The lower level of CET itself does not fully represent the societal preference of a more equitable distribution of health and healthcare. Much of the literature suggests that resource allocation decisions should also take into account the relative social value of QALYs in different population groups [31,32,33,34], which implies different threshold values for different QALYs [35]. A quantitative approach to adjust CETs to represent social values is equity weighting [36], which attributes more or less importance to health benefits relative to others. The factors used for equity weighting (see Table 2) in other countries were heavily discussed in the public forums held by the Working Group, and a consensus was drawn that the Revision Committee should incorporate two factors of equity distribution in the new proposal of CETs: severity and rarity of the diseases.

3.4.3 Severity Factor

Life expectancy in Hungary lags several years behind most EU countries, due to higher death rates from cardiovascular diseases and cancer [37]. Health gains accrued to worse-off population groups might be valued more by society [22], the Revision Committee therefore preferred the concentration of funding to technologies that provide a relatively higher proportion of health to severely ill patients, in order to narrow the gap with the EU in this way. Severity is usually defined in terms of the pre-treatment health state of patients or the expected QALY in case of no treatment (i.e., future health prospect) [35].

As shown by the practice in Lithuania [21], Norway [22], the Netherlands [27], Slovakia [24] and the UK [5, 7], multiple thresholds allow for incorporating equity weights into the reimbursement decision. The Revision Committee therefore suggested that Hungary should apply multiple CETs, where technologies with high relative health gains should be assessed against the upper bound of CET (i.e., the current threshold of three times per capita GDP), while other technologies with less relative benefits should meet the new, reduced reference criteria (1.5 times per capita GDP) for gaining reimbursement.

The review showed that absolute and proportional shortfall are approaches to obtain weights for adjusting the ICER threshold. The concept of ‘proportional shortfall’ was commonly referred to as a useful approach to quantify severity [38,39,40]. It proposes that priority should be determined by the proportion of QALYs that people lose relative to their remaining life expectancy due to some illness. The approach of shortfall (either absolute or proportional) requires detailed, up-to-date information in age groups on the potential life-years lost in the country due to the different diseases. This information is currently not available in Hungary. The Revision Committee acknowledged the potential benefits of proportional shortfall and proposed a conceptually similar but simpler equity approach, which can be calculated from traditional economic evaluations without any further research or workload.

The Committee suggested setting priorities based on the incremental relative QALY gains (IRQG), where the numerator is the effect size (difference in QALY of new and comparator treatment), and the denominator is the expected QALY provided by the new treatment:

$${\text{IRQG}} = \frac{{{\text{QALY}}_{{\text{new technology}}} - {\text{QALY}}_{{{\text{comparator}}}} }}{{{\text{QALY}}_{{\text{new technology}}} }}$$

A large incremental QALY represents meaningful improvement in health. A relative measure was proposed to be used for most of the technologies as this way the priority of end-of-life treatments will not be marginalised. As such IRQG relies on not only the superiority of a new technology to the comparator, but also reflects the magnitude of the potential improvement relative to the total QALYs, a higher IRQG can be achieved with smaller incremental QALYs in diseases with less expected QALYs.

3.4.4 Analysis of Historical Data on QALYs

Cut-off points were set based on the cumulative distribution of IRQGs in recent HTA dossiers. The quantitative analysis showed that the median IRQG was 0.25, which is very low, suggesting that the majority of medicines are similar or marginally better than the comparator. The Working Group proposed using the new reference CET (1.5 x GDP per capita) for technologies with relatively low marginal health gain (IRQG ≤ 0.25). This means that ceteris paribus around 50% of the technologies would have to be assessed against the new reference CET. As only a small majority of technologies proved to be truly innovative with high relative marginal health gain, the Working Group suggested using the upper CET (3 x GDP per capita) for technologies with IRQG > 0.60, which was only reached by 12% of the technologies in the last 12-month period. Technologies between the two cut-off points (0.25 and 0.60) were proposed to be assessed against a mid-level CET (2 x GDP per capita).

3.4.5 Rarity Factor

The literature demonstrates that some countries assess the value of new drugs for rare diseases differently from technologies for more common diseases, due to unmet need, the emotional nature of neglected diseases, and higher patient expectations [41,42,43,44]. The Revision Committee recognised that drugs developed for rare patient populations require a different approach for HTA and concluded that a separate, higher threshold range should be set for orphan medicines, and the CET threshold should be proportional to the absolute health gain, similar to the practice by NICE. The increased threshold positively discriminates patients with rare diseases, and orphan medicines can be included in the positive drug list after proper HTA instead of the current reimbursement method based on the named patient basis, which creates a significant administrative burden for healthcare professionals, patients and the national healthcare payer.

For orphan medicines with EMA designation the Working Group suggested using the absolute incremental QALY gain (difference in the expected QALYs of the new and comparator therapy), as this indicator directly reflects hope for improved longevity of life or quality of life (QoL) gain for the families of paediatric patients with rare diseases, which is a priority area in the light of forthcoming medical technologies (e.g., advanced therapy medicinal products (ATMPs) in spinal muscular atrophy (SMA)). The Revision Committee concluded that for incremental discounted QALY gains of 0.5 or less, the threshold should be three times GDP per capita (equal to the upper level of CETs for other technologies). For incremental discounted QALY gains above 0.5 and below 20, the threshold should range proportionally between three times and ten times GDP per capita. For 20 or more incremental discounted QALY gains, the threshold should be ten times GDP per capita.

4 Discussion

The role of CET is somewhat different in the reviewed countries. In some countries, it is actually a hard rule on the reimbursement of new technologies, while in other countries it is used as a soft tool to inform the decision maker and support negotiation about the actual price of new technologies. Other factors can also be considered when deciding whether to adopt a technology into the reimbursement system. However, without considering cost-effectiveness, it is difficult to improve the allocative efficiency of scarce financial resources.

The WHO-CHOICE [45] has suggested thresholds between one and three times GDP per capita for a year of perfect health gained to guide policymakers on value for money [45]. However, recently WHO researchers have also stated that WHO had not recommended that three times GDP for a year of perfect health gained be considered ‘relatively’ cost effective [46]. A recent brief report demonstrated growing use and misuse of 1–3 times GDP per capita CETs in low- and middle-income countries without examining the criteria in a local context and encouraged practitioners to develop CETs reflecting local priorities [47]. Several studies [12, 48,49,50,51] have called for developing consensus on the estimation and use of CETs.

The value of the CET in the countries examined is in the range of 1–3 times the per capita GDP. CEE countries are in the upper range and their CETs are linked to the GDP per capita (or similar economic indicator, such as the average wage in Slovakia). Some more affluent Western European countries tend to use CET in the lower range, and their thresholds are not linked to economic indicators, in other words CETs are not increased automatically if the economy grows (which was the case in recent years before the COVID pandemic). In the European countries CETs have been increasing in fairly rapidly growing economies in CEEs in recent years, CETs in CEE countries have been overtaking CETs in Western European countries not even relatively to the GDP per capita, but even in absolute terms. The CETs in Hungary, Poland and Czech Republic are € 39,540, € 33,188 and € 44,834 respectively, while in the UK it is only € 22,400–€ 33,600, whilst GDP per capita in Hungary, Poland and Czech Republic is 40%, 39% and 55% of GDP in the UK, respectively. An important consequence of a high CET is the ineffective price control mechanism of new health technologies. Data show that prices paid in Poland for certain pharmaceuticals appear to be higher than the mean values for the European Union [51, 52].

As shown in Tables 1 and 2, multiple CETs have been introduced in several countries to overcome the disadvantages and limitations of using a single CET. While ICERs are certainly informative in assessing value for money, they need to be considered alongside affordability, fairness, feasibility and other criteria deemed important in the local context. Prioritization decisions in practice often include other considerations than just efficiency. The assumption that all units of health gain have equal social value, also referred to as ‘a QALY is a QALY is a QALY’ [53], has already been debated heavily in the health economics literature [31, 34, 35, 40, 54,55,56]. Society may be willing to pay more for treating life-threatening diseases such as cancer [57, 58], than for treating a self-limiting or chronic disease that does not seriously compromise daily living. To provide a more quantifiable framework for prioritization, multiple thresholds are being introduced.

There are three main approaches to determine CETs [44]: the willingness-to-pay (WTP) method for a unit of outcome; the opportunity cost method, which links the threshold to the volume of health displaced by new technologies when budget constraints are taken into account; and the precedent method based on the value of a technology already funded [59,60,61]. In the absence of such recent studies in Hungary, the Threshold Working Group decided to benchmark Hungary with other countries where a well-established HTA system exists. The Working Group concluded that a more restrictive application of the CET and the prioritization for higher relative QALY gains and rare diseases may be needed in Hungary. The use of the IRQG as an equity weight has been tested only on historical data, and it is difficult to foresee how its use will influence the chosen economic evaluation methods by pharmaceutical companies in the HTA dossier. Consequently, the Committee recommends monitoring the comparison of IRQGs in past and future economic evaluations in HTA dossiers and revising the methodology if necessary.

The results of the present study are in line with recommendations of recent publications [44, 47] that countries should make individual efforts to propose a threshold based on the local context. To this end, social preferences, economic constraints of the country, observed trends in other countries in the region, and the maturity of the HTA system need to be taken into account.

The strength of our paper is that we have managed to extract information on CETs in CEE countries (e.g., Latvia, Lithuania), in addition to those which are regularly included in the literature. This way we could provide a more comprehensive picture on CEE countries. The proposal presented in this paper might have some important policy implications in Hungary. We believe that introducing lower CETs for medicines in common diseases with less relative health gain will lead to more appropriate pricing of new technologies and will increase the efficiency of budget allocation. The use of IRQG to determine the value of the CET is anticipated to prioritise the adoption of technologies that produce higher relative health benefits. Access to orphan medicines on the positive drug list is likely to improve, as technologies that are accessible only on a named patient basis can be officially listed. The role of the HTA is expected to be strengthened in terms of serving as a primary filter for selecting technologies that are worth funding. Applying the new CETs also creates a stronger negotiating position and might increase bargaining power of the payer. Pharmaceutical companies that can bring cost-effective technologies to market are less likely to face budgetary constraint because the less cost-effective technologies will not use up the available budget.

A limitation of our proposal is that the CETs have not been derived empirically, as no information was available on the ICERs of past decisions or on the willingness-to-pay, and no underlying data were accessible to estimate the opportunity costs. Therefore, the best available approach was to draw conclusions from the practices of other countries and develop recommendations by involving a wide group of HTA experts. The proposal has been endorsed by the Ministry of Human Capacities in November 2021 [62]. It is highly recommended to review the initial experiences in the first years, and amend the CETs, if needed. In addition, in the absence of any studies explicitly investigating the preferences of the population, the appropriateness of adjusting the CET in relation to the relative health gain remains an assumption.

We are aware of the methodological weaknesses of cost-effectiveness analyses and also want to emphasise that considering the cost-effectiveness of a technology is necessary, but it is not the sole basis for decision-making. We advocate making as much data as possible on cost-effectiveness results publicly available, taking uncertainties into account, and making reimbursement decisions more transparent and accountable.

5 Conclusion

Threshold values in relation to the GDP per capita vary widely between countries. Multi-level thresholds can be set to reflect different preferences of resource allocation in healthcare funds providing selective advantage for specialised technologies. CETs should be aligned with the country’s economic performance and should reflect societal preferences. Our recommendation may increase the efficiency and equity of healthcare resource allocation in Hungary by strengthening the role of HTA in the reimbursement decisions of new technologies.