Skip to main content
Log in

The polluter pays principle and Everglades restoration

  • Published:
Journal of Environmental Studies and Sciences Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Florida’s Agricultural Privilege Tax (APT) is a unique example of the “polluter pays principle” applied to reduce nonpoint source pollution. It has been more than 20 years since the APT was enacted as a building block for restoration of the Everglades ecosystem, the most extensive environmental restoration project in the world. This article provides a historical perspective on the environmental, socio-political, and institutional factors that led to the enactment and evolution of the APT. The efficiency and equity of the tax as part of a broader program to achieve water quality goals for the Everglades are also evaluated. A key result of this evaluation is that the APT has encouraged reductions in nutrient loads from agricultural areas, but these contributions have been limited. Dramatic increases in abatement costs to treat nonpoint outflows with stormwater treatment areas have occurred, and the timeline to achieve water quality objectives has been pushed forward by decades beyond the original goal. Contrary to the polluter pays principle, political compromises that have shaped the APT since its inception have shifted an increasing share of the burden to the public to reduce the flow of nutrients into the Everglades. An inconsistent regulatory approach to reduce nonpoint sources throughout the Everglades watershed may be the most important impediment to Everglades restoration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The APT is a type of “ambient tax” with a collective penalty for each polluter when the aggregate emission levels of pollution reduction across a group of sources are below the reduction target or an incentive credit when aggregate emissions reductions exceed the target. For references to the APT, see Hoffman and Boyd 2006; Karp 2005; Kling 2013; Nanda 2006; Ribaudo 2004; Segerson 1997; Selman and Greenhalgh 2009; Vossler et al. 2013; Willinger et al. 2014; Xepapadeas 2011.

  2. Total costs would be divided equally between federal and nonfederal (state and local) governments. Initial cost estimates for CERP were $8.2 billion over 30 years (NRC 2007, p. 76). More recent estimates are that CERP will take more than 50 years and at least $16.4 billion to complete (Stern 2017).

  3. The Central and Southern Flood Control District was initially created by the Florida Legislature in 1948 to be the local partner for the C&SFP. As the name suggests, the primary purpose was flood protection. It would be renamed the “South Florida Water Management District” in the Water Resources Act of 1972. Both entities were given ad valorem tax authority to meet the local cost-share for the C&SFP (Swihart 2011, pp. 23–33).

  4. Not all groups who were involved in the litigation were satisfied with the settlement terms in the decree. The Miccosukee Tribe and environmental groups, in particular, argued that the terms failed to set a timetable to control pollution and did not require sufficient financial responsibility for agricultural landowners in the EAA (Bovard 2004; Fuller 2011; Kenworthy 1993).

  5. All dollar values for the APT are in nominal $ to be consistent with the language of the EFA legislation over time.

  6. The majority of the land area and taxable value in the SFWMD is in Dade, Broward, and Palm Beach counties that includes Miami, Ft. Lauderdale, and West Palm Beach as well as other heavily urban communities. Because of the large taxable assessed value in these counties, the EFA tax rate is capped at 0.1 mill or $10 per $100,000 of taxable value.

  7. The “polluter pays” amendment was one of three ballot initiatives sponsored by the citizens group Save Our Everglades, Inc. Another initiative was a “fee on Everglades sugar production” that would impose a 1-cent fee per pound of sugar grown in the EAA. The third initiative would create the “Everglades Trust Fund” to be administered by the SFWMD for the purpose of resource conservation and abatement of water pollution. The 1-cent fee initiative was defeated after an aggressive campaign by the sugar industry (Santaniello 1996). Both the polluter pays and trust fund initiative were approved and were enacted as constitutional amendments.

  8. It should be noted that the land area for the FEBs in Restoration Strategies was originally intended for storage reservoirs under the CERP plan. The reservoirs would have provided new water flow to the remnant Everglades rather than directing existing flows to the STAs. These changes along with other modifications have reduced the expected new flows to the remnant Everglades by more than 50% from the original CERP plan (NRC 2016, pp. 156–159).

  9. Runoff is highly dependent on rainfall, so the baseline load is flow-weighted and is predicted with a regression model that accounts for the variability between current year rainfall and the baseline period of 1978–1988 (Davison et al. 2018, pp. 4-14–4-21). The target load is the predicted load reduced by 25%. Despite changes in cropping patterns in the EAA in the past two decades, the baseline period to measure TP load reductions has not changed.

  10. The percentage reduction in 1996 was 68% which exceeded the credits needed to lower the APT to the minimum rate. The extra credits were carried forward to reduce the rate in the following years, such as 1998, when the actual reduction would not fully reduce the tax to the minimum rate.

  11. Land, design, and construction costs are based on SFWMD (2017). All cost figures for STAs are nominal because the SFWMD does not provide an annual historical record of expenditures and there is no other official source for cost data. Projected land and construction costs after 2016 are from SFWMD (2014). Operating and maintenance (O&M) costs prior to 2011 are from Entry and Gottlieb (2014) and after 2011 from SFWMD, various years. O&M after 2016 are based on the 2012–2016 annual average of $26.3 million with 2% annual inflation. Acreage is from Pietro (2012) and represents the total surface area of the STA; the effective treatment area is approximately 57,000 acres.

  12. When the APT converted to a flat tax with no future incentive credits in 2013, the cumulative basin-wide total was more than 300 credits (Pescatore and Wang 2014). If the target reduction was not met and actual reductions were 0%, the cumulative credits would have still reduced the tax rate to the minimum for at least another decade.

  13. This estimate is based on an average of 460,000 acres/year in production during 1996–2016 and assumes no change in the acreage planted in the EAA for 2017–2026. The Florida Legislature in 2017 authorized $1.5 billion for a new reservoir in the EAA near the existing STAs and new FEBs. As of 2018, most of the acreage for the reservoir is publicly owned land and the SFWMD has purchased approximately 500 acres for the reservoir (SFWMD 2018).

  14. A variety of alternative dynamic tax structures for the APT could have provided stronger incentives to improve efficiency and address equity concerns. For example, Lee and Milon (1999) proposed a two-tier structure for the APT that would integrate the costs of STAs into the tax rate so that the full costs of TP abatement were considered in cropping and production practices within the EAA. For a more general discussion of alternative tax approaches, see Goetz and Martinez (2013) and Vossler et al. (2013). Kling (2013) also suggested that a permit trading program between nonpoint sources in the EAA could improve efficiency.

  15. This shifting of financial responsibility in public funding for the EAA is certainly not unique to water quality. The cost-sharing agreement for the original C&SFD that created today’s EAA had a federal cost-share of approximately 60% with the non-federal share funded mainly from ad valorem taxes on nonagricultural lands in South Florida and general revenues from the State. In his classic book on the early history of environmental policy in Florida, Luther Carter observed that cost-sharing for the C&SFD “…has favored agricultural interests – and especially the corporate farming enterprises of the Everglades Agricultural Area – in an outrageously unfair way” (Carter 1974, p. 96). Since agricultural lands south of Lake Okeechobee were a primary beneficiary of flood control yet paid a minimal share of the costs for the C&SFD, more land was brought into cultivation in the EAA than economically justified.

  16. Other explanations are also possible. Knox (2013), for example, describes the narrative of “Everglades restoration” as public policy designed to promote vague goals about benefits for the environment. At the same time, economic activities that benefit special interests are maintained even though these activities are detrimental to meaningful restoration.

Abbreviations

APT:

Agricultural Privilege Tax

BMP:

best management practices

CERP:

Comprehensive Everglades Restoration Plan

C&SFP:

Central and South Florida Flood Control Project

CWA:

Clean Water Act

DOJ:

Department of Justice

EAA:

Everglades Agricultural Area

EFA:

Everglades Forever Act

ENP:

Everglades National Park

EPA:

Environmental Protection Agency

EvPA:

Everglades Protection Area

FEB:

flow equalization basin

NRC:

National Research Council

PPP:

polluter pays principle

SFWMD:

South Florida Water Management District

STA:

stormwater treatment area

TMDL:

total maximum daily load

TP:

total phosphorus

References

  • Abrams RA (2014) The problem of nutrient pollution: lessons from Florida’s fragmented approach. Univ Denver Water Law Rev 17:207–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Abtew W, Piccone T, Pietro K, Xue S (2016) Hydrologic and treatment performance of constructed wetlands: the Everglades Stormwater treatment areas. In: Finlayson C et al (eds) The wetland book. Springer, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Ambec S, Ehlers L (2016) Regulation via the polluter pays principle. Econ J 126(June):884–906

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barley v. South Florida Water Management District (2002) Supreme court of Florida, case no. SC00-1998. 823 So2d 73

  • Bottcher A, Izuno F (eds) (1994) Everglades agricultural area: water, soil, crop, and environmental management. University Press of Florida, Gainesville

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovard J (2004) Your taxes go to sweetener but sour the Everglades. Christ Sci Monit

  • Carter L (1974) The Florida experience, land and water policy in a growth state. Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen H, Ivanoff D, Pietro K (2015) Long-term phosphorus removal in the Everglades stormwater treatment areas of South Florida in the United States. Ecol Eng 79(June):158–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chimney M (ed.) (2018) Performance and Operation of the Everglades Stormwater Treatment Areas, Ch 5B. In: South Florida Water Management District, 2018 South Florida environmental report. West Palm Beach

  • Chimney M, Goforth G (2006) History and description of the Everglades nutrient removal project, a subtropical constructed wetland in South Florida (USA). Ecol Eng 27(4):268–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christen K (1998) Florida court rules all Everglades polluters liable for cleanup costs. Water Environ Technol 10(3):15–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Daroub S, Van Horn S, Lang T, Diaz O (2011) Best management practices and long-term water quality trends in the Everglades agricultural area. Crit Rev Environ Sci Technol 41(S1):608–632

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Davis S, Ogden J (eds) (1994) Everglades: the ecosystem and its restoration. St. Lucie Press, Delray Beach

    Google Scholar 

  • Davison T, Iudicello J, Wang Y, Hutchins J, Olson S (2018) Source control programs in the Everglades construction project basins, Ch 4. 2018. South Florida Environmental Report, West Palm Beach, pp 4–22

  • Durant R, Fiorino D, O'Leary R (eds) (2004) Environmental governance reconsidered, challenges, choices, and opportunities. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Entry J, Gottlieb A (2014) The impact of stormwater treatment areas and agricultural best management practices on water quality in the Everglades protection area. Environ Monit Assess 186:1023–1037

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Filkins D (2016) Swamped: Jeb Bush’s fight over the Everglades. The New Yorker:32–37

  • Florida Department of Environmental Protection (2012) Governor Scott and DEP announce Everglades restoration projects will move forward. Tallahassee, FL. September 12, 2012

  • Florida Department of Environmental Protection (2018) Emergency authorizations implement measures to address South Florida algal blooms. Tallahassee, FL

  • Florida House of Representatives (2013) Final bill analysis—HB 7065. Tallahassee, FL. July 11, 2013

  • Fuller B (2011) Enabling problem-solving between science and politics in water conflicts: impasses and breakthroughs in the Everglades, Florida, USA. Hydrol Sci J 56(4):576–587

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fumero J, Rizzardi K (2001) The Everglades ecosystem: from engineering to litigation to consensus-based restoration. St Thomas Law Rev 13:667–696

    Google Scholar 

  • Garnache C, Swinton S, Herriges J, Lupi F, Stevenson J (2016) Solving the phosphorus pollution puzzle: synthesis and directions for future research. Am J Agric Econ 98(5):1334–1359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goetz R-U, Martinez Y (2013) Nonpoint source pollution and two-part instruments. Environ Econ Policy Stud 15:237–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goforth G (2001) Surmounting the engineering challenges of Everglades restoration. Water Sci Technol 44(11–12):295–302

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Graham W, Angelo M, Frazer T, Frederick P, Havens K, Reddy R (2015) Options to reduce high volume freshwater flows to the St. Lucie and Caloosahatchee estuaries and move more water from Lake Okeechobee to the Southern Everglades. University of Florida Water Institute

  • Gsteiger Y (2013) A clean Everglades—near the finish line or another watery mirage? Trends, American Bar Association, pp 9–12

  • Guest DG (2001) “This time for sure”—a political and legal history of water control projects in Lake Okeechobee and the Everglades. St Thomas Law Rev 13(3):645–667

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman S, Boyd J (2006) Environmental fees: can incentives help solve the Chesapeake’s nutrient pollution problems? Resources for the Future, RFF DP 06–38, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houck OA (2014) Cooperative federalism, nutrients, and the clean water act: three cases revisited. Environ Law Rep 44:10426–10442

    Google Scholar 

  • Johns G (2002) The Everglades forever act in the Everglades agricultural area: economic impacts of non-point source pollution controls. In: Letson D, Milon J (eds) Florida coastal environmental resources—a guide to economic valuation and impact analysis. Florida Sea Grant College program, SGR124. University of Florida, Gainesville, pp 117–129

    Google Scholar 

  • Julian P, Payne G, Xue S (2017) Water quality in the Everglades Protection Area, Ch. 3A. In: South Florida Water Management District, 2017 South Florida Environmental Report, West Palm Beach, FL

    Google Scholar 

  • Karp L (2005) Nonpoint source pollution taxes and excessive tax burden. Environ Resour Econ 31:229–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenworthy T (1993) Everglades revival plan unveiled. Washington Post, July 14, 1993

  • Klas M (2016) Sugar’s decades-long hold over Everglades came with a price. Miami Herald July 11, 2016

  • Kleindienst L (1997) Everglades group: make polluters pay for cleanup. Sun-Sentinel May 6, 1997

  • Kling C (2013) State level efforts to regulate agricultural sources of water quality impairment. Choices 28(3):1–4

    Google Scholar 

  • Knox C (2013) Distorted communication in the Florida Everglades: a critical theory analysis of ‘Everglades restoration. J Environ Policy Plan 15(2):269–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lake Okeechobee Technical Advisory Committee (1986) Final report Lake Okeechobee technical advisory committee. Florida Department of Environmental Regulation, Tallahassee

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee DJ, Milon JW (1999) Flexible incentives and water quality control technologies for the Everglades agricultural area. In: Casey F, Schmitz A, Swinton S, Zilberman D (eds) Flexible incentives for the adoption of environmental Technologies in Agriculture. Kluwer, pp 211–227

  • Leeds J (2016) South Florida environmental report. South Florida Water Management District I:5B–52B

  • Light A (2006) Spark plugs of policy innovation: intergovernmental relations and public participation in Florida’s Acceler8 initiative to speed Everglades restoration. Vermont Law Rev 30:939–968

    Google Scholar 

  • Light S, Dineen J (1994) Water control in the Everglades: a historical perspective. In: Davis S, Ogden J (eds) Everglades: the ecosystem and its restoration. St. Lucie Press, pp 47–84

  • Marcus N (1997) Save our Everglades fires back in court. Sun-Sentinel, April 26, 1997

  • Melville D (2005) ‘Whiskey is for drinking’: recent water law developments in Florida. J Land Use Environ Law 20(2):489–502

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitsch W (2014) When will ecologists learn engineering and engineers learn ecology? Ecol Eng 65:8–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitsch W, Zhang L, Marios D, Song K (2015) Protecting the Florida Everglades wetlands with wetlands: can stormwater phosphorus be reduced to oligotrophic conditions? Ecol Eng 80:8–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan C (2011) Judge: let EPA enforce cleanup rules. Tampa Bay Times, April 26, 2011

  • Nanda V (2006) Agriculture and the polluter pays principle. Am J Comp Law 54:317–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash J (2000) Too much market? Conflicts between tradeable emission permits and the “polluter pays” principle. Harv Law Rev 24:465–535

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council (2005) Re-engineering water storage in the Everglades: risks and opportunities. National Academies Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council (2007) Progress toward restoring the Everglades: the first biennial review—2006. National Academies Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council (2008) Progress toward restoring the Everglades: the second biennial review—2008. National Academies Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council (2010) Progress toward restoring the Everglades: the third biennial review—2010. National Academies Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council (2016) Progress toward restoring the Everglades: the sixth biennial review—2016. National Academies Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Navarette F, Shanmugam P, Alexander M (2013) Design of treatment wetlands to improve Everglades water quality. Fla Water Resour J

  • Noe G, Childers D, Jones R (2001) Phosphorus biogeochemistry and the impact of phosphorus enrichment: why is the Everglades so unique? Ecosystems 4:603–624

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Nordheimer J (1986) Florida fears that Lake Okeechobee is dying. New York Times, August 23, 1986

  • Office of Program Policy Analysis and Government Accountability (OPPAGA) (1997) Preliminary report: project cost estimates for implementing the Everglades Forever Act. Report 96–79. The Florida Legislature, Tallahassee

    Google Scholar 

  • Ollis S, Davis S, Glassner D, Hallas K (2018) Northern Everglades and Estuaries Protection Program – Annual Progress Report, Ch 8A. In: 2018 South Florida Environmental Report. South Florida Water Management District, West Palm Beach

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action, public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2001) Environmentally related taxes in OECD countries. Issues and Strategies, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2002) The polluter pays principle as it relates to international trade, Paris

  • Pescatore D, Wang Y (2014) Water year 2013 supplemental evaluations for regulatory source control programs in Everglades construction project basins, App 4–2. In: 2014 South Florida Environmental Report. South Florida Water Management District, West Palm Beach

    Google Scholar 

  • Pezzey J (1988) Market mechanisms of pollution control: ‘polluter pays’ economic and practical aspects. In: Turner K (ed) Sustainable environmental management: principles and practice. Belhaven Press, London, pp 190–242

    Google Scholar 

  • Pietro K (2012) Synopsis of the Everglades stormwater treatment areas, water year 1996–2012. South Florida water Management District, ASB-WQTT-12-001

  • Reid A, Uraizee I, Zhu Y (2016) A draining problem—how the release of Lake Okeechobee floodwaters is dirtying Florida’s coastline. Sun-Sentinel

  • Ribaudo M (2004) Policy exploration and implications for nonpoint source pollution control: discussion. Am J Agric Econ 86(5):1220–1221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzardi K (2001a) Alligators and litigators: a recent history of Everglades regulation and litigation. Fla Bar J 75(March):18–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzardi K (2001b) Translating science into law: phosphorus standards in the Everglades. J Land Use Environ Law 17(1):149–168

    Google Scholar 

  • Roka F, Baucom L, Rice R, Alvarez J (2010) Comparing costs and return for sugarcane production on sand and muck soils of Southern Florida, 2008–2009. J Am Soc Sugar Cane Technol 30:50–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Rolnik G (2016) Meet the sugar barons who used both sides of American politics to get billions in subsidies. ProMarket, Stigler Center at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, September 19, 2016

  • Santaniello N (1996) Tax proponents say big sugar `not off hook.' sun-sentinel, November 7, 1996

  • Segerson K (1997) Flexible incentives: a unifying framework for policy analysis. In: Casey F, Schmitz A, Swinton S, Zilberman D (eds) Flexible incentives for the adoption of environmental Technologies in Agriculture. Kluwer

  • Selman M, Greenhalgh S (2009) Eutrophication: policies, actions, and strategies to address nutrient pollution. World Resources Institute, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shade-Poole K, Moller G (2016) Impact and mitigation of nutrient pollution and overland water flow change on the Florida Everglades, USA. Sustainability 8(9):940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharfstein B, Zhang J (2017) Lake Okeechobee Watershed Research and Water Quality Monitoring Results and Activities, Ch 8B. In: 2017 South Florida Environmental Report. South Florida Water Management District, West Palm Beach

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheikh P, Johnson B (2004) Phosphorus mitigation in the Everglades. Congressional Research Service, Report RL32131, Washington, DC, January 13, 2004

  • Shortle J (2017) Nutrient pollution: a wicked challenge for economic instruments. Water Econ Policy 3:1650033–1–1650033–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Shortle J, Horan R (2013) Policy instruments for water quality protection. Ann Rev Resour Econ 5:111–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • South Florida Water Management District (2014) Restoration strategies for clean water for the Everglades. West Palm Beach, Fl., January 2014

  • South Florida Water Management District (2017) Public Records Request P003179–030317. West Palm Beach, FL

  • South Florida Water Management District (2018) SFWMD Approves Land Purchase from Willing Seller for EAA Storage Reservoir. April12, 2018. West Palm Beach, FL

  • South Florida Water Management District n.d. Everglades Forever Act Annual Financial Report. West Palm Beach, FL

  • Stern C (2017) Everglades Restoration: Federal Funding and Implementation Progress. Congressional Research Service, Report R42007, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone J, Legg J (1992) Agriculture and the Everglades. Soil and Water Conservation May– June:207–215

  • Sweedler M (2018) Florida fights giant algal bloom in Lake Okeechobee. Wall Street Journal July 16, 2018

  • Swihart T (2011) Florida’s Water: A Fragile Resource in a Vulnerable State. RFF Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Vossler C, Suter J, Poe G (2013) Experimental evidence on dynamic pollution tax policies. J Econ Behav Organ 93:101–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Davison T (ed) (2018) Appendix 4-1: Supplemental Information for the Everglades Agricultural Area Basin in the Southern Everglades. In: 2018 South Florida Environmental Report, South Florida Water Management District, West Palm Beach, FL.

  • Willinger M, Ammar N, Ennasri A (2014) Performance of the ambient tax: does the nature of the damage matter? Environ Resour Econ 59:479–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas A (2011) The economics of non-point-source pollution. Ann Rev Resour Econ 3:355–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to J. Walter Milon.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Milon, J.W. The polluter pays principle and Everglades restoration. J Environ Stud Sci 9, 67–81 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13412-018-0529-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13412-018-0529-y

Keywords

Navigation