Skip to main content
Log in

The contribution of Carlo Casarosa on the forerunners of the life cycle hypothesis by Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Italian economist Carlo Casarosa published a study in 2002 claiming that there existed two contributions—one by Roy Harrod (1948, Lecture Two) and one by James Duesenberry (1949, Chapter III, Sect. 9)—that could be considered forerunners of Modigliani and Brumberg’s pioneering works about the Life Cycle Hypothesis (LCH). Those contributions, according to the Italian scholar, had been, until that moment, scarcely known by the scientific community. Particularly, he pointed out that, while Modigliani in 1970 eventually recognized Harrod’s contribution to the LCH, he never mentioned Duesenberry’s work. After presenting and commenting on the content of Casarosa’s investigation, in this paper we present the results of an extended historiographical analysis that we have carried out on the early literature about the LCH. Rather interestingly, our analysis shows that several economists, especially from Cambridge (UK), had acknowledged the role of Harrod (together with the one of Frank Ramsey) since early 1950s, while Duesenberry’s contribution to the LCH was completely ignored.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A list, though not exhaustive, of relevant references is Modigliani (1966), (1970), (1975), (1986) and (1988), Modigliani and Ando (1957), Ando and Modigliani (1959), (1960) and (1963), Drèze and Modigliani (1975), Modigliani and Tarantelli (1975), Modigliani and Sterling (1983). On some occasion Modigliani referred to the LCH as to M-B-A model (see for example, Ando and Modigliani 1960, p. 78), to acknowledge Ando’s contribution.

  2. “In Chapter 2 of Towards a Dynamic Economics, Sir Roy Harrod made a pioneering contribution to the study of aggregate saving by analysing the implications of the basic assumption that current saving decisions of households reflect an endeavour to achieve the preferred allocation of lifetime resources to consumption (and bequests) over the life cycle. Since that time, this approach has been pursued by a number of authors, both at the theoretical level and for the analysis of empirical data” (Modigliani 1970, p. 197).

  3. See for example, Mayer (1972), Kouri (1986), Baranzini (2005), Deaton (2005), Szenberg and Ramrattan (2008), Puttaswamaiah (2009), Read (2011), Rancan (2020).

  4. Earlier discussions on Harrod’s second lecture had been provided by Higgins (1948), Robinson (1949) and Graaff (1950), who, of course could not refer to M-B LCH, published few years later. See Sect. 4.1.

  5. In fact, Mayer (1972) includes Harrod’s theory within the “wealth theories”, while Duesenberry’s contribution on “relative income” within the “measured income theories”. The latter set includes both the models of “absolute income” (Keynes and others) and that of “relative income” itself (Mayer 1972, p. 16).

  6. As for the Cambridge economist, Attanasio (2015) has recently argued that, in the light of his pioneering insight onto an Overlapping Generation Model provided in his famous 1928 article (see Ramsey 1928, pp. 557–8), Ramsey can (and must) to all extent be included within the restricted circle of authoritative forerunners of the LCH. We do agree with this argument, although Ramsey provided a very brief sketch of an OLG model. In any case, in this work we will deal with Ramsey’s insight only indirectly, given that our main focus is on Carlo Casarosa’s work, who did not discuss the contribution of the Cambridge economist.

  7. See Casarosa (2002), p. 66.

  8. The present and all other translations of the Italian text of Casarosa are made by the authors.

  9. It is worth recalling Modigliani’s own words: “our purpose was to show that all the well-established empirical regularities could be accounted for in terms of rational, utility-maximizing, consumers allocating optimally their resources to consumption over their life, in the spirit of Irving Fisher (1930)” (Modigliani, 1986, p. 299). Moreover, commenting on the list of motives for saving that Keynes presented in Chapter 9 of his General Theory (Keynes 1936), some years later, Modigliani argued that “five of these, which include “to increase one's future income” or “to insure one's independence and power”, implied that all, or nearly all, the accumulation would finally wind up as bequeathed wealth. This, in turn, meant that most private wealth originated through bequests – that is, it either had been received through bequests or was destined to be bequeathed. And, indeed, how else could society accumulate wealth?” (Modigliani, 1988, p. 15). Modigliani clearly aimed at stressing that “one of the most significant early results of the Life Cycle Hypothesis was to establish that, even in the absence of bequests, the mere fact that income dries up with retirement could generate, for the entire economy, an amount of (hump) wealth quite large relative to income” (ibidem, p. 16).

  10. In fact, M-B (1954, 1980) cite Umberto Ricci’s works (1926, 1927) on intertemporal choices, and only in his later works of the 1970s the more well-known contributions by Irving Fisher. For a deeper insight on Ricci’s works, see Pavanelli (2006) and the references contained therein.

  11. We notice that, formally, the problem of the individual at the beginning of his/her adult life can be posed as follows: \(Max~U = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^L {{\beta ^{i - 1}}v\left( {{c_i}} \right),}\) s.t. \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^L {\frac{{{c_i}}}{{{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}^{i - 1}}}} \le {W_1}}\) and \(w_{L} \ge 0,\) where \(v\left( {c_{i} } \right)\) is the intertemporal utility defined over individual consumption, \(c_{i} > 0\), \(v^{\prime} > 0\), \(v^{\prime\prime} < 0;\) \(\beta \equiv \frac{1}{1 + \delta }\) is the individual discount factor and \(\delta > 0\) is the individual discount rate, \({W_1} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^N {\frac{{{y_i}}}{{{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}^{i - 1}}}} + {a_1}}\) is lifetime wealth in present value, \(y_{i}\) is the labor income in period i in real terms, \(a_{1}\) is the starting level of wealth in real terms, potentially different from zero, r is the real interest rate, supposed constant. First order conditions for an interior solution yield: \(MRS_{t,t + 1} \equiv \frac{{v^{\prime}\left( {c_{t} } \right)}}{{v^{\prime}\left( {c_{t + 1} } \right)}} = \frac{1 + r}{{1 + \delta }}\), which is the well-known Euler equation stating that the marginal rate of substitution of consumption between two periods must equate the interest factor.

  12. Casarosa (2002, p. 77) points out that the hypothesis of static expectations is too restrictive, although it was rather the rule at the time Modigliani and Brumberg wrote their articles, and, thus, represents a limiting feature of the M-B LCH (on this respect, see also Farrell 1970). In fact, he will explore the implications of taking account of rational expectations (and family composition) in a paper published in 2010 (see Casarosa and Spataro 2010). Indeed, we note that Modigliani was familiar with the issue of how to model economic agents’ expectations, albeit, as discussed in Hands (1990), being a forerunner of the “rational expectation” hypothesis (Grunberg and Modigliani, 1954), he simply disregarded it in his publications on the grounds of either pragmatism or simply because he found it not fully convincing in describing the actual behavior of individuals. In any case Modigliani discussed the role of expectations in the LCH on several occasions (e.g., Modigliani 1966). For a deeper and interesting insight, see Hartley (2004).

  13. E.g., Drèze and Modigliani (1975), Modigliani (1970, 1975), Modigliani and Tarantelli (1975) Modigliani and Sterling (1983). See Deaton (2005) for a review on more recent developments.

  14. It is worth noting that neither Harrod cites Duesenberry nor the latter cites the former in their books. Casarosa argues that the American economist completes his own monograph [Duesenberry (1949)] before the publication of Harrod's work and, therefore, probably without knowing the results contained in the latter book and that “it is much more likely that Modigliani and Brumberg glimpsed Duesenberry's ideas than Harrod's” (Casarosa 2002, p. 63). The first fact is probably true, given that in the preface of his volume, Duesenberry writes that “under the title “The Consumption Function” the original version of this book was submitted as a doctoral dissertation at the University of Michigan in February 1948”. The second guess by Casarosa can be agreed with too, although it is worth recalling that, as Harrod writes in the first page of the foreword of his book, “these lectures were composed during the autumn of 1946 and delivered in the University of London in February 1947”.

  15. We note that Cassel (1932) used the same assumptions when introducing the case of a Uniformly Progressing State (par. 6, pp. 32 ff.). According to Kurz and Salvadori (2003), the model of exogenous growth provided by Cassel can be considered the “proximate starting point of the development of neoclassical growth theory” (Kurz and Salvadori 2003, p. 18).

  16. For a deeper insight see Comim (2000).

  17. In Harrod’s words: “there remains the saving required to provide for the saver’s needs during his own life-time, saving destinated to be subsequently dissipated in dis-saving. I shall call this hump-saving” (Harrod 1948, p. 49). Later, he adds that “the hump of savings at any times embodies the savings of people of all ages; it is a cross-section (ibidem). In fact, Modigliani can be rightly agreed with when arguing that this terminology is somehow confusing, given that the hump-wealth would have been more appropriate (Modigliani 1986, p. 300). In an interesting review of Harrod’s book, Joan Robinson, rather surprisingly, writes that “unfortunately his exposition is so idiosyncratic, and the matter is so closely packed in the small compass of five lectures, that his book is extremely hard to follow (the original audience of the lectures must have had a strenuous time of it)” (Robinson 1949, p. 69).

  18. Please note that Harrod cites Cassel, who had reached the same conclusions, when discussing about “saving for posterity” (Harrod 1948, p. 49), although he does not mention Cassel’s contribution on the link between saving and population growth. Moreover, Harrod does not cite the work of Neisser (1944).

  19. Joan Robinson defines Harrod’s line of reasoning in this respect, as “an argument of some subtlety” (Robinson 1949, p. 74).

  20. We can summarise Harrod’s line of reasoning as follows: 1) there seems no general presumption that the rate of saving will be precisely what is required to sustain a steady advance of production with the rate of interest constant (Harrod 1948, p. 54); 2) we may have to contemplate a continuously rising or falling rate of interest (more likely a falling interest rate in presence of positive per capita growth and stationary population) (ibidem); 3) in general, financial markets are not prepared to manage the systematic fall in the interest rate required to absorb the over-saving of a growing economy (ibidem, p. 62); 4) a public intervention is needed to restore the harmony between “thriftiness” and capital requirements, through monetary policies aimed at controlling (reducing) the interest rate; 5) however, according to Harrod, the latter will not suffice given that is far from clear how aggregate saving will react to changes in the interest rate, so that he also suggests that the latter should be accompanied by accommodating fiscal policies.

  21. As already quoted above, in the preface of the book Duesenberry refers to his 1948 doctoral dissertation, giving evidence that his ideas were elaborated well before 1949. On the other hand, Harrod delivered his lectures at the University of London in February 1947.

  22. The debate on the social dimension of consumption behaviour has a long tradition in the economic science. For an insight into such a topic, see Mason (1998) and Palley (2010).

  23. Current economic literature refers to this phenomenon as the “ratchet effect”. That was also discussed by Modigliani in his 1949 article.

  24. For an analysis of Duesenberry’s theory of consumption and its legacy, see Mason (2000) and Drakopoulos (2012). For recent applications of the “relative income” model, see, among others, de la Croix and Michel (1999) and Renström and Spataro (2019).

  25. Tobin (1967, p. 143) refers to this situation as the “golden age”.

  26. Casarosa does not discuss the second part of Duesenberry’s conclusion, according to which “if on the other hand the retired population buys annuities or fixed interest securities they will not share in the capital gains associated with the increase in income. The rate of saving will then be dependent on the rate of increase of income(Duesenberry 1949, p. 43). Casarosa is right in considering, Dusenberry’s argument as flawed. In fact, the American economist seems to envisage two distinct cases: one in which wealth of each cohort does not grow, and the other one in which wealth (stocks) for individuals of each cohort increases at the economy’s rate of growth due to some externality or, say, capital gains. However, the latter case is not possible, given that, if this were the case, aggregate wealth would grow both because of new flows of savings (that each year increase at the per-capita income pace) and because of Duesenberry’s envisaged “capital gains”. However, this rate of growth of wealth would be higher than the one ensuring the steady state.

  27. Duesenberry (1949, p. 45) also adds that the propensity to save of an individual is a raising function of his/her percentile position in the income distribution.

  28. Modigliani cited Harrod’s book in Ando and Modigliani (1959), although with regard to the issue of stability and growth (p. 501), not on “hump saving”. The citation contains anyway a mistake in the year of publication of the book: 1952 instead of 1948.

  29. In our opinion this is merely a typo, because Harrod refers correctly, when proposing a way of measuring the parameter e, to the elasticity of marginal utility of income (Harrod 1948, p. 44).

  30. For the influence of Ramsey on Harrod, Keynes and other economists in Cambridge, see Duarte (2009a) and Misak (2020).

  31. Once again, it is worth recalling that Harrod, in any case. does not discuss the role of wealth in affecting saving behavior, apart from the very narrow channel of its effect on the individuals’ time preference, T).

  32. M. R. Fisher (1956) writes that “as an early state of the investigation, the writer benefitted from discussions with Professor Milton Friedman of Chicago and the late Dr. R. E. Brumberg of Cambridge and has been materially able to view an advance mimeographed copy of the former’s forthcoming publication on the Consumption Function” (pp. 262–263). On the Palgrave Dictionary Fisher specifies again that: “early attempts to establish such a linkage were made by Irving Fisher (1930) and again by Harrod (1948) with his notion of hump saving, but a sharply defined hypothesis which carried the argument forward both theoretically and empirically with its range of well-specified tests for cross-section and time series evidence was first advanced in 1954 by M-B. Both their papers and advance copies of the permanent income theory of Milton Friedman (1957) were circulating in 1953 and led to M. R. Fisher carrying out tests of the theories even preceding publication of Friedman’s work (1956)” (M. R. Fisher, 1987, p. 177).

  33. Among other citations of Harrod’s contribution to the LCH, see Walker (1962, p. 1). Tobin (1967) simply states that the source of his graphs is “the life cycle theory proposed by Fisher and later by Modigliani and Brumberg” (p. 132). In turn, Buiter (2003) states that, thanks to his early contributions, “after Friedman (1957) and Modigliani (M-B, 1954; Ando and Modigliani, 1963), Tobin comes a close third as regards the significance of his contributions to the life- cycle/permanent income approach” (p. F590).

  34. On the same lines, see Bread (2011, p. 140).

  35. Modigilani and Brumberg give an account of the empirical results contained in Hamburger’s PhD dissertation by devoting to it Sect. 4.3, entitled The Hamburger Test, and introducing it as follows: “in a pioneering contribution, William Hamburger fitted a regression using estimates of consumption, income, and assets that are conceptually almost identical with our own, and produced (sometimes before the genesis of this paper) a consumption function that compares favourably with D-M [Duesenberry-Modigliani, N. o. A.] function for the period 1929–1950 over which it was tested” (M-B 1980, p. 178). Then they go on commenting on the limits of the methodology adopted by Hamburger, although concluding that “his empirical findings appear to agree remarkably well with our a priori estimates” (ibidem, p. 181).

  36. The programme of the Conference, which took place on the 30th of December 1953 in New York, is available on line on the webpage of the American Economic Association: https://www.aeaweb.org/conference/1953. In the same session, chaired by Raymond Goldsmith, Modigliani presented the first paper written with Brumberg and later published in 1954, and Margaret Reid presented a paper entitled Random Variations in Income and Their Effect on Income Expenditure Curves. The discussant was Hendrik Samuel Houthakker from the Cowles Commission.

  37. Although, as argued by Ando and Modigliani (1963), “if we interpret the highest previous peak income as that of a proxy for net worth, then the Duesenberry-Modigliani consumption function can be considered as providing a good empirical approximation to the consumption function discussed in this paper. […] At the same time the present model has the advantage that the hypotheses on which it rests are explicitly stated as specifications of the consumer’s utility function. It is also analytically more convenient as a building block in models of economic growth and fluctuations, as we have endeavored to demonstrate in various contributions” (p. 80).

  38. Modigliani was asked by Robert Strotz, the managing editor of Econometrica, to which he had submitted the second manuscript written with Brumberg on the macroeconomic implications of the LCH, to mention the names of those who had already read his work and he provided the name of Duesenberry together with the ones of Christ, Klein and Brown.

References

  • Alexander SS (1950) Mr. Harrod’s dynamic model. Econ J 60(240):724–739

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ando AK, Modigliani F (1959) Growth, fluctuations, and stability. Am Econ Rev 501–524.

  • Ando AK, Modigliani F (1960) The ‘permanent income’ and the ‘life cycle’ hypothesis of saving behavior: comparisons and tests. Consump Sav 2:74–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Ando A, Modigliani F (1963) The" life cycle" hypothesis of saving: Aggregate implications and tests. Am Econ Rev 53(1):55–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson FJ (1949) Mr. Harrod’s Dynamic Theorems. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 63:12–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O (2015) Frank Ramsey’s: A mathematical theory of saving. Econ J 125(583):269–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baranzini M (2005) Modigliani’s life-cycle theory of savings fifty years later. BNL Quarterly Review Vol LVIII 233–234:109–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Brumberg RE (1956) An approximation to the aggregate saving function. Econ J 66(261):66–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brumberg RE (1953) Utility analysis and aggregate consumption functions: an empirical test and its meaning. Doctoral dissertation, Johns Hopkins University.

  • Buiter WH (2003) James Tobin: an appreciation of his contribution to economics. Econ J 113(491):F585–F631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casarosa C (2002) La relazione fra tasso di risparmio e tasso di crescita nella teoria del ciclo di vita: da Harrod a Modigliani-Brumberg. Il Pensiero Economico Italiano 10(1):51–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Casarosa C, Spataro L (2010) Rate of Growth of Population and Aggregate Saving in the Basic Life-Cycle Model. Economia Politica 27(1):83–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassel G (1932) Theory of Social Economy. Harcourt, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Comim F (2000) On the concept of applied economics: lessons from cambridge economics and the history of growth theories. Hist Polit Econ 32(Supp1):145–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D, Michel P (1999) Optimal growth when tastes are inherited. J Econ Dyn Control 23(4):519–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (2005) Franco Modigliani and the life-cycle theory of consumption. BNL Q Rev 58(233–234):91–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am Econ Rev 55(5):1126–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Drakopoulos SA (2012) The History of attitudes towards interdependent preferences. J Hist Econ Thought 34(4):541–557

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drèze JH, Modigliani F (1975) Consumption decisions under uncertainty. In: Stochastic optimization models in finance (pp. 459–486). Academic Press.

  • Duarte PG (2009) The growing of Ramsey’s growth model. Hist Polit Econ 41(Supp1):161–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duarte PG (2009a) Frank P Ramsey: A Cambridge Economist. Hist Polit Econ 41(3):445–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry JS (1949) Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell MJ (1959) The new Theory of the Consumption Function. Econ J 69(276):678–696

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1907) The Rate of Interest: Its nature, determination and relation to economic phenomena. The MacMillan Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1930) Theory of interest: as determined by impatience to spend income and opportunity to invest it. Augustusm Kelly Publishers, Clifton

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher MR (1956) Exploration in savings behaviour. Bull Oxf Univ Inst Econ Stat 18(3):201–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher MR (1987) Life-Cycle Hypothesis. In: Eatwell J, Millgate M, Newman P (eds) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Macmillan, London and Basingstoke, pp 177–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1957) A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Graaff JDV (1950) Mr. Harrod on hump saving. Economica 17(65):81–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grunberg E, Modigliani F (1954) The predictability of social events. J Polit Econ 62(6):465–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE (1978) Stochastic implications of the life cycle-permanent income hypothesis: theory and evidence. J Polit Econ 86(6):971–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamburger W (1954) The determinants of aggregate consumption. Rev Econ Stud 22(1):23–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamburger W (1955) The relation of consumption to wealth and the wage rate. Econometrica, J Econ Soc 23(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamburger W (1951) Consumption and Wealth. Unpublished PhD dissertation, University of Chicago.

  • Hands DW (1990) Grunberg and Modigliani, Public Predictions and the New Classical Macroeconomics. In: Samuels WJ (ed) Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology. JAI Press, VII, Greenwich, Connecticut, pp 207–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen AH (1946) Some Notes on Terborgh’s" The Bogey of Economic Maturity". Rev Econ Stat 28(1):13–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen AH (1949) Towards a dynamic economics. Am Econ Rev 39(2):497–499

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrod RF (1939) An essay in dynamic theory. Econ J 49(193):14–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrod RF (1948) Towards a Dynamic Economics. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartley JE (2004) Modigliani’s Expectations. East Econ J 30(3):427–440

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1949) Mr. Harrod’s dynamic theory. Economica 16(62):106–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins B (1948) Towards a dynamic economics. Econ Record 24(2):173–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of interest, employment and money. Harcourt, Brace and Co, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kouri P (1986) Franco Modigliani’s contributions to economics. Scandinavian J Econ 88(2):311–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD, Salvadori N (2003) Theories of economic growth: old and new. The Theory of Economic Growth: A ‘Classical’Perspective, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 1–22.

  • Kuznets S (1942) Use of National Income in Peace and War, National Bureau of Economic Research - Occasional Paper.

  • Kuznets S (1946) National Product Since 1869 (assisted by L. Epstein and E. Zenks). New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Leff NH (1969) Dependency rates and savings rates. Am Econ Rev 59(5):886–896

    Google Scholar 

  • Martini A, Spataro L (2021) A re-assessment of the relation between saving and economic growth from the marginalist thinkers to the debate of the 1950s. Hist Econ Ideas XIX(2):143–173

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason R (1998) The economics of conspicuous consumption. Theory and thought since 1700. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason R (2000) The social significance of consumption: James Duesenberry’s contribution to consumer theory. J Econ Issues 34(3):553–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer T (1972) Permanent income, wealth, and consumption: a critique of the permanent income theory, the life-cycle hypothesis, and related theories. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1987) In Honor of Nobel Laureate, Franco Modigliani. J Econ Perspect 1(2):145–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Misak C (2020) Frank Ramsey: A Sheer Excess of Powers. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1949) Fluctuations in the saving-income ratio: a problem in economic forecasting. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol 11. NBER, New York, pp 369–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1961) Long-run implications of alternative fiscal policies and the burden of the national debt. Econ J 71(284):730–755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1970) The life cycle hypothesis of saving and intercountry differences in the saving ration. In: Eltis WA, Scott MF, Wolfe JN (eds) Induction, growth and trade: Essays in Honour of Sir Roy Harrod. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1975) The life-cycle hypothesis of saving twenty years later. In: Parkin M, Nobay AR (eds) Contemporary Issues in Economics. Manchester University Press, Manchester, pp 2–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1986) Life cycle, individual thrift, and the wealth of nations (Nobel Lecture. Am Econ Rev 76(3):297–313

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1988) The role of intergenerational transfers and life cycle saving in the accumulation of wealth. J Econ Perspect 2(2):15–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (2001) Adventures of an Economist. Texere, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Ando AK (1957) Tests of the life cycle hypothesis of savings. Comments and suggestions. Oxford Ins Econ Stat Bull 19(2):99–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Brumberg R (1954) Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: an Interpretation of Cross-Section Data. In: Kurihara KK (ed) Post-Keynesian Economics. Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, pp 419–421

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Brumberg R (1980) Utility analysis and aggregate consumption functions: an attempt at integration. In: Abel A (ed) The collected papers of France Modigliani. 2, the life cycle hypothesis of saving. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, pp 128–197

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Sterling A (1983) Determinants of private saving with special reference to the role of social security-cross-country tests. In: Modigliani F, Hamming R (eds) The determinants of national saving and wealth. The Macmillan Press Ltd., London, pp 24–55

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Tarantelli E (1975) The consumption function in a developing economy and the Italian experience. Am Econ Rev 65(5):825–842

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1966) The life cycle hypothesis of saving, the demand for wealth and the supply of capital. Soc Res 160–217

  • Muth JF (1961) Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements. Econometrica 29:315–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neisser H (1944) The economics of a stationary population. Soc Res 470–490.

  • Palley TI (2010) The relative permanent income theory of consumption: a synthetic Keynes–Duesenberry–Friedman model. Rev Polit Econ 22(1):41–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pavanelli G (2006) The early reception and diffusion of Irving Fisher’s work in Italy. J Hist Econ Thought 28(3):267–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1968) Population increase. Can J Econ/revue Canadienne D’economique 1(3):497–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puttaswamaiah K (ed) (2009) Franco Modigliani: Peerless twentieth-century macroeconomist: Nobel laureate in economics. Isle Publishing Company, Washington D.C

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey FP (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. Econ J 38(152):543–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rancan A (2020) Franco Modigliani and Keynesian Economics. Routledge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Read C (2011) The life cyclists. Fischer, Keynes, Modigliani, and Freidman. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Renström TI, Spataro L (2019) Population growth: A pure welfarist approach. J Public Econ Theory 21(1):135–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricci U (1927) Ancora sull’offerta del risparmio. Giornale Degli Economisti 67(September):481–504

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricci U (1926) L’offerta del risparmio. Giornale degli Economisti 66: 73–101

  • Robinson J (1949) Mr. Harrod’s dynamics. Econ J 59(233):68–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szenberg M, Ramrattan L (2008) Franco Modigliani: A Mind That Never Rests. Palgrave Macmillan, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1967) Life cycle saving and balanced growth. In: Fellner W (ed) Ten Economic Studies in the Tradition of Irving Fisher. Wiley, New York, pp 231–256

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1947) A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of Consumer Saving. PhD dissertation, Harvard University.

  • Vickrey W (1947) Resource distribution patterns and the classification of families. In: Studies in Income and Wealth (pp. 266–297). NBER.

  • Walker ER (1949) Towards a dynamic economics: some recent developments of economic theory and their application to policy. Int Aff 25(1):78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker FV (1962) Income growth and hump saving. Econ Inq 1(1):1

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to an anonymous referee for valuable suggestions and to the Editor for his kind support. The usual disclaimer applies. Although the conception and drafting of the text is the outcome of joint research, Sections 2, 3.1.2, 3.2.1 are attributable to Luca Spataro, and Sections 3.1.1, 3.2.2, 4 are attributable to Alice Martini, the remaining Sections have been coauthored.

Funding

No funds, grants, or other support were received.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Spataro.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors have no conflicts of interest to declare that are relevant to the content of this article.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Martini, A., Spataro, L. The contribution of Carlo Casarosa on the forerunners of the life cycle hypothesis by Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg. Int Rev Econ 69, 71–101 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-021-00386-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-021-00386-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation