Introduction

Societies are becoming more diverse on ethnic, cultural and economic dimensions due to growing migrant populations all over the world, especially in Northern Africa, Western Asia and sub-Saharan Africa (International Migration Report 2019 2019). This increasing heterogeneity may pose a challenge to the successful management of common-pool resources (CPRs) in two ways: (1) directly by diversifying interests amongst users and (2) indirectly by reducing trust amongst users. Both ways lead to decreased cooperation in CPRs. CPRs are natural or man-made resources—such as grasslands, communal forests, fishing grounds or irrigation systems—for which it is costly to exclude potential users (Ostrom 1990). Different from a public good, a common-pool resource may run out, making it vulnerable to the ‘tragedy of the commons’ as described by Hardin (1968), a situation where the short-term dominant strategy of users is to use the limited resource unlimitedly, which leads to its decay. The effect of increasing heterogeneity on the success of CPRs, and the role of trust in this process, is still contested (Baland and Platteau 1999; Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002; Ruttan 2006, 2008; Varughese and Ostrom 2001). The aim of this paper is to gain insight into whether and how two types of heterogeneity—economic and sociocultural—and their interplay with trust affect the success of a CPR, that is, its sustainable long-term use and quality of the resource.

Economic heterogeneity expresses inequalities in wealth, income and access to resources, and sociocultural heterogeneity represents disparities in language, ethnicity, religion and other cultural expressions (Baland and Platteau 1996; Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002; Ruttan 2006). Most research argues that economic and sociocultural heterogeneity may result in increased costs of negotiation and bargaining due to a lack of shared ideas, values and incentives between individuals or groups of individuals (Aksoy 2019; Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002), that it may lead to unequal sharing of decision-making rights and different motivations to cooperate (Anderson and Paskeviciute 2006; Fung and Au 2014; Komakech et al. 2012) and that it may decrease social cohesion (Flache and Mäs 2008; Jehn et al. 1999). On the other hand, some research suggests positive effects of economic heterogeneity on the provision of collective goods, stating that it can lead to an inequality of incentives, which results in some appropriators being motivated enough to invest in collective action on their own—hereby carrying the costs of cooperation (Olson 1965).

In order to understand the indirect relation between heterogeneity and CPR success, we introduce trust as a mediator: there is evidence that trust is influenced by heterogeneity (Alesina and La Ferrara 2002; Delhey and Newton 2005; Ostrom 1990; Putnam 2007) and that it plays an important role in influencing societal outcomes (Fukuyama 1995; Putnam 2000; Uslaner 2002; Zak and Knack 2001). We will investigate the relation between trust and CPR success, and the role of trust in the indirect relation between heterogeneity and CPR success.

This paper will study 32 fisheries and 50 irrigation systems, using Elinor Ostrom’s well-known Common-Pool Resource Database (Ostrom et al. 1989).Footnote 1 Considering the field of study, which typically uses in-depth case studies, this is a relatively large database (Poteete and Ostrom 2004; Ruttan 2006). While the CPR Database was used before to investigate the relation between heterogeneity and CPR outcomes, this was done with correlations and Mann-Whitney U tests on the available data, which contains a lot of missing observations (Ruttan 2006, 2008). Instead, the current paper uses innovative and advanced imputation techniques such as multiple imputations with chained equations, random forests and predictive mean matching to make the data suitable for including both economic and sociocultural heterogeneity, trust and control variables in the same model. This enables us to test the effects of one type of heterogeneity while controlling for the other, without decreasing the sample size due to the large amount of missing data, something that, to the extent of our knowledge, has not been attempted yet in previous research using this database. On top of that, our preparation of the data allows to test both direct effects of heterogeneity and trust on CPR success, and indirect effects of heterogeneity on CPR success through trust. This enables us to uncover part of the ‘black box’ of the theoretical mechanism.

We aim for theoretical progress in two ways. First, we test hypotheses regarding the relation between economic and sociocultural heterogeneity and CPR success for the combined sample, and two subsamples for fishing grounds and irrigation systems.Footnote 2 Second, we formulate and test a hypothesis regarding the relation between trust and CPR success specifically for fisheries and irrigation systems. The outcomes are relevant not only for classic CPRs as fisheries and irrigation systems, but also for the rising number of contemporary institutions for collective action on food, infrastructure, health and energy, such as citizen initiatives producing green energy and urban agriculture projects (Bravo and De Moor 2008; De Moor 2013a, b, 2018). In a time where mankind is rapidly depleting the earth’s resources, research on success and failure of CPRs is more important than ever.

The negative influence of heterogeneity

Regarding economic heterogeneity it is suggested that large differences in wealth may result in a loss of incentives to cooperate for less wealthy appropriators if the benefits of cooperation are not high enough (Baland and Platteau 1999), if there is no wealthy appropriator willing to initiate collective action, or if the wealthy appropriators turn to their exit options—alternative ways to generate income—instead (Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002; Jones 2004; Molinas 1998). Adding to this argument, Shanmugaratnam (1996) argues that sustainable use of CPRs is more challenging under a more unequal distribution of private wealth, as it leads to a diversification of interests amongst appropriators of the CPR. When actors have different interests, assurance mechanisms such as sanctioning are harder to implement since the actors are less likely to agree on them. However, these assurance mechanisms are needed for successful CPR management, making diversification of the interests of actors problematic. Heterogeneity in access to exit options can also have negative effects on the CPR itself: if resource appropriators have relatively rewarding earning opportunities outside of the appropriation of the resource, they may be more willing to comply with effort-restricting measures that are set in place to maintain the CPR. On the other hand, appropriators without access to exit options may not be willing to restrict their appropriation efforts as it will have a greater impact on their total income (Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002; Gaspart and Platteau 2007). Evidence from observations and experiments supporting these arguments are manifold (Bardhan 2000; Hackett et al. 1994; Varughese and Ostrom 2001).

With respect to sociocultural heterogeneity, the general argument is that collective action is more likely to be established when the individuals involved have strong, multistranded, interpersonal relationships, share common interests, and have relatively stable group memberships (Anderson and Paskeviciute 2006; Ostrom 1990; Ostrom et al. 1992; Varughese and Ostrom 2001). Furthermore, Anderson and Paskeviciute (2006) consider heterogeneity to be an impediment to cooperation, as people feel threatened by others who are not part of their ‘ingroup’.

If subgroups of appropriators within a CPR differ in ownership of assets, skills, knowledge or sociocultural characteristics, it is likely that these subgroups also differ in interests and preferred use of the resource.Footnote 3 This can make it hard to reach agreements on the making and enforcing of rules due to a lack of mutual trust and the inability to understand each other. It can be reason for conflict and thus impedes collective action (Carpenter and Cardenas 2011; Gehrig et al. 2019; Johnson and Libecap 1982; Keuschnigg and Schikora 2014; Ostrom 1990; Varughese and Ostrom 2001). For instance, farmers may have different interests than nomads when it comes to the use of the resource, and men and women may have different actual and perceived costs and benefits, caused by a long history of gender inequality (Agarwal 1994, 1997; Molinas 1998; Varughese and Ostrom 2001).

Nettle and Dunbar (1997) focus on another aspect of sociocultural background, namely language; they state that speaking the same language facilitates a feeling of social allegiance, which is deemed important for the maintenance of group cohesion. Evidence in favour of these arguments is found by Wiessner (1977) with respect to language differences between tribes in Botswana. Another example of sociocultural homogeneity having a positive effect on sustainable cooperation is given by Singleton (2001) in an analysis of contemporary Pacific Northwest salmon fishing. The study describes how homogeneous Aboriginal tribes were very efficient and sustainable in the appropriation of salmon fishing grounds, in spite of the sometimes unequal economic results between individual members. The study describes how conflicts about appropriation only arose between Aboriginal tribes and the state. Based on a survey study of group membership in the USA, Alesina and La Ferrara (2000) concluded that residents from racially heterogeneous communities participate less in social activities. Carpenter and Cardenas (2011), employing a laboratory experiment with Colombians and Americans, discovered that mixed groups cooperate less than homogeneous groups. Keuschnigg and Schikora (2014) found in a study using public good games [PGGs] that religious heterogeneity decreases cooperation in the presence of a leader: whereas a generous contribution of leaders in homogeneous groups is met with reciprocity from the followers, this was not the case in heterogeneous groups. Vermillion (1999) mentions that the absence of social divisions is a requirement for collective action amongst farmers in devolution programs of irrigation systems, in which rights and responsibilities are transferred from the government to local water user groups. Lastly, Gaspart and Platteau (2007) concluded on basis of their case study of Senegalese fisheries that the division between native and migrant appropriators forms an insuperable problem for cooperation and mutual trust. Here, agreement on regulatory schemes has become nigh impossible.

Although the literature theoretically and empirically suggests predominantly a negative effect of heterogeneity, there are arguments for a positive effect, indirectly based on a well-known theory by Olson (1965), also known as the ‘Olson effect’:

In smaller groups marked by considerable degrees of inequality – that is, in groups of members of unequal “size” or extent of interest in the collective good – there is the greatest likelihood that a collective good will be provided; for the greater the interest in the collective good of any single member, the greater the likelihood that that member will get such a significant proportion of the total benefit from the collective good that he will gain from seeing that the good is provided, even if he has to pay all of the cost himself. (p. 34)

Although the link with economic heterogeneity cannot directly be distilled out of this quote, it is often interpreted as an argument in favour of a positive effect of economic heterogeneity on collective action: those with higher incomes will act as catalysts for collective action because they can afford it, and it is in their interest to do so (Baland and Platteau 1997, 1999; Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson 2002; Jones 2004; Ruttan 2006, 2008). In addition, it is likely that the Olson effect will only take place when inequality is large and there are actors that are indeed so rich that they can afford to pay to see collective action happen. It is unlikely that there are many of these cases in the current database. Based on the discussed literature, we therefore expect negative effects to be more probable. Hence, our first hypothesis reads: (hypothesis 1a) economic and (hypothesis 1b) sociocultural heterogeneity have a negative relation with CPR success.

The role of trust

A variable that we consider to play a role in the indirect effect of heterogeneity on CPR success is trust. The first part of the argument, illustrating the relation between heterogeneity and trust, is that people are more likely to trust someone who is more similar to themselves (Alesina and La Ferrara 2002; Coleman 1994), implying more mutual trust in a more homogeneous setting and less mutual trust in a heterogeneous one. People tend to trust members of their family and members of the same ingroup; be it racial, social, ethnic or based on something else (Alesina and La Ferrara 2002; Romano et al. 2017). Many studies point out a negative association between heterogeneity and trust. For instance, in their study using individual level data from the USA, Alesina and La Ferrara (2002) observe a negative relation between social distance and trust, and point out that being economically unsuccessful and living in a neighbourhood with a high degree of income inequality reduces trust. Delhey and Newton (2005) find that generalised trust is closely related to homogeneity in religious, cultural, social and political identification as well as to economic equality. Similarly, Gehrig et al. (2019) find in a lab-in-field CPR experiment in Zanzibar that less trusting fishermen overexploit the CPR more in heterogeneous groups, while they cooperate in the homogeneous group to achieve a sustainable use of the resource. Regarding causality, Leigh (2006a, b) uses an instrumental variable approach in two studies, to show that increasing inequality and ethnic and linguistic fractionalisation reduce trust. Adding to that, Romano et al. (2017) find in a series of trust games in 17 countries that people are generally more trusting towards ingroup members than towards outgroup members.

The second part of the argument concerns the relation of trust with positive societal outcomes—in our case CPR success. Societies with high levels of trust amongst individuals yield a lesser need for the individuals to protect themselves from being taken advantage of by others in mutual transactions (Knack and Keefer 1997). Instead of formal institutions, mutual trust amongst individuals facilitates the use of informal agreements, leading to a decrease in transaction costs and a greater likelihood of economic efficiency and success (Alesina and La Ferrara 2002; Knack and Keefer 1997). Next to economic success, trust is known to promote cooperation and participation in social activities (Alesina and La Ferrara 2000; La Porta et al. 1997; Romano et al. 2017).

Empirical evidence supports this argument. A multitude of studies show a positive relation between high levels of interpersonal trust and economic growth of societies (Knack and Keefer 1997; La Porta et al. 1997; Zak and Knack 2001). Regarding the causal direction of the effects of trust, Acedo and Gomila (2013) find in an experiment involving an iterated prisoner’s dilemma that higher trust results in higher levels of cooperation. Likewise, Gächter et al. (2004) find that more trusting people contribute more than less trusting people in three-person one-shot public good games.

Summarising, we hypothesise that (hypothesis 2a) economic and (hypothesis 2b) sociocultural heterogeneity have a negative relation with trust; (hypothesis 3) trust has a positive relation with CPR success; (hypothesis 4a) economic and (hypothesis 4b) sociocultural heterogeneity have a negative indirect relation with CPR success through trust.

The relevance of sector type

The cases analysed in this paper are either fisheries or irrigation systems. These two types of CPR vary in a multitude of aspects, which may influence the way sociocultural and economic heterogeneity and trust impact their success. First, whereas fishing grounds can be considered natural resources, irrigation systems are entirely man-made. This influences the way appropriators see the resource; an open-access resource available to everyone versus a self-made system only available to the ones who are granted access and/or are contributing to its maintenance (Gaspart and Platteau 2007). Second, whereas there are many different techniques to appropriate a fishing ground, which can be cause for conflict between appropriators (Gaspart and Platteau 2007), irrigation systems work one way for all users. Third, while mutual monitoring for irrigation systems is easy, this is more difficult for fishing grounds, where fishing boats cannot see each other during appropriation and where illegal appropriation forms a daily threat to the success of the CPR (Gaspart and Platteau 2007; Regmi 2007).Footnote 4 Fourth, while the resource flow of a fishing ground can be considered relatively stable—conditional on the resource not being nearly depleted, the flow of water coming from the river that provides water to the irrigation system is less predictable (Regmi 2007). This poses a challenge for devising appropriation rules. For fishing grounds, many countries impose individual fishery quotas to improve sustainability of fishing activities (Sanchirico et al. 2006) or even moratoriums until specific fish populations regrow (see for instance Jiang et al. 2009; Khan et al. 2018; Palmer and Sinclair 2008). However, these rules do not necessarily make sense for an irrigation system, since the total discharge of a river is likely to change over time and is less dependent on use by farmers and more dependent on external factors such as the weather. Instead, time allocation rules are used that can vary depending on the availability of water (Regmi 2007). Fifth, whereas a fishing ground does not require much, if any, maintenance, irrigation systems do: man-made components such as check gates have to be checked regularly and fixed when broken. The government will take care of the maintenance if the system is government owned, but for systems that are not government owned, this requires farmers to work together (Vermillion 1999). This type of collective action is not required for fishermen, whose profits are not dependent on each other in this way. Lastly, a big difference between fishing grounds and irrigation systems is the constant disadvantage of appropriators in an irrigation system that are located downstream as opposed to at the head of the river (Ostrom 1990; Regmi 2007). The appropriators upstream are the first ones to receive water and are the least likely to be disadvantaged when other appropriators overexploit the resource. The appropriators downstream on the other hand, will experience the worst consequences of overexploitation of the resource by more upstream appropriators. Whereas fisheries usually have a rotation system of sorts to equalise appropriation time at better spots, this is not possible for irrigation systems (Ostrom 1990; Regmi 2007). A table describing differences in nature and various characteristics between fishing grounds and irrigation systems using variables from the CPR Database can be found in Appendix 1.

The differences between the two sector types may have implications for the expected effects of trust on CPR success: due to almost automatic mutual monitoring and the closed-access and man-made nature of the resource, trust amongst appropriators may be less vital in order for the irrigation system to be successful. For fisheries however, trust amongst appropriators may play a more important role in reaching sustainable appropriation, as appropriators would need to trust each other not to overexploit the resource while not being able to see each other, or each other’s actions, straight away. Based on the above we expect (hypothesis 5) that the relation of trust with CPR success is stronger for fishing grounds than for irrigation systems.

Data and methods

Data

We use the Common-Pool Resource Database compiled by Elinor Ostrom and her team (1989) to test our hypotheses. This database is based on a bibliography comprising over 1800 published and unpublished original CPR case studies from before 1990. A small subset of this bibliography was selected,Footnote 5 and coded into the CPR Database using extensive survey forms containing over 600 questions on topics such as geographic and demographic features of the CPR location, boundaries and physical characteristics of the CPR, the situations faced and actions performed by appropriators of the CPR and the strategies of appropriators in subgroups (Ostrom 1990; Ostrom et al. 1989; Schlager 1990; Tang 1989). It was required that the material is written “by a researcher who has spent considerable time in the field” (Ostrom et al. 1989, p. 10) and that the material contains “key information about the structure of the resource, the rules used in organizing the resource, the strategies adopted by the appropriators, and the outcomes achieved” (Ostrom et al. 1989, p. 10). This way, 40 person-years of fieldwork, conducted by researchers interested in the field of CPRs, such as social scientists, historians and engineers, are captured in one database (Ostrom et al. 1989). The first major publication based on the CPR Database is Elinor Ostrom’s Governing the Commons (1990), contributing to the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences that she won together with Oliver E. Williamson, for her analysis of economic governance in CPRs. The dataset contains 32 fisheries and 50 irrigation systems for analysis of the variables of interest for this paper. The 3 CPRs that are neither fisheries nor irrigation systems are not included since they lack cases for making a comparison between sector types. The CPRs are located in 29 different countries from all over the world, although many are situated in the Middle East and Asia. A table comprising the cases and their sources used in this study can be found in Appendix 2.

Measurements

Many of the variables that are available in the database are recorded for both the beginning and the end of a period of time, during which “the actions of the appropriators are relatively consistent” (Ostrom et al. 1989, p. 352). These periods are of variable length, and different survey forms are provided for each period. These period forms, or ‘time slices’, are the observations in the dataset. Of the 82 separate CPRs that will be used for our analyses, seven have more than one period form filled out, so more than one time slice; this means that researchers conducting the case study found that during their study, several periods could be distinguished with specific information for each of them. Separate periods are considered as different observations since this period-specific information would get lost otherwise. Though the data has a multilevel structure—subgroups nested in time slices nested in CPR cases—we take all variables on the time slice level: operationalised variables are either original CPR level variables for a specific period or aggregated subgroup variables for that period. We do this because not all CPRs have multiple time slices or multiple forms coded for their separate subgroups: there are 123 forms for 82 CPRs, existing of 95 cases due to the extra period files.Footnote 6 Cases that are twice in the dataset due to multiple coding forms for different subgroups are deleted, as we only use the aggregate information, which otherwise would be duplicate. The three cases that are neither fisheries nor irrigation systems are removed. In total the number of observations that can be used for analyses is N = 92. If variables are recorded for both the beginning and the end of the period, the variables for the end of the period will be used (cf. Ruttan 2006, 2008). See the CPR Coding Manual for a more detailed description of the data (Ostrom et al. 1989).

Dependent variables

Unit quality: This variable is operationalised with an item indicating the ‘quality of the units that are withdrawn from the resource’. There are five answering categories, ranging from ‘extremely poor quality’ (0), to ‘extremely high quality’ (4). The quality of the appropriated units is an indicator of the quality of the resource in general, and thus represents a substantive part of the success of the CPR.

Balance: This variable is operationalised with an item indicating the ‘balance between the quantity of [resource] units withdrawn and the number of units available in the resource’. There are five answering categories, ranging from ‘extreme shortage’ (0) to ‘quite abundant’ (4). The balance between withdrawal and renewal of the resource indicates the health of the resource as well as the sustainability of the behaviour of the appropriators, and thus represents another substantive part of the success of the CPR.

Independent variables

Sector type: This independent variable indicates whether the CPR is an irrigation system (1) or not (0). Since the dataset exists only of irrigation systems and fishing grounds, the variable can be interpreted as being an irrigation system (1) versus a fishing ground (0). In the regression tables, this variable will be named ‘Irrigation’ for the main effects and will be abbreviated to ‘Irr.’ when used in an interaction effect.

Economic heterogeneity: The independent variable economic heterogeneity is operationalised as the highest level of variation in income within any subgroup within a CPR time slice (cf. Ruttan 2008). The item on variation in income has three outcome variables, ranging from ‘low’ (0) to ‘moderate’ (1) to ‘high’ (2).

Sociocultural heterogeneity: This independent variable consists of the maximum value found per time slice in any of seven items: the extent to which ethnic, racial, religious, caste, clan and gender identification and the language spoken affect communication between subgroups.Footnote 7 All seven items have the same five-point response scale ranging from ‘no difference along this variable’ (0) to ‘large differences which significantly affect communication’ (4).

Trust: This variable serves as both independent and dependent. It is an item indicating the extent of mutual trust amongst appropriators within the CPR on a three-point scale, with the categories ‘low levels of trust’ (0), ‘modest levels of trust’ (1) and ‘moderate to high levels of trust’ (2).

Control variables

The following control variables were added to the final unit quality and balance models because they could influence success of the CPR: cultural view of the resource, number of users of the resource, closed access to the resource, opportunities for exit options, monetary, physical and social sanctions, pollution, level of financial pressure for immediate returns from the CPR, dependence on CPR for family income, the presence of consistently disadvantaged appropriators who are cut off from benefits and variation in availability of units over space. A more detailed description of the variables can be found in Appendix 3. Since most variables have no significant relations with the outcome variables, these models are not considered for the interpretation of the results but are presented in Appendix 3.

Analytical strategy and causality

To test the hypotheses, OLS regression will be used and the unstandardised coefficients will be interpreted. Even though the variables unit quality, balance, economic heterogeneity, sociocultural heterogeneity and trust are not continuous but ordinal, we will consider them continuous in the interest of simplicity of interpretation. This allows us to retain statistical power—especially given the small sample size in the subsamples—by reducing degrees of freedom. In addition, it allows us to calculate indirect effects in a meaningful way. Following argumentation of amongst others Pasta (2009) and Williams (2018) on treating ordinal independent variables as continuous, a likelihood ratio test was completed to establish whether the models would significantly differ between treating the variables as ordinal or continuous (see Williams (2018) for a more extensive explanation of the test). The test concluded that economic heterogeneity, sociocultural heterogeneity and trust can be treated as continuous in the models.Footnote 8 Ordinal logistic regression was also performed, with ordinal independent variables added as dummies. These models can be found in Appendix 4. The main results from the OLS analyses are largely supported by the more conservative ordinal logistic models. In addition, a robustness check was performed with an alternative operationalisation of economic and sociocultural heterogeneity, by taking the mean per time slice of the variation of income in CPR subgroups for economic heterogeneity and the mean of the seven sociocultural heterogeneity items instead of the maximum value. The results are very similar to the OLS models and can be found in Appendix 5. Relations found in the OLS models that are not backed up by the ordinal logistic models or the robustness check models will not be considered robust.

Part of the analytical strategy is to analyse the entire sample, including both fisheries and irrigation systems, as well as two subsamples of fishery- and irrigation-only cases. This allows us to look at the general picture as well as to look at associations between variables that may be specific to the sector type. Questions that may arise after looking at the combined sample may be answered when looking at the separate samples. In addition, analysing the combined sample allows us to not miss out on the detection of associations between variables by retaining statistical power compared with the subsample analyses, given the small sample size. To test hypothesis 5 regarding the differences in the effect of trust on CPR success between fishing grounds and irrigation systems, an interaction between trust and sector type (Irr. × Trust) is added in addition to measuring the effect of trust in the two subsamples.

Although causal phrases are used throughout the discussion of the results, the observational data only allows to test associations, and causal conclusions can in principle not be drawn. However, we have some confidence in the assumed causal directions. Even though one could argue that trust could bring homogeneity about instead of homogeneity inducing trust, it is important to know that sociocultural heterogeneity (ethnic, racial, clan, caste, religious and gender identification and the language spoken) is rather fixed, as is economic inequality, although less so. Hence, in this respect, we have some confidence in the assumed causality (see also Leigh (2006a, b) and Romano et al. (2017)). With respect to trust and CPR success, it might also be possible that a high score on CPR unit quality and balance increases trust. However, experimental research of Acedo and Gomila (2013) and Gächter et al. (2004) discussed earlier provides evidence for the causal direction reflected in our hypotheses.

Multiple imputation: mice, random forests and predictive mean matching

All main independent variables have missing values—some more than others. The missingness of the independent variables is not correlated with relevant variables in the model. We assume the missing values to be missing at random (MAR) (Rubin 1987) and not dependent on unobserved data.Footnote 9 This is, however, an untestable assumption. To prevent having to perform analyses on a smaller sample size than 92 cases due to missing observations in key variables, multiple imputation with chained random forests (RFs) (Breiman 2001; Van Buuren 2019) was performed, using the MissRanger package in R (Mayer 2019), an adaptation of the MissForest package by Stekhoven and Bühlmann (2012) using the Ranger package (Wright et al. 2019). RF imputation accommodates nonlinearities and interactions and does not need a specific regression model to be defined. Predictive mean matching (PMM) was used to fill in the missing values with realistic imputations, that is, avoiding the imputation of continuous values in a discrete variable, for each iteration. PMM also enables imputed values to be endowed with realistic levels of local variability, effectively raising the variance of the resulting RF-estimated conditional distributions to a more realistic level (Mayer 2019). We created 100 simulations and ensured the chained RFs would stop re-fitting after 30 iterations, though in every simulated imputed dataset, this procedure took at most 5 iterations, suggesting quick convergence to optimally imputed values. Imputation diagnostics, including the ‘out of bag error’ (OOB)Footnote 10 distribution per imputed variable, were inspected for key variables and supported our confidence in the imputation model. Research comparing MissForest imputation to other imputation techniques shows that MissForest performs well and in a lot of cases better than other established imputation techniques, even when applied to data with up to 30% missing values (Stekhoven and Bühlmann 2012). As the current database has 28% missing data, using the MissRanger package based on the MissForest package is well suited. By making use of multiple imputation, both sociocultural and economic heterogeneity can be included in one model without reducing the sample size. The value of including both forms of heterogeneity in the model is that the risk of overestimating the influence of one by not controlling for the other is reduced. Table 1 provides insights in the original versus the imputed dataset.

Table 1 Imputed data statistics: key variables above line, control variables below line

The adjusted R2 including the 95% confidence interval is provided for the models where possible.Footnote 11 In addition, the fraction of missing information [FMI] is reported for the models where it was possible to calculate them, providing information on the uncertainty about the missing data, which affects the pooled standard errors (Pan and Wei 2016; Wagner 2010). These statistics are retrieved using the pool function of the Mice package (Van Buuren 2019). In addition, the Akaike information criterion [AIC] will be reported for every model. Lastly, tables stating the FMI per variable for main models will be provided in Appendix 6.

Results

In this section, Spearman’s rank correlations will first be discussed to get an initial idea of the relation between variables. To test the hypotheses, we will discuss OLS regressions for the combined sample of both fishing grounds and irrigation systems, and the two subsamples separately. Both direct and indirect effects will be discussed. Lastly, the robustness of the found results is assessed by crosschecking the OLS regressions with the ordinal logistic regressions and the OLS regressions with the alternative operationalisation of the heterogeneity variables, both of which can be found in the appendices.

Correlations

Table 2 shows the relation between key variables using Spearman’s rank correlation. The table shows the average coefficients over 100 imputed datasets and includes the standard errors in parentheses. The same table for the available case data is shown in Appendix 7, showing very similar results. It is shown that economic heterogeneity has a significant negative relation with trust in all three samples. In addition, it has a negative relation with balance in the combined and irrigation system sample. Sociocultural heterogeneity has a negative relation to trust in the combined sample and the irrigation sample, a significant negative relation to balance in the irrigation sample and a marginally significant negative relation with unit quality in the irrigation sample. Trust has a positive relation to both CPR success outcomes in all three samples except unit quality in irrigation systems. So far, the results thus partially support hypotheses 2a and 2b and largely support hypothesis 3. Only limited support is found for hypotheses 1a and 1b. Hypothesis 5 does not hold for balance but could yet hold for unit quality.

Table 2 Spearman correlation for main variables

Combined sample results

The OLS regression models on CPR success using the imputed data are presented in Table 3. Model 1 and model 2 show that irrigation systems have significantly lower scores on unit quality (B = − 0.53, p < 0.001) and balance (B = − 0.52, p = 0.005) than fishing grounds, indicating that there may be fundamental differences in success variables between the sector types. Model 3 and model 4 include the effect of sociocultural and economic heterogeneity and show that there is no significant relation between either sociocultural or economic heterogeneity and unit quality or balance, so far thus rejecting hypotheses 1a and 1b stating a negative relation of heterogeneity with CPR success. Model 5 and model 6 include the effect of trust; model 5 shows a significant relation between trust and unit quality (B = 0.20, p = 0.040), and model 6 shows a significant relation between trust and balance (B = 0.54, p < 0.001), supporting hypothesis 3 stating that higher levels of trust are associated with CPR success. To test hypothesis 5, models 7 and 8 include the interaction effect between trust and sector type. Model 8 shows no improvement in fit, but model 7 shows an increase from 0.28 to 0.39 for the adjusted R2. The main effect of trust on unit quality, thus the relation between trust and unit quality in fishing grounds, is significant and positive (B = 0.53, p < 0.001), adding to the support for hypothesis 3. The interaction effect is significant and negative (B = − 0.57, p < 0.001) indicating that the relation between trust and unit quality for irrigation systems is basically zero and thus that trust amongst appropriators in a fishing ground may play a bigger role in achieving high levels of unit quality than in irrigation systems.Footnote 12 This result only partially supports hypothesis 5; only in the case of unit quality. The main effect of trust on balance in model 8, thus the relation between trust and balance for fishing grounds, is marginally significant and substantive (B = 0.43, p = 0.053), indicating a 0.43 unit increase on a five-point scale of balance per increased unit of economic heterogeneity. Model 9 shows that economic heterogeneity (B = − 0.32, p = 0.004) has a significant negative relation with trust, supporting hypothesis 2a. No evidence for hypothesis 2b is found. Lastly, model 10 shows that there is no significant main effect of sector type on trust, indicating that irrigation systems and fisheries do not necessarily differ in levels of trust, even though trust within each sector type may affect CPR success differently.

Table 3 OLS regression on main variables and interaction effect using the imputed sample of both fisheries and irrigation systems

The indirect effects of economic heterogeneity on unit quality and balance through trust are calculated manually, using Sobel’s (1982) product of coefficients approach for the coefficient, and Monte Carlo simulations for the standard error and two-sided p value.Footnote 13 Taking the coefficient of trust for fisheries from model 7, we calculate a significant indirect effect of economic heterogeneity on unit quality through trust (B = − 0.17, p = 0.017).Footnote 14 Using the trust coefficient for irrigation systems, we find a significant indirect effect of economic heterogeneity on balance through trust (B = − 0.20, p = 0.033). These results partially support hypothesis 4a stating the negative indirect effect of economic heterogeneity on CPR success through trust, but as no other significant indirect effects are found for the combined sample, the supportive evidence for hypothesis 4a is very limited and hypothesis 4b is so far rejected. To check the robustness of the tests for the indirect effects, moderated mediation models using the mediate function in R were applied (Tingley et al. 2014), to test the difference in mediation effects of heterogeneity through trust on CPR success between fishing grounds and irrigation systems.Footnote 15 The results support the found indirect effects and can be seen in Appendix 8.

Separate sample results

Table 4 shows the models testing the hypotheses separately for the fishing ground sample (N = 40) and the irrigation system sample (N = 52). In the fishing ground sample, a positive significant relation between trust and unit quality (B = 0.54, p = 0.004) in model 3 and a marginally significant relation between trust and balance (B = 0.50, p = 0.062) in model 4 are found. Both results add to the support for hypothesis 3. A marginally significant relation between economic heterogeneity and trust is visible (B = − 0.28, p = 0.071) in model 5. Although not significant at the 5% level, it is a substantive effect of a 0.28 point decrease in the three-point scale of trust per increased unit of economic heterogeneity, providing modest support for hypothesis 2a.

Table 4 OLS regression on main variables using the imputed sample for fishing grounds (left) and irrigation systems (right)

With respect to the irrigation system sample, a hint of the indirect effect of economic heterogeneity by trust can be seen from models 2, 4 and 5. Model 2 shows a marginally significant negative relation of economic heterogeneity and balance (B = − 0.35, p = 0.10), modestly supporting hypothesis 1a. Model 4 shows a significant relation of trust and balance (B = 0.59, p = 0.007), supporting hypothesis 3. In addition, it shows the disappearance of the significance of economic heterogeneity. Lastly, model 5 shows a significant negative relation between economic heterogeneity and trust (B = − 0.29, p = 0.050), providing some support for hypothesis 2a. Possibly, the results support hypothesis 4a for balance: the disappearance of the significant effect of economic heterogeneity from models 2 to 4 combined with the significant negative relation between economic heterogeneity on trust could be an indicator of an indirect effect of economic heterogeneity through trust on balance. Regarding sociocultural heterogeneity, model 1 shows a significant negative relation between sociocultural heterogeneity and unit quality (B = − 0.15, p = 0.034) and model 5 shows a negative relation with trust (B = − 0.37, p = 0.026), providing partial support for respectively hypotheses 1b and 2b for irrigation systems. However, the significant effect of sociocultural heterogeneity on unit quality remains in model 3 (B = − 0.19, p = 0.025) and trust is not significant, indicating that there is no indirect effect of sociocultural heterogeneity on unit quality through trust.

The indirect effects of economic or sociocultural heterogeneity on balance and unit quality for fishing grounds are not significant. For irrigation systems, the indirect effect of sociocultural heterogeneity on balance is marginally significant (B = − 0.22, p = 0.079), indicating modest support for the role of trust as stated in hypothesis 4b. The indirect effect of economic heterogeneity on balance through trust is just about not significant on the marginal level, but should, given the small sample size, not be ignored (B = − 0.17, p = 0.109). To check the robustness of the tests for the indirect effects, moderated mediation models were applied. The models can be found in Appendix 8.

Table 5 shows an overview of the results found per hypothesis. Counting the three samples—combined, fishery and irrigation—and the three methods—OLS regression as shown in main tables, the ordinal logistic regression [OLR] and the robustness check [RC] models with the alternative operationalisation of economic and sociocultural heterogeneity—there are nine tests for each hypothesis, except for hypotheses 4a and 4b which have not been calculated with the OLR models and thus have six tests. From this overview, we can conclude that there is convincing evidence for hypothesis 2a on the negative relation of economic heterogeneity with trust and hypothesis 3 on the positive relation of trust with CPR success, confirmed in, respectively, eight and nine tests out of nine. Hypothesis 1b is only supported for balance in irrigation systems, and hypothesis 5 is only supported regarding unit quality; it is marked as supported in all tests because all tests point out that trust is more important for fishing grounds than irrigation systems for unit quality, but the hypothesis as a whole—encompassing both balance and unit quality—is still only partially supported. Hypothesis 4a is partially supported with three significant indirect effects out of six tests in addition to the supported hypotheses 2a and 3.

Table 5 Overview of results of hypothesis tests, where ‘x’ marks that support is found

Discussion

The aim of this paper is to study whether and how economic and sociocultural heterogeneity affect the successful management of CPRs, to explore the role of trust and to see whether these relations differ for fisheries and irrigation systems. Using advanced imputation techniques to prepare the famous but challenging CPR Database allowed us to test the influence of two types of heterogeneity on CPR success at the same time, as well as looking at direct and indirect mechanisms. Existing literature predominantly suggests that both types of heterogeneity negatively influence collective action and therefore CPR success, that heterogeneity negatively affects mutual trust and that trust has a positive effect on societal outcomes.

For the multivariate analysis, we applied OLS regression models instead of ordinal logistic regression, favouring a simpler interpretation of coefficients. However, we tested all hypotheses in an ordinal logistic regression as well, plus we ran a model with alternative operationalisations of heterogeneity as a robustness check. In addition, we tested the found indirect effects through a moderated mediation analysis. Results are only considered robust if they are found for most of the combined and separate samples over the three analysis types. It appeared that neither form of heterogeneity has a robust significant relation with either measure of CPR success, contrary to a large body of existing literature. Economic heterogeneity, however, is found to be significantly negatively related to trust in all but one test, indicating that the role of economic heterogeneity regarding trust in CPRs is relevant. Trust has a positive association with both unit quality and balance in all tests, confirming the importance of mutual trust for positive CPR outcomes. A distinction between sector type proves relevant, since the significant interaction of trust with sector type on unit quality implies that trust only has a positive effect on unit quality for fisheries, and not for irrigation systems, something we later confirm in the subsample analyses. Trust seems to play a role in upkeeping balance in irrigation systems, so the role of trust cannot be disregarded for irrigation systems. Regarding our calculations for the indirect effects, we find partial support: a significant indirect effect of economic heterogeneity on balance through trust is found in the combined sample. To invigorate the results, and to explore the findings that were not considered robust in the current analysis, more data should be gathered and more research conducted.

The difference between findings in the subsamples may be related to fundamental differences between sector types. For fishing grounds, both the quality (for instance, size of the fish) and the balance between renewal and subtraction may be affected by trust between appropriators. For irrigation systems on the other hand, the balance may be affected but the quality of the water in an irrigation system may be less threatened by a lack of trust. These findings illustrate the difficulty of drawing conclusions from results across sector types since a specific measure of CPR success might mean different things for different CPR types. It is especially because of these differences that it is theoretically interesting to compare different CPRs, as it helps to understand the mechanisms behind the failure or success of different types of resources.

The findings are relevant given the increasing number of contemporary CPRs, also known as citizen collectives, or institutions for collective action, such as local communities producing their own green energy and urban agriculture projects with community farms (De Moor 2013b). Like irrigation systems, green energy production and community farms are self-made systems, monitoring is relatively easy, production may be unstable due to the dependency on the weather, and maintenance is required—either by the government if government-owned, or through collective actions of farmers if not. If indeed our findings for irrigation systems apply to such CPRs, we can expect that trust amongst appropriators will benefit the balance rather than the quality of these CPRs, and maybe that trust may in general play a smaller role in achieving collective action, given that monitoring is easy which makes trust a less important factor. For CPRs where monitoring requires more effort, such as fisheries and communal forests, trust will be more important in achieving high quality of the resource units and a balanced resource.

It has to be noted that this study has some shortcomings and that there is potential for improvement and replication. First, although the database provides a relatively large sample for a field of research dominated by case studies, the sample size has limited statistical power. A substantial number of missing data for specific variables implied a suboptimal operationalisation of economic heterogeneity. The imputation method used is however innovative and provides imputation diagnostics, such as the OOB, that gives us confidence in the imputation process and its results. Next to this, we reported the FMI where possible, herewith disclosing the level of uncertainty we have about the imputation of missing data. Second, individual level data instead of our case study level data could have provided more information on the role of trust; there may be individual confounding factors influencing the level of mutual trust of appropriators, such as general level of trust in society, how long an appropriator has resided in the community, individual cultural views or the history of interactions between individual appropriators. In addition, the CPR Database only provides very broad categorisations, even for variables of great interest, like trust; more detailed measurements would provide more detailed results and subsequently more detailed conclusions. Third, the cases in the CPR Database are all from before 1989. Whereas the argument of difficult monitoring in fishing grounds may be true for most fisheries back then, there currently exist modern solutions: the vessel monitoring system (VMS), used from the late 1990s on, and the automatic identification system (AIS), implemented in the early 2000’s. Both systems have significantly improved monitoring of fishing activities worldwide (Longépé et al. 2018; Natale et al. 2015). AIS has the main purpose of avoiding collisions, but can also be used to track fishing activities (Kurekin et al. 2019; Longépé et al. 2018; Matsumoto et al. 2016; Natale et al. 2015; Wu et al. 2016). This may reduce the need for high levels of mutual trust amongst fishermen, as real-time monitoring is now a possibility. It is unlikely, however, that such systems are in use in the smallest CPRs in less developed areas. Depending on the availability of these modern technologies, the role of trust in achieving high unit quality and balance may thus not be discarded. Lastly, as we discussed, there may be reversed causality. As argued, we have reasons to believe that heterogeneity is indeed influencing trust and CPR success; we referred to studies using instrumental variables showing that heterogeneity negatively affects trust, and experimental studies showing that trust indeed positively affects societal outcomes such as cooperation. However, in future research the causality issues could be addressed by replicating our research on CPR success using for instance experimental methods, since laboratory experiments are tailor-made to point out causality.

The research question on cooperative behaviour in CPRs is not only fundamental to social sciences, but also to the current state of affairs concerning the use and depletion of natural and man-made resources, such as rainforests, fish populations, oil and gas. There is currently a rise of new CPRs: an increasing amount of green energy cooperatives, local community farms, collective gardens and care cooperatives are part of everyday life due to an increasing privatisation of social services (De Moor 2013a, 2013b, 2018). These commons too, may become subject to the risk of overexploitation. Next to that, ‘classic’ commons like fishing grounds, forests and pastures have new meanings nowadays, and are not only regarded as sources of products but also as conservation tools and leisure areas. Contemporary problems surrounding CPRs include amongst others landscape planning, water management and even climate change (Bravo and De Moor 2008). The investigation of the impact of societal characteristics such as heterogeneity and trust on cooperation could provide new insights into the use and preservation of these CPRs, demonstrating the contributions that social and environmental sciences can make to a sustainable society.