It is a huge honour and privilege for us, the co-editors, to bring to the readership of SankhyāSeries B this Econometrics Special Issue celebrating the 125th anniversary of P.C. Mahalanobis. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, when we were passing through the premises of the Indian Statistical Institute, it was already more than a decade and a half after Mahalanobis, or “The Professor” as he is affectionately called by everyone at “The Institute”, had passed away. However, it was impossible to miss The Professor’s vision about The Institute, whether in the design of research and teaching, or the reminiscences and influences upon many of our teachers, or indeed the social environment at The Institute. Hence, when we were requested by Professor Sanghamitra Bandyopadhyay (Director, Indian Statistical Institute) and Professor Dipak Dey (Editor-in-Chief of Sankhyā) to edit this special issue, it was a matter of great honour but also a somewhat daunting challenge. We wish to provide a few qualifications at the outset.

First, Mahalanobis was a pioneering researcher in statistics and allied disciplines, but he was much more – a polymath, planner, educationist and visionary, and indeed one of the architects of the new Indian nation after independence. Together with his fundamental contributions in statistics, he also contributed significantly to research, thinking and societal value in planning and economics, not least in econometrics; here, our focus here lies exclusively on his contributions in econometrics. Significantly, he was the first Indian elected member of The Econometric Society and its first fellow elected from India (1951), and a founder of The Indian Econometric Society.

Second, while the Econometric Society defines its objective as “the advancement of economic theory in its relation to statistics and mathematics,” in the context of this special issue, we have taken a narrower view of econometrics as the study of economic data aligned with economic reasoning and advancing the discipline of economics. Thereby, we offer a place of primacy to measurement and statistical inference based on economic data. We believe this focus is in line with the philosophy of Mahalanobis and the objectives of Sankhyā.Footnote 1

Third, in the choice of topics and in inviting potential authors, we draw upon Rao (1963a, 1973), Rudra et al. (1996) and Kumar (1997, 2004). Further, we tried to maintain a balance between theory and applications and between leading experts and early career scholars, as well as representation across different regional and sub-disciplinary views. We were pleased and humbled by the overwhelming response from authors. With equally enthusiastic efforts by the reviewers themselves, the submitted papers were reviewed in the usual way and using customary quality benchmarks. Given the high quality and volume of submissions, it was soon apparent that what started as a single special issue would take two special issues to do full justice. The six papers collected in this Special Issue on Econometrics in honour of P. C. Mahalanobis represent the first part; the second special issue will appear in 2020.

The papers included here make very distinct contributions and, as a collection, nicely represent the context of current econometrics research. In their own distinct ways, each paper also represents in our view a current interpretation of the work and vision of Mahalanobis in econometrics. In the following paragraphs, we attempt to briefly highlight these connections along specific themes of The Professor’s academic work (own research, and roles as the founding Editor of Sankhy\(\overline {a}\) and the founder and Director of the Indian Statistical Institute), professional work (as planner and official statistician) and as a visionary. In doing so, we have drawn liberally from the research of P. C. Mahalanobis, his interactions with leading economists and econometricians of his time (as evident, for example, from Rao (1963a)), and writings on The Professor’s work and influence by other econometricians.

1 Official and Regional Statistics

Mahalanobis was appointed the Chairman of the National Income Committee in 1949 and was closely connected with the development of operational statistics in India in the early post-independence period. His work and thinking in terms of official and regional statistics were visionary.Footnote 2 They followed from his previous experiences in Bengal and were supported by the National Sample Survey, established in 1950, through the collection of socioeconomic sample data covering the entire country. Primary objectives were to provide information needed by the government for administrative purposes, including planning, and for the computation of national income. For planning purposes, he developed “[w]hat is described in India as the single sector model of Mahalanobis … a forward-looking Harrod-Domar type of model” (Mahalanobis, 1950, 1952), which has investment, per capita income and its growth as core elements (Mukherjee, 1963).

As may be expected, Mahalanobis placed great emphasis on accuracy, on computation, and on timely compilation of national statistics; see, for example, Mahalanobis (1936a, 1963b) and Kuznets and Mahalanobis (1964).Footnote 3 Together, a strong focus on reliable statistics at the regional level was apparent from the very beginning (Mahalanobis, 1933). Allan, Koop, McIntyre and Smith (2019, in this issue) makes an excellent current contribution to statistical accounts highlighting all of the above issues – focus on growth rate of regional income, computation, accuracy, timeliness and quantification of uncertainty, but based on statistical models – a great tribute indeed to the legacy of Mahalanobis. Specifically, Allan et al. (2019) use current methodology to nowcast economic growth in Scotland, which is classified in official statistics as a region of the United Kingdom, including nowcasts in “pseudo real-time,” an important aspect of their model is also the use of mixed frequency data.

2 Mahalanobis Distance

Mahalanobis distance (or Mahalanobis D2 statistic), originally developed in Mahalanobis (1927, 1936b), has been a popular and very useful measure of “closeness” of multivariate observations. This was a very fundamental contribution and much has been written about it from a statistical perspective; see, for example, Rao (1963b, 1973) and Rudra et al. (1996). Here we discuss some interesting connections with our current understanding of econometrics, focusing on contributions in this special issue. Mahalanobis distance has close links with entropy (and Kullback-Leibler as a generalisation) and other divergence measures. In turn, the maxent or minimum divergence (relative entropy) principle, also discussed in Mahalanobis (1950), has been very useful in econometrics for constructing measures of dependence, hypothesis testing of a parametric null against an omnibus alternative, estimation of conditional moments and specification testing; see for example, Parzen (1982), Robinson (1991) and Ullah (1996). In fact, Mahalanobis distance and similar concepts have been very useful as tools for modelling dependence and non-stationarity in time series and spatial data (Robinson, 2014). Hence, Mahalanobis distance offers a nice connection to several contributions in this special issue, namely: Bailey, Kapetanios and Pesaran (2019, in this issue); Balakrishna, Koul, Sakhanenko and Ossiander (2019, in this issue); Cai, Maiti, Bhattacharjee and Calantone (2019, in this issue); and Lee, Ullah and Wang (2019, in this issue).

Bailey et al. (2019) propose a new measure of the strength of cross-sectional (or spatial) dependence in panel data, together with asymptotic and finite sample performance and an application in finance. The proposed measure is based on pair-wise cross-section correlations and is therefore related to the Mahalanobis D2 statistic; the use of averaging, bootstrap and spatial thinking in this paper also bears the legacy of Mahalanobis, which we discuss later. Balakrishna et al. (2019) develop omnibus tests of a parametric linear autoregressive time series model with multiplicative errors. As discussed above, a common use of Mahalanobis distance and related divergence measures is in testing a parametric null hypothesis against an omnibus alternative, and this provides a nice contrast with the current approach developed in this paper. Cai et al. (2019) develop a Lasso-based model selection methodology for dependent data. Here, spatial dependence is modelled using geographic or geodesic distances, which offers an interesting connection with Mahalanobis distance; there is also a connection with nonparametric regression which we discuss later. Lee et al. (2019) makes a theoretical contribution to higher order asymptotics of an asymmetric least squares estimator, providing improved bias correction and mean squared error at very low and high percentiles. This has nice applications to risk measurement, but also a connection to Mahalanobis D2 in its common use for identifying outliers. Such use is often compromised by inaccurate local measures of the covariance matrix, and in this context, the findings of this paper applied to the quantile regression model can be very useful.

3 Causal Models and Endogeneity

It is fairly apparent from his writings that Mahalanobis was primarily concerned with correlations rather than causal “interactions” (Mukherjee, 1963).Footnote 4 Nevertheless, his emphasis on forward looking planning models reflects a strong focus on counterfactual outcomes in the future that result from today’s planning decisions.Footnote 5 Such reasoning is quite closely in line with how causal modelling has subsequently evolved within the field of econometrics (and applied economics). Perhaps one cannot ignore the irony that in his own applied work Mahalanobis consistently eschewed causation in favour of correlation, and yet many of his contributions are found in the foundations of causal inference.

Baltagi and Ghosh (2019, in this issue) provides an excellent example of the theory and practice of modelling endogenous causal effects currently in econometrics. They consider treatment effects in a policy setting where the causal effect of a continuous treatment variable is measured by its impact on the marginal distribution of an outcome (partial distributional policy effects); however, the treatment itself is endogenous, which then requires new inference procedures. Some notable links are also there in the other contributions in this special issue. The system approach inherent in The Professor’s planning models is integrated in the spatial Durbin model considered in Cai et al. (2019), from which some structural (causal) interpretations can be gleaned. Likewise, the (strong and weak) factor structure modelled in Bailey et al. (2019) can be provided structural interpretation, in line with the current practice of econometrics.Footnote 6

The Professor’s thinking on causation and economic theory was set in specific planning policy contexts. In fact, a central critique of contemporary economic theories considered by Mahalanobis was the fundamental focus, in classical economic theory, on aggregate demand, output, and consumption and not equally on distributional effects; see Stone (1963) for an excellent discussion including the context of Indian planning. Mahalanobis was intimately conscious of extreme inequalities in Indian society, and more generally issues of socio-economic equity and justice. This concern was also expressed in his work as the Chairman of the Committee on Distribution of Income and Levels of Living, and his development of Fractile Graphical Analysis (which we discuss later) can be partly related to his empirical studies on inequality (Mukherjee, 1973); see, for example, Mahalanobis (1959, 1963a).Footnote 7 Likewise, Baltagi and Ghosh (2019) apply their proposed methods to a very important and current problem of social justice, that of systematic patterns of incarceration (imprisonment) in the United States.

4 Nonparametrics: Subsampling and Regression

In the later part of his career, The Professor made some fundamental contributions to the early development of nonparametric regression. With large data, the regression function of y on x can be calculated by averaging all observations on y at each point x. With finite data, Mahalanobis (1958, 1960, 1963a) developed Fractile Graphical Analysis (FGA) which proceeds by sorting x and partitioning into fractile groups, such as deciles, and then computing and plotting conditional averages of y; essentially, this is an early form of nonparametric regression based on a histogram sieve (Deaton, 1995).

In a way, focus on nonparametrics rather than parametric regression models perhaps reflects The Professor’s lack of comfort with structural and parametric restrictions arising from economic theory. This is interesting because, notwithstanding errors inherent in parameter estimates and economic measurements, Mahalanobis was more comfortable with using planning and national accounts identities. Similar use of averages are also abundant in The Professor’s early work, for example in moving-block sampling methods for spatial data, or interpenetrating subsamples; see, for example, Mahalanobis (1946, 1950). In particular, Mahalanobis (1946) demonstrates careful spatial analysis and a deep appreciation of J. A. Hubbard’s early spatial sampling methodology, both of which he built into his own method of block-sampling. Further, in operationalising the single sector and two-sector planning models, Mahalanobis estimated key structural parameters using averages of time series data across many countries “to concretise his ideas on the rate of investment and rate of growth of national income in India” (Mukherjee, 1963). In fact, one might argue that his work laid the foundations for popular and useful resampling methods such as bootstrapping and subsampling that are now standard tools in econometrics and elsewhere (Hall, 2003; Robinson, 2014).

In this special issue there are several examples of current econometric treatments of spatial heterogeneity and spatial dependence (Bailey et al. 2019; Cai et al. 2019), which provides interesting contrast with The Professor’s work. Likewise, the use of correlations (functions of second order moments, or sample averages) is central in the work of Bailey et al. (2019), which provides yet another link with The Professor’s legacy. As discussed above, use of bootstrap is pervasive in econometrics today, and several different examples can be found in this special issue; see Bailey et al. (2019), Baltagi and Ghosh (2019), and Lee et al. (2019).

As a final point of comparison, regularization by assumption of sparsity is popular in the current theory and practice of econometrics. In this special issue, it is central to the measurement of cross-section dependence in Bailey et al. (2019) and likewise to high dimensional variable selection in Cai et al. (2019). This can be placed in contrast with traditional approaches prevalent at The Professor’s time. There are two notable examples in Rao (1963a): macroeconomic models of national accounts identified by structural constraints (Frisch, with Parikh, 1963); and models of linear demand systems with explicit parameter restrictions (Stone, 1963). An interesting contrast also obtains from The Professor’s own work on demand systems (Mahalanobis, 1963a; Bhattacharya and Mahalanobis, 1967), specifically on the consumption of cereals in India and regional disparities in household consumption in India, using his nonparametric FGA method and its generalisation.

Finally, we are grateful to all the authors, and likewise to all the reviewers, for their significant efforts and contributions, the Editor-in-Chief and co-editors of Sankhy\(\overline {a}\) for continuous editorial assistance, and to the Indian Statistical Institute and its Director for institutional support. By its very nature, this preface is selective of certain aspects of Mahalanobis’ work that, in our view, best capture the link with current econometrics research as represented in this special issue. Like any other selection, this is therefore inherently subjective. Nevertheless, we hope it provides a meaningful connection to the readership of Sankhyā, and places The Professor’s influence upon econometrics in a current light. We believe that the six papers in this special issue make a significant contribution to the current literature in econometrics and are pleased to present this collection to the readership of SankhyāSeries B.