Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Technological Revolutions and Economic Development: Endogenous and Exogenous Fluctuations

  • Published:
Journal of the Knowledge Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Innovation scholars have highlighted that technological revolutions generate long-run fluctuations in innovative and economic activity. This paper aims at examining whether such fluctuations are endogenous or exogenous. This question is particularly important with respect to the current debate on the productivity slowdown and a potential new technological revolution. We propose a framework that integrates both endogenous and exogenous factors. On the one hand, the economic system tends to generate endogenously, and therefore recurrently, technological revolutions, structural change, and associated long-run fluctuations of production. This tendency is explained via a process of co-evolution between investment in innovation and demand, based on cumulative multiplier and accelerator feedback effects. On the other hand, exogenous factors are expected to exert a major impact upon this endogenous process by influencing the length and amplitude of fluctuations, i.e., the timing and economic impact of technological revolutions. Exogenous factors may include random historical events (e.g., wars), technical factors, public policies, and socio-institutional actors. To provide a preliminary evidence supporting the framework, we have fitted the ICTs (Information and Communications Technologies) cycle and the economic cycle to patent and productivity data, respectively. Our results suggest that the current productivity slowdown may be a signal that the economic system needs to change its leading technologies. This phase of technological ferment may represent an important and rare opportunity, for public policies and socio-institutional actors, to orient future development toward socially desirable directions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. ICTs include semiconductors, computers, software, telecoms, and the Internet (Perez 2010).

  2. Note that by replying to the observation that R&D activity generally declines during depression periods, Kleinknecht pointed out that it is the relative propensity to embrace radical versus incremental innovations that is at issue here (Silverberg 2002).

  3. Assuming that investment in innovation also has a positive impact on total employment would reinforce the proposed co-evolutionary process between technological and economic variables.

  4. Note that although a new paradigm may start emerging during the decline phase of the previous paradigm (dotted curve), the proper phase of emergence begins later, when the stock of investment has reached a minimum threshold (the logistic curve is indeed asymptotic to 0). Symmetrically, the decline of a paradigm is supposed to asymptotically continue (dotted curve) after the end of the proper phase of decline.

  5. Following Andersen (1999), instances of negative growth are disregarded and considered periods of crisis.

  6. Also note that in this context, depressions do not necessarily need to occur since recessions may be sufficient to trigger the emergence of a new technological cluster, if favorable exogenous factors intervene. This implies that logistic curves representing in Fig. 1, the stock of investment in the paradigm, may be partially overlapping.

  7. Data have been provided by Bergeaud et al. (2016). Following Bergeaud et al. (2016), data have been smoothed by using the HP filter (lambda = 500).

  8. Most scholars identify one big wave that would expand from the end of the nineteenth century to the 1970s and that would correspond to the second industrial revolution, based on innovations like electricity, internal combustion engine, and chemistry. Freeman and Perez (1988), instead, identify two waves corresponding to the electrification from 1890 to 1930 and to the motorization from 1940 to 1980.

  9. Data since 1977 have been extracted from Eurostat; data before 1977 have been extracted from the CRIOS dataset (Coffano and Tarasconi 2014) by using the IPC codes provided by OECD (https://www.oecd.org/sti/inno/40807441.pdf).

References

  • Andersen, B. (1999). The hunt for S-shaped growth paths in technological innovation: a patent study. Journal Evolutionary Economics, 9(4), 487–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, P., & Tushman, M. L. (1990). Technological discontinuities and dominant designs: a cyclical model of technological change. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 604–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Archibugi, D. (2017). Blade runner economics: will innovation lead the economic recovery? Research Policy, 46, 535–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Archibugi, D., Filippetti, A., & Frenz, M. (2013a). The impact of the economic crisis on innovation: evidence from Europe. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 80, 1247–1260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Archibugi, D., Filippetti, A., & Frenz, M. (2013b). Economic crisis and innovation: is destruction prevailing over accumulation? Research Policy, 42, 303–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu, S., Fernald, J. G., & Shapiro, M. G. (2001). Productivity growth in the 1990s: technology, utilization, or adjustment? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 55, 117–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baxter, M., & Kouparitsas, M. A. (2005). Determinants of business cycle comovement: a robust analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, January, 52(1), 113–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergeaud, A., Cette, G., & Lecat, R. (2016). Productivity trends from 1890 to 2012 in advanced countries. Review of Income and Wealth, 62(3), 420–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi, S., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2000). Technological regimes and Schumpeterian patterns of innovation. The Economic Journal, 110, 388–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, D. M., Oliner, S. D., & Sichel, D. E. (2013). Is the information technology revolution over? International Productivity Monitor, no, 25(Spring), 20–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caiani, A., Godin, A., & Lucarelli, S. (2014). Innovation and finance: a stock flow consistent analysis of great surges of development. Journal Evolutionary Economics, 24, 421–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cette, G. (2014). Presidential conference. Does ICT remain a powerful engine of growth? Revue d'économie politique, 124, 473–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cette, G., Clerc C., Bresson L., 2015. Contribution of ICT Diffusion to Labour Productivity Growth: The United States, Canada, the Eurozone, and the United Kingdom, 1970–2013. International productivity monitor, n°28, Spring.

  • Christensen, C. M. (1997). The innovator's dilemma: when new technologies cause great firms to fail. Boston, Massachusetts: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, J., Freeman, C., & Soete, L. (1981). Long waves, inventions, and innovations. Futures, 13(4), 308–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coffano, M., Tarasconi, G., 2014. CRIOS-Patstat database: sources, contents and access rules (February 1, 2014). Center for Research on innovation, organization and strategy, CRIOS working paper n.1. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2404344

  • Crafts, N. F. R. (1995). Exogenous or endogenous growth? The industrial revolution reconsidered. The Journal of Economic History, 55(4), 745–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A. (2001). Path dependence, its critics and the quest for 'Historical economics. In P. Garrouste & S. Ioannides (Eds.), Evolution and path dependence in economic ideas: past and present. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, P., & A. (1990). The dynamo and the computer: an historical perspective on the modern productivity paradox. The American Economic Review, 80(2), 355–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1982). Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. Research Policy, 11, 147–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., and Virgillito, M. E., 2019. Whither the evolution of the contemporary social fabric? New technologies and old socio-economic trends. LEM papers series 2019/02.

  • Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., & Roventini, A. (2010). Schumpeter meeting Keynes: a policy-friendly model of endogenous growth and business cycles. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34(9), 1748–1767.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., & Perez, C. (1988). Structural crises of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour. In G. Dosi et al. (Eds.), Technical change and economic theory (pp. 38–66). London: Francis Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. J., 2012. Is U.S. economic growth over? faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds. NBER working papers 18315, National Bureau of economic research, Inc.

  • Gordon, R. J. (2013). US productivity growth: the slowdown has returned after a temporary revival. International Productivity Monitor, Centre for the Study of Living Standards, 25, 13–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1957). Hybrid corn: an exploration in the economics of technological change. Econometrica, 25(4), 501–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. (2001). Information technology and the US economy. The American Economic Review, 91(1), 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D., Ho, M., & Stiroh, K. (2006). Potential growth of the US economy: will the productivity resurgence continue? January: Business Economy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, R., Schot, J., & Hoogma, R. (1998). Regime shift to sustainability through process of niche formation: the approach of strategic niche management. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 10(2), 175–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleinknecht, A. (1990). Are there Schumpeterian waves of innovation? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 14, 81–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleinknecht, A., & van der Panne, G. (2006). Who was right? Kuznets in 1930 or Schumpeter in 1939?. In T.C. Devezas (ed.), Kondratieff waves, warfare and world security. Amsterdam: IOS Press, 2006, 118–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kondratieff, N. D. (1935). The long waves in economic life. Review of Economics and Statistics, 17(6), 105–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konstantakis, P. G., & Michaelides, K. N. (2017). Does technology cause business cycles in the USA? A Schumpeter-inspired approach. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 43, 15–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Zinkina, J., & Bogevolnov, J. (2011). Kondratieff waves in global invention activity (1900–2008). Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 78, 1280–1284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S.S., 1930. Secular movements in production and prices. Their nature and their bearing upon cyclical fluctuations. Houghton Mifflin, The Riverside press, Boston; 1967 reprint: Kelley, New York.

  • Lee, M., Yun, J. J., Pyka, A., Won, D., Kodama, F., Schiuma, G., Park, H., Jeon, J., Park, K., Jung, K., Yan, M.-R., Lee, S., & Zhao, X. (2018). How to respond to the fourth industrial revolution, or the second information technology revolution? Dynamic new combinations between technology, market, and society through open innovation. Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market and Complexity, 4, 21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B. (2017). Is there a technological fix for the current global stagnation? A response to Daniele Archibugi, Blade Runner economics: Will innovation lead the economic recovery? Research Policy, 46, 544–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markard, J., Raven, R., & Truffer, B. (2012). Sustainability transitions: an emerging field of research and its prospects. Research Policy, 41, 955–967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mensch, G. (1979). Stalemate in technology – Innovations overcome the depression. New York: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (1993). 1993. "Introduction: the new economic history and the industrial revolution." in The British industrial Revolution: An economic perspective, edited by Joel Mokyr. Oxford: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2015). The future of productivity. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD, 2017. The Next Production Revolution: Implications for Governments and Business.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Perez, C. (2010). Technological revolutions and techno-economic paradigms. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 34, 185–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perez, C. (2013). Unleashing a golden age after the financial collapse: drawing lessons from history. Environmental Innovations and Societal Transitions, 80(1), 11–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pillai, U. (2011). Technological progress in the microprocessor industry (pp. 13–16). Survey of Current Business.

  • Rosenberg, N., & Frischtak, R. (1983). Long waves and economic growth: a critical appraisal. The American Economic Review, 73(2), 146–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti, P. P., & Pyka, A. (2012). On the co-evolution of innovation and demand: some policy Implications. Revue de L’OFCE / Debates and Policies, 124, 347–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti, P. P., & Pyka, A. (2013). The co-evolution of innovation, demand and growth. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 22, 461–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmookler, J. (1966). Invention and economic growth. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles. A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. London: McGraw-Hill Book Co..

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwab, K. (2017). The fourth industrial revolution. New York: Crown Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G. (2002). The discrete charm of the bourgeoisie: quantum and continuous perspectives on innovation and growth. Research Policy, 31(8–9), 1275–1289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G., & Lehnert, D. (1993). Long waves and 'Evolutionary Chaos' in a simple Schumpeterian model of embodied technical change. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 4, 9–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G., & Verspagen, B. (2003). Breaking the waves: a Poisson regression approach to Schumpeterian clustering of basic innovations. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27, 671–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solomou, S. (1986). Innovation clusters and Kondratieff long waves in economic growth. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 10, 101–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinmueller, W. E. (2017). Science fiction and innovation: a response. Research Policy, 46, 550–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tushman, M., & Romanelli, E. (1985). Organizational evolution: a metamorphosis model of convergence and reorientation. In L. L. Cummings & M. S. Barry (Eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior (Vol. 7, pp. 171–222). Greenwich: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tylecote, A. (2019). Biotechnology as a new techno-economic paradigm that will help drive the world economy and mitigate climate change. Research Policy, 48, 858–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Utterback, J. M., & Suarez, F. (1993). Innovation, competition, and industry structure. Research Policy, 22(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank for their useful comments Daniele Archibugi, Claude Diebolt, André Lorentz, Moritz Mueller, Pierpaolo Parrotta, and Patrick Rondé, as well as the participants at the 17th Conference of the International J. A. Schumpeter Society (Seoul), the 2d BETA-Workshop in Economics of Science and Innovation (Strasbourg), the 2019 EMAEE conference (Brighton), and the 2019 EAEPE conference (Warsaw). I would also like to thank Enrico Burello, who greatly helped me during the empirical analysis. The responsibility for eventual errors remains exclusively mine.

Funding

This work has received financial support by the project CPER-ARIANE “DYN-TECH,” funded by Lorraine region and FEDER.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marianna Epicoco.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Epicoco, M. Technological Revolutions and Economic Development: Endogenous and Exogenous Fluctuations. J Knowl Econ 12, 1437–1461 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-020-00671-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-020-00671-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation