Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Estimation and use of recreational fishing values in management decisions

  • Review
  • Published:
Ambio Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In many countries, commercial and recreational fishing compete for access to marine resources. In some cases, recreational catch outweighs commercial harvest and may threaten species otherwise protected from commercial fishing. This has led to increasing calls for improved management of recreational fishing in the broader context of general fisheries management. As a result, fisheries managers face the challenge to decide how to allocate the available marine resources between competing uses. In this paper, we review and explain two common approaches that have been used to support recreational fishing allocation decisions. While economic activity analysis is an appropriate tool to assess how a change in resource allocation would affect regional economic activity (economic contributions and impacts), it is ill-suited to assess associated gains or losses in welfare of society as a whole (economic efficiency). Hence, economic activity analysis and social cost–benefit analysis complement each other, with each providing a different set of information answering a different set of questions. Unfortunately, both types of analysis use the term “economic value” suggesting that they are alternative approaches that provide the same information, whereas in fact they are not. If the objective of fishery managers is to ensure that society as a whole is made better off, the appropriate metric is economic value as defined by welfare economics. Under this definition, all goods and services provided by marine resources that are beneficial to humans have economic value. This includes non-use values such as the continued existence of an endangered marine species. The aim of this paper is to support managers and policymakers in allocating marine resources by reviewing relevant economic principles, concepts, and tools in the context of recreational fishing, including the use and challenges of estimating the non-market benefits generated by recreational fishing experiences.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Abbott et al. (2018) refer to the introduction of individually tradeable quotas for commercial recreational fishing (Abbott et al. 2009), and harvest tags and fishing days for private recreational fishers (Abbott 2015; Johnston et al. 2007).

  2. Recreational and commercial fishing additionally competes with other users (e.g. scuba-divers) and non-users (e.g. people who value the continued existence of threatened fish species). This paper focuses on commercial and recreational fishing, acknowledging that maximizing the economic efficiency of marine resource allocations would require the inclusion of all users and non-users enjoyed by society.

  3. This concept of economic value is not inconsistent with the concept of bounded rationality (Simon 1972), which suggests that individuals may make less than optimal decisions due to the complexity of assessing all options. In such cases, choice may be made on past behaviours or limited information, rather than on relative economic value per se.

  4. We note that perfectly competitive markets are stylised models used to outline generally accepted principles of microeconomic theory. For more details see, for example, Mas-Collel et al. (1995) and Frank (2014).

  5. In the short run, producer surplus differs from profit by fixed costs (Frank 2014).

  6. The term ‘non-market value’ refers to the benefit enjoyed from the fishing experience (generated through fish catch and fishing-site characteristics) and does not include, for example, producer surplus enjoyed by the recreational fishing industry.

  7. Recreational fishers may be indifferent between going fishing or spending their time in another activity if the cost of participation equals the benefit they gain. In fact, Ditton and Sutton (2004) found that many recreational fishers would be readily prepared to substitute to other recreational activities if fishing was not available.

  8. A ‘region’ can be defined at any scope and scale.

  9. The terms “impact” and “contribution” appear to be defined differently across studies. Watson et al. (2007) offer definitions and suggest differentiating between the two terms by the way substitution effects are treated: impact studies take substitution effects into account, whereas contribution studies do not.

  10. Revenue approximates output value (also called gross production value).

  11. As pointed out by an anonymous reviewer, expenditure attribution can be estimated by means of socio-economic surveys, which have been used, for example, in Australia for this purpose.

  12. This also holds for value-added generated by the commercial fishing industry. The surplus enjoyed by consumers of seafood are equally excluded from this metric.

  13. Some economic activity studies report consumer surplus and add it to expenditure to derive the total benefit gained by recreational fishers (e.g. McLeod and Lindner 2018).

  14. Estimating the economic value of charter fishing trips may also require the use of non-market valuation methods even though charter fishing is a service purchased within markets. The market may be too ‘thin’ to generate enough information for the estimation of consumer surplus.

  15. For more detailed information on these methods including their strengths and limitations we refer the interested reader to the references identified in the following sections.

  16. Benefit transfer can be a low-cost alternative to employing revealed and stated preference methods. Benefit transfer involves extrapolating existing empirical value estimates (typically derived using revealed and stated preference methods) and using them in similar situations and locations (e.g. Johnston et al. 2015). However, applying this method is not without its challenges and depends before all else on the availability of suitable value estimates.

  17. Some studies have combined multi-site travel cost models with discrete choice models to overcome this limitation (e.g. Whitehead and Lew 2020).

  18. Hedonic pricing uses market prices for goods and services and estimates, through regression analysis, the proportion of the market value associated with the goods and services’ individual characteristics (e.g. Hanley and Barbier 2009).

  19. The selection of the payment vehicles may affect choice behaviour and estimated willingness-to-pay (e.g. Oviedo et al. 2016; Talpur et al. 2018).

  20. Access may require a fishing licence, which may incur a seasonal, annual, or multi-annual fee.

  21. See, for example, McPhee and Hundloe (2004b) who provide a critical review of case studies and their role in influencing changes in the allocation of access to fisheries in Australia.

  22. As pointed out by an anonymous reviewer, it is important to note that the efficiency of resource allocations is a dynamic concept. For example, price fluctuations in commercial fish markets, introductions of new gear restrictions, or changes in the site-choice preferences of recreational fishers might change the relative value between commercial and recreational fishing. Minimising the resulting efficiency loss would then require an adjustment of the allocated resources across the two sectors.

References

  • Abbott, J., V. Maharaj, and J. Wilen. 2009. Designing ITQ programs for commercial recreational fishing. Marine Policy 33: 766–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, J.K. 2015. Fighting over a red herring: The role of economics in recreational-commercial allocation disputes. Marine Resource Economics 30: 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, J.K., P. Lloyd-Smith, D. Willard, and W. Adamowicz. 2018. Status-quo management of marine recreational fisheries undermines angler welfare. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 115: 8948–8953.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Alberini, A., V. Zanatta, and P. Rosato. 2007. Combining actual and contingent behavior to estimate the value of sports fishing in the Lagoon of Venice. Ecological Economics 61 (2–3): 530–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arlinghaus, R., R. Tillner, and M. Bork. 2015. Explaining participation rates in recreational fishing across industrialised countries. Fisheries Management and Ecology 22: 45–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbier, E.B. 2017. Marine ecosystem services. Current Biology 27: 507–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boardman, A.E., D.H. Greenberg, A.R. Vining, and D.L. Weimer. 2018. Cost-benefit analysis: Concepts and practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I.E. Strand. 1989. A random utility model for sportfishing: Some preliminary results for Florida. Marine Resource Economics 6: 245–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breffle, W.S., and E.R. Morey. 2000. Investigating preference heterogeneity in a repeated discrete-choice recreation demand model of Atlantic salmon fishing. Marine Resource Economics 15: 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, T.C. 1984. The concept of value in resource allocation. Land Economics 60: 231–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlén, O., G. Bostedt, R. Brännlund, and L. Persson. 2019. Gone fishing: The value of recreational fishing in Sweden. Center for Environmental and Resource Economics, CERE, Gone fishing: The value of recreational fishing in Sweden (February 4, 2019)

  • Carter, D.W., and C. Liese. 2010. Hedonic valuation of sportfishing harvest. Marine Resource Economics 25: 391–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, H.Z., and S.R. Cosslett. 1998. Environmental quality preference and benefit estimation in multinomial probit models: A simulation approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80: 512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, F.C., W.F. Figueira, J.S. Ueland, and L.B. Crowder. 2004. The impact of United states recreational fisheries on marine fish populations. Science 305: 1958–1960.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Colquhoun, E. 2015. Measuring the economic value of recreational fishing at a national level. Fisheries Research and Development Corporation, FRDC Report 2012-214, Canberra

  • Cook, B.A., and R.L. McGaw. 1996. Sport and commercial fishing allocations for the Atlantic salmon fisheries of the Miramichi River. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics-Revue Canadienne D Economie Rurale 44: 165–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooke, S.J., and I.G. Cowx. 2004. the role of recreational fishing in global fish crises. BioScience 54: 857–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crowe, F.M., I.G. Longson, and L.M. Joll. 2013. Development and implementation of allocation arrangements for recreational and commercial fishing sectors in Western Australia. Fisheries Management and Ecology 20: 201–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deely, J., S. Hynes, and J. Curtis. 2019. Combining actual and contingent behaviour data to estimate the value of coarse fishing in Ireland. Fisheries Research 215: 53–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denniss, R. 2012. The use and abuse of economic modelling in Australia: Users’ guide to tricks of the trade. Canberra: The Australia Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Agriculture and Fisheries. 2017. Queensland Sustainable Fisheries Strategy, 2017–2027. Brisbane: Queensland Government.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Agriculture and Water Resources. 2017. Commonwealth Fisheries Policy Statement, Canberra

  • Department of Agriculture and Water Resources. 2018. Commonwealth Fisheries Harvest Strategy Policy: Framework for applying an evidence-based approach to setting harvest levels in Commonwealth fisheries. Canberra: Department of Agriculture and Water Resources.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ditton, R.B., and S.G. Sutton. 2004. Substitutability in recreational fishing. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 9: 87–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, S. F. 1990. An economics guide to allocation of fish stocks between commercial and recreational fisheries. NOAA Technical Report NMFS 94. Woods Hole, MA: National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration

  • Edwards, S.F. 1991. A critique of three “economics” arguments commonly used to influence fishery allocations. North American Journal of Fisheries Management 11: 121–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elkington, J. 1998. Cannibals with forks: The triple bottom line of 21st century business. Gabriola Island: New Society Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ernst & Young. 2015. Economic study of recreational fishing in Victoria. Victorian Recreational Fishing Peak Body. Melbourne

  • Ezzy, E., H. Scarborough, and A. Wallis. 2012. Recreational value of southern bluefin tuna fishing. Economic Papers: A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 31: 150–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R.H. 2014. Microeconomics and behavior. Boston: McGraw-Hill Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freese, S., J. Glock, and D. Squires. 1995. Direct allocation of resources and cost-benefit analysis in fisheries—An applicaiton to Pacific whiting. Marine Policy 19: 199–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gretton, P. 2013. On input-output tables: Uses and abuses. Melbourne: Productivity Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grogger, J.T., and R.T. Carson. 1991. Models for truncated counts. Journal of Applied Econometrics 6: 225–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanley, N., and E.B. Barbier. 2009. Pricing nature—Cost-benefit analysis and envrionmental policy. Cheltenham/Northampton MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, R., and K. Schnier. 2016. Commercial and recreational allocation for summer flounder. USA: Mid-Atlantic Fishery Management Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, B., M.A. Young, P.E. Carnell, S. Conron, D. Ierodiaconou, P.I. Macreadie, and E. Nicholson. 2020. Quantifying welfare gains of coastal and estuarine ecosystem rehabilitation for recreational fisheries. Science of The Total Environment 710: 134680.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, L.M. 2005. Recreational fishing site choice models: insights and future opportunities. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 10: 153–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ihde, T.F., M.J. Wilberg, D.A. Loewensteiner, D.H. Secor, and T.J. Miller. 2011. The increasing importance of marine recreational fishing in the US: Challenges for management. Fisheries Research 108: 268–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, R., D. Holland, V. Maharaj, and T. Warner. 2007. Fish harvest tags: An alternative management approach for recreational fisheries in the US Gulf of Mexico. Marine Policy 31: 5050–5516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, R.J., J. Rolfe, R.S. Rosenberger, and R. Brouwer, eds. 2015. Benefit transfer of environmental and resource values. A guide for researchers and practitioners. The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources, vol. 14. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knuckey, I., S. Sen, and P. McShane. 2019. Review of fishery resource access and allocation arrangements across Australian jurisdictions. Canberra: FRDC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layman, B. 2002. The use and abuse of input–output multipliers. Perth, WA: Department of Treasury and Finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lloret, J., S. Biton-Porsmoguer, A. Carreño, A. Di Franco, R. Sahyoun, P. Melià, J. Claudet, C. Sève, et al. 2019. Recreational and small-scale fisheries may pose a threat to vulnerable species in coastal and offshore waters of the western Mediterranean. ICES Journal of Marine Science 77: 2255–2264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lloret, J., and T. Font. 2013. A comparative analysis between recreational and artisanal fisheries in a Mediterranean coastal area. Fisheries Management and Ecology 20: 148–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovell, S., S. Steinback, and J. Hilger. 2013. The economic contribution of marine angler expenditures in the United States, 2011. U.S. Department of Commerce, NOAA Tech. Memo. NMFS-F/SPO-134.

  • Mas-Colell, A., M.D. Whinston, and J.R. Green. 1995. Microeconomic theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Massey, D.M., S.C. Newbold, and B. Gentner. 2006. Valuing water quality changes using a bioeconomic model of a coastal recreational fishery. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 52: 482–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLeod, P., and R. Lindner. 2018. economic dimension of recreational fishing in Western Australia. Perth, WA: Recfishwest.

    Google Scholar 

  • McPhee, D., and T. Hundloe. 2004a. The role of expenditure studies in the (mis)allocation of access to fisheries resources in Australia. Australasian Journal of Environmental Management 11: 34–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McPhee, D., and T. Hundloe. 2004b. The role of expenditure studies in the (mis)allocation of access to fisheries resources in Australia. Australasian Journal of Environmental Management 11: 13–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mkwara, L., D. Marsh, and R. Scarpa. 2015. The effect of within-season variability on estimates of recreational value for trout anglers in New Zealand. Ecological Economics 119: 338–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, J.J., P.G. Allen, T.H. Stevens, and D. Weatherhead. 2005. A meta-analysis of hypothetical bias in stated preference valuation. Environmental and Resource Economics 30: 313–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council. 2005. Valuing ecosystem services: Toward better environmental decision-making. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oviedo, J.L., A. Caparros, I. Ruiz-Gauna, and P. Campos. 2016. Testing convergent validity in choice experiments: Application to public recreation in Spanish stone pine and cork oak forests. Journal of Forest Economics 25: 130–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pascoe, S. 2019. Recreational beach use values with multiple activities. Ecological Economics 160: 137–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pascoe, S., A. Doshi, Q. Dell, M. Tonks, and R. Kenyon. 2014. Economic value of recreational fishing in Moreton Bay and the potential impact of the marine park rezoning. Tourism Management 41: 53–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearsons, G.A. 2017. Travel cost models. In Introduction to revealed preference methods, ed. P.A. Champ, K.J. Boyle, and T.C. Brown, 187–233. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poudel, J., I.A. Munn, and J.E. Henderson. 2018. An input-output analysis of recreational fishing expenditures (2006 & 2011) across the southern United States. International Journal of Environmental Studies 75: 650–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pouso, S., S. Ferrini, R.K. Turner, Á. Borja, and M.C. Uyarra. 2019. Monetary valuation of recreational fishing in a restored estuary and implications for future management measures. ICES Journal of Marine Science 77: 2295–2303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prayaga, P., J. Rolfe, and N. Stoeckl. 2010. The value of recreational fishing in the Great Barrier Reef, Australia: A pooled revealed preference and contingent behaviour model. Marine Policy 34: 244–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Productivity Commission. 2016. Marine fisheries and aquaculture. Canberra: Productivity Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Properjohn, M., and J. Tisdell. 2010. Results of a Pilot Travel Cost Study of the Recreational Use of Moreton Bay. Fishecon Working Paper Series 1/10

  • Provencher, B., K.A. Baerenklau, and R.C. Bishop. 2002. A finite mixture logit model of recreational angling with serially correlated random utility. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 84: 1066–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Provencher, B., and R.C. Bishop. 2004. Does accounting for preference heterogeneity improve the forecasting of a random utility model? A case study. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48: 793–810.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raguragavan, J., A. Hailu, and M. Burton. 2013. Economic valuation of recreational fishing in Western Australia: Statewide random utility modelling of fishing site choice behaviour. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 57: 539–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, A., M. Munday, N. Roche, A. Brown, M. Armstrong, J. Hargreaves, S. Pilgrim-Morrison, K. Williamson, and K. Hyder. 2017. Assessing the contribution of recreational sea angling to the English economy. Marine Policy 83: 146–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rolfe, J., and B. Dyack. 2011. Valuing recreation in the Coorong, Australia, with travel cost and contingent behaviour models. Economic Record 87: 282–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rolfe, J., and P. Prayaga. 2007. Estimating values for recreational fishing at freshwater dams in Queensland. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 51: 157–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, K.L., F.I. Trinnie, R. Jones, A.M. Hart, and B.S. Wise. 2016. Recreational fisheries data requirements for monitoring catch shares. Fisheries Management and Ecology 23: 218–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharma, K.R., and P.S. Leung. 2001. Economic impacts of catch reallocation from the commercial fishery to the recreational fishery in Hawaii. North American Journal of Fisheries Management 21: 125–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shrestha, R.K., A.F. Seidl, and A.S. Moraes. 2002. Value of recreational fishing in the Brazilian Pantanal: A travel cost analysis using count data models. Ecological Economics 42: 289–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A. 1972. Theories of bounded rationality. Decision and Organization 1: 161–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorg, C.F., and J.B. Loomis. 1986. Economic value of idaho sport fisheries with an update on valuation techniques. North American Journal of Fisheries Management 6: 494–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Southwick, R., J.C. Holdsworth, T. Rea, L. Bragg, and T. Allen. 2018. Estimating marine recreational fishing’s economic contributions in New Zealand. Fisheries Research 208: 116–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talpur, M.A., M.J. Koetse, and R. Brouwer. 2018. Accounting for implicit and explicit payment vehicles in a discrete choice experiment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy 7: 363–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tietenberg, T., and L. Lewis. 2008. Envrionmental and natural resource economics. Boston: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinch, R., L. Mathieu, S. Anderson, and A. Radford. 2015. Comparing industry sector values, with a case study of commercial fishing and recreational sea angling. UKFEN, supported by Seafish, Defra and Marine Scotland

  • Toivonen, A.-L., E. Roth, S. Navrud, G. Gudbergsson, H. Appelblad, B. Bengtsson, and P. Tuunainen. 2004. The economic value of recreational fisheries in Nordic countries. Fisheries Management and Ecology 11: 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train, K.E. 1998. Recreation demand models with taste differences over people. Land Economics 74: 230–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watson, P., J. Wilson, T. Dawn, and S. Winte. 2007. Determining economic contributions and impacts: What is the difference and why do we care? Journal of Regional Analysis and Policy 37: 140–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitehead, J.C., and D.K. Lew. 2020. Estimating recreation benefits through joint estimation of revealed and stated preference discrete choice data. Empirical Economics 58: 2009–2029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamazaki, S., S. Rust, S. Jennings, J. Lyle, and S. Frijlink. 2013. Valuing recreational fishing in Tasmania and assessment of response bias in contingent valuation. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 57: 193–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the four anonymous reviewers for their useful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gabriela Scheufele.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Scheufele, G., Pascoe, S. Estimation and use of recreational fishing values in management decisions. Ambio 51, 1275–1286 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13280-021-01634-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13280-021-01634-7

Keywords

Navigation