Skip to main content
Log in

Dutch-auction IPOs: institutional development and underpricing performance

  • Published:
Journal of Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Dutch-auction method of bringing IPOs to market has been used sparingly since its initiation in 1999 despite the potential for this method to lead to more fully-priced issues. The development of Dutch-auctioned IPOs is documented here, and institutional details are reviewed. An empirical investigation of the characteristics of these IPOs is presented. The evidence indicates smaller magnitudes of underpricing of Dutch-auctioned IPOs relative to traditional IPOs. A multi-variate analysis indicates, however, that this smaller degree of underpricing is due to factors other than the Dutch-auction process. The evidence strongly reinforces the institutional rationing hypothesis for underpricing. It also contributes to the international evidence of the failure of auctioned IPOs to avoid underpricing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There was one additional IPO in 2007, NetSuite. This issue is included in the 21 IPOs examined below.

  2. A weighted average first-day rate of return for the Dutch-auctioned issues is 15.6% where the weights are determined by the gross value of the issues. Ritter (March, 2006) calculates a similar statistic for all IPOs as 22.4%.

  3. The standard deviation for the sample of traditional IPOs is 49.04. The standard deviation for the 21 Dutch-auctioned issues is 56.8.

  4. See Hambrecht’s Web page at www.wrhambrecht.com.

  5. Hypothetical versions of Table 3 are listed in all of the prospecti of Hambrecht’s associated OpenIPO issues.

  6. Google’s registration statement states that the purpose of an offer price set lower than the clearing price is to achieve broader distribution of the stock or to attempt to prevent downward price volatility in the aftermarket.

  7. See WR Hambrecht’s web page at www.wrhambrecht.com.

  8. The allowable aftermarket selling period for owners is frequently restricted to 180 days after the issue date.

References

  • Aggarwal R (2000) Stabilization activities of underwriters after initial public offerings. J Finance 55:1075–1103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron D (1982) A model of the demand for investment banking advising and distribution services for new issues. J Finance 37(4):955–976

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron D, Holmstrom B (1980) The investment banking contract for new issues under asymmetric information. J Finance 35(5):1115–1138

    Google Scholar 

  • Bear RM, Curley AJ (1975) Unseasoned equity financing. J Financ Quant Anal 10:311–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty RP, Ritter JR (1986) Investment banking, reputation, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. J Financ Econ 15:213–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty RP, Welch I (1996) Issuers expenses and legal liability in initial public offerings. J Law Econ 39:545–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benvenite L, Spindt R (1989) How investment bankers determine offer prices, and allocation of new issues. J Financ Econ 24:343–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block S, Stanley M (1980) The financial characteristics and price movement patterns of companies approaching the unseasoned securities market in the late 1970’s. Financ Manage 9:30–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth J, Chua L (1996) Ownership dispersion, costly information, and IPO underpricing. J Financ Econ 15:261–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley D, Jordan B (2002) Partial adjustment to public information and IPO underpricing. J Financ Quant Anal 37:595–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley DJ, Jordan BD, Roten IC, Yi Ha-Chin (2000) Venture Capital and IPO Lockup Expiration: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of Financial Research XXIV, No, 4

    Google Scholar 

  • Busaba W, Benveniste L, Guo R (2001) The option to withdraw IPOs during the premarket: empirical analysis. J Financ Econ 60:73–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter RB, Manaster S (1990) Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. J Finance 45:1045–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter RB, Dark FH, Singh AK (1998) Underwriter reputation, initial returns, and the long-run performance of IPO stocks. J Finance 53:285–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen H-C, Ritter JR (2000) The seven percent solution. J Finance 55(3):1105–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig S, Sidel R (2004) Wall street vindicated by Google. Wall Street J, p. C1. 8/19/2004

  • Delaney KJ, Sidel R (2004) How miscalculations and hubris hobbled celebrated Google IPO. Wall Street J, A1. 8/19/2004

  • Derrien F, Womack K (2003) Auctions vs bookbuilding and the control of underpricing in hot IPO markets. Rev Financ Stud 16(1):31–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downes DH, Heinkel R (1982) Signalling and the valuation of unseasoned new issues. J Finance 37(1):1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt M, Hwang CY (1989) Signalling and the pricing of new issues. J Finance 44(2):393–420

    Google Scholar 

  • Gupta U (2001) An IPO for everyone. INC Magazine 23(12):140–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanley K (1993) The underpricing of initial public offerings and the partial adjustment phenomenon. J Financ Econ 34:231–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hebb GM, MacKinnon GH (2004) Valuation uncertainty and IPOs: investment bank vs. commercial bank underwriters. J Econ Finance 28:1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibbotson R, Sindelar JL, Ritter JR (1988) Initial public offerings. Bank Am J Appl Corp Finance 1:37–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagganathan R, Jirnyi A (2010) Why don’t issuers choose IPO auctions? The complexity of indirect mechanisms. NBER Working Paper

  • Jagganathan R, Jirnyi A, Sherman A (2009) Why have IPO auctions failed the market test? NBER Working Paper, January

  • Jenkins HW (2004) Back to the drawing board on IPO reform. Wall Street J, A11. 8/25/2004

  • Johnson J, Miller R (1988) Investment banker prestige and the underpricing of initial public offerings. Financ Manage 17:19–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kessler S (2004) The A-B-Cs of Google’s auction. Business Week Online 8/10/2004.

  • Leland H, Pyle D (1977) Informational assymetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation. J Finance XXXII(2):371–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Logue DE (1973) On the pricing of unseasoned equity issues: 1965–1969. J Financ Quant Anal 8:91–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran T, Ritter J (2002) Why don’t issuers get upset about leaving money on the table in IPOs? Rev Financ Stud 15:413–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowry M, William Schwert G (2002) IPO market cycles: bubbles or sequential learning? J Finance 57:1171–1200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucchetti A, Sidel R, Simon R (2004). With eyes for Google, 3 investors ride a 111-day roller coaster. Wall Street J, A1. 8/20/2004

  • Marshall BB, Crutchley CE, Lending D (2004) Early internet IPOs versus subsequent entrants. J Econ Finance 28:1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald JG, Fisher AK (1972) New-issue stock price behavior. J Finance 27:97–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuberger B, Hammond C (1974) A study of underwriters experience with unseasoned new issues. J Financ Quant Anal 9(2):165–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neuberger B, LaChapelle CA (1983) Unseasoned new issue price performance on three tiers: 1975–1980. Financ Manage 12:23–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oster C (2004) How to get your five shares of Google. Wall Street J, D1. 7/27/2004

  • Reilly FK (1973) Further evidence of short-run results for new issues investors. J Financ Quant Anal 8(1):83–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reilly FK, Hatfield K (1969) Experience with new stock issues. Financ Anal J 25(5):73–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reside MA, Robinson RM, Prakash AJ, Dandapani K (1994) A tax-based motive for the underpricing of initial public offerings. Manag Decis Econ 15:553–561

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter JR (1984) The “hot issue” market of 1980. J Bus 57:215–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter JR (2006) The IPO market. Unpublished working paper. (Found on Ritter’s Web Page, www.UFL.edu)

  • Ritter J, Welch I (2002) A review of IPO activity, pricing, and allocations. J Finance 57(4):1795–1828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson MA, Robinson RM (2002) Capital gains taxes and IPO pricing. Financ Decis 14(2) (Fall)

  • Robinson RM, Robinson MA, Peng C-C (2004) Underpricing and IPO ownership retention. J Econ Finance 28:1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rock K (1986) Why new issues are underpriced. J Financ Econ 15:187–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith CW (1986) Investment banking and the capital acquisition process. J Financ Econ 15:3–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solomon D (2004) Regulators continue to study Google filings. Wall Street J, C4 8/19/2004

  • Stoll HR, Curley A (1970) Small business and the new issues market for equities. J Financ Quant Anal V:309–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinic SM (1988) Anatomy of initial public offerings of common stock. J Finance 43:789–822

    Google Scholar 

  • Varshney S, Robinson R (2004) IPO research symposium review. J Econ Finance 28(1):56–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman G (2004) Google shares prove big winners—for a day. Wall Street J, C1 8/20/2004

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard Robinson.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Institutional details of the Dutch auction process:

Table 6 lists the distributional details of the various processes used for the 21 Dutch-auctioned issues. Note that all utilize Hambrecht’s OpenIPO process even when other firms are the lead underwriters, as in Google and NetSuite. It also lists the individual issues for which the various processes apply. A summary of the most important provisions is presented below.

Table 6 This table summarizes the major characteristics of an OpenIPO issue, as described in the registration statement and/or the prospectus. The underlined headings are arbitrary, as registration statements and prospecti differ from one another in their composition and tend to be repetitive and chronologically disorganized

1.1.1 Underwriter compensation

As indicated in Table 2, underwriter compensation varies from 1.88 to 7% of the issue price. Provisions U1 and U2, listed in Table 6, indicate that the underwriter, or underwriter syndicate, purchases all of the IPO shares once the issue price is determined. These shares are purchased, most commonly, at a 2–7% discount, and then sold to the successful bidders at the issue price. A 7% discount is standard for traditional IPOs. [See Chen and Ritter (2000).]

1.1.2 Qualification process

Provisions Q1 through Q3 indicate that bidders must meet account requirements established by the underwriters and participating dealers. Account requirements may include a minimum account balance in a participating brokerage firm, and/or minimum number of transactions completed through a participating brokerage firm. As noted in Table 6, these requirements are typical for an OpenIPO issue. To date, however, only Google and NetSuite required bidders to obtain an ID number prior to placing a bid, and to consent to electronic communication from the underwriter.

1.1.3 Bidding process

Provisions B1 through B5b describe the bidding process for the OpenIPO. Bids include number of shares desired at a proposed price. Each firm’s registration statement (which, in the SEC’s Effectiveness Process, becomes the firm’s prospectus) provides an offering price range for the issue. Bids can be above, below, or within the range indicated. Nearly all of the firms using the OpenIPO process (20 of the 21 issues) specified a minimum bid of 100 shares. Google indicated that it would accept a minimum bid of 5 shares. [See Oster (2004).] In general, bidders have the right to withdraw a bid any time prior to the close of the auction. Underwriters may reject any bid based on eligibility or creditworthiness criteria, or any bid that the underwriter considers “manipulative or disruptive” to the auction process.

1.1.4 Confirmation process

Provisions C1 through C11 concern the “confirmation” process. This process requires that bids be “confirmed” just prior to the closing of the auction. “Confirmation” consists of electronic notification that the bidder stands behind their previous bid offers, or that they are revising their bids in some way by changing the price and/or the quantity demanded. Since any initial bid can be changed up to the time of closing, confirmation of final offers must be forthcoming in order to participate in the issue. In general, bids must be reconfirmed if either the number of shares offered changes or if the public offering price range is revised sufficiently so that the total value of the issue changes by 20% or more.

1.1.5 Closing (end-of-auction) process

Provisions E1 through E3 pertain to the closing of the auction. Over time, the description of this process has evolved. For the first two OpenIPO issues, the closing process was not referred to at all. For the next seven issues, the approximate closing date was published on Hambrecht’s website. For the last twelve issues, the prospecti state that reconfirmation of all bids are required if the auction is unable to close within 15 days after the registration statement becomes effective. Also, the prsopecti generally state that closing occurs within 1 to 4 h after the time the registration statement is declared “effective” by the SEC.

1.1.6 Pricing process

Provision P6 allows the firm to select an issue price that is below the market-clearing price. This assures excess demand, and therefore allows rationing of the shares as explained above. Most OpenIPO issues allow the public offering price to be set outside the initial or revised range set forth by the prospectus, as stated in P2. This has actually occurred for two issues to date. [See New River Pharmaceuticals Inc. and FortuNet, Inc. in Table 2.]

1.1.7 Distribution process

Provisions D1 through D9 refer to the actual distribution process. As shown in Table 6, some issuers refuse to recognize bids demanding more than 5% of the total shares offered. This assures wider distribution of shares, a more liquid aftermarket, and most importantly, that no institution or individual will obtain a controlling interest in the issuing company. Provision D2 assures that the issuer may use its discretion to reduce a large order. This certainly assures that the issuer can eliminate a large controlling interest.

Rationing the issue so as to prevent a controlling outside interest is not only a protection measure for the management entrepreneurs who retain the controlling interest, but it is also an assurance to the issue’s purchasers that management will not be readily changed, that they can rely on the continuity of the IPO management team.

1.1.8 Post-issue process

The post-issue process, described in PI1 through PI8, describes the overallotment, the lock-up period, and the aftermarket stabilization activity that may take place. Although 180-day lock-up periods are most common, shorter periods may be specified in each issue for certain classifications of the firm’s ownership, which would result in a shorter average lock-up period for the issue. The registration statements for five of the last OpenIPO issues address requests for early release from the lock-up period, as shown in PI6 and PI6a. This inclusion represents another step in the evolutionary process for IPOs brought to market using the OpenIPO process. PI7, which is included in most OpenIPO issues, indicates that the underwriter intends to act as market maker after the issue has been made public.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Robinson, M.A., Robinson, R. Dutch-auction IPOs: institutional development and underpricing performance. J Econ Finan 36, 521–554 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-010-9166-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-010-9166-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation