Skip to main content
Log in

Dangers of commitment under rational expectations

  • Published:
Journal of Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Within a New Keynesian framework, interest rate rules that respond to public expectations lead to determinate and expectationally stable solutions for any level of commitment, as shown by Waters (Macroecon Dyn 13(4):421–449, 2009). That paper also demonstrates gains to commitment, under least square learning, though over-commitment can lead to some very poor outcomes for some parameter values. This paper shows an identical outcome under rational expectations. The optimal level of commitment is unchanged if there are observation errors in the policymaker’s knowledge of public expectations, which is not the case under learning. However, if there is sufficient policymaker uncertainty about the parameter values, partial commitment is best.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The model here is quite standard. Clarida et al. (1999) provide and excellent overview, and Woodford (2003) presents a detailed, micro-founded approach.

  2. See Evans and Honkapohja (2001) for definitions and mathematical exposition of these concepts.

  3. In earlier studies of commitment, such as Barro and Gordon (1983), the inflation bias arises due to the policymaker’s desire to push output above the natural rate, but that is not the case here. See Clarida et al. (1999) for a detailed discussion.

  4. The present approach follows Evans and Honkapohja (2006), Woodford (1999) and Clarida et al. (1999).

  5. He also checks the result with a formal derivation. Jensen and McCallum (2002) also discuss this issue. Evans and McGough (2008) refer to this approach as the MJB-alternative in their study of the New Keynsian model with inertia.

  6. If the policymaker has a biased estimate of λ, the change in policy would be equivalent to the change caused by varying the policymaker preference parameter α.

  7. For all reported results, the loss for each run is calculated over 200 periods after 600 periods for initialization. Since losses are computed with discounting, longer runs do not provide much extra information.

References

  • Barro RJ, Gordon DB (1983) A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. J Polit Econ 91:589–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blake AP (2001) A ‘timeless perspective’ on optimality in forward-looking rational expectations models. Working paper, National Institute for Economic and Social Research

  • Clarida R, Gali J, Gertler M (1999) The science of monetary policy: a New Keynesian perspective. J Econ Lit 37:1661–1707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Gali J, Gertler M (2000) Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory. Q J Econ 115:147–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, Honkapohja S (2001) Learning and expectations in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, Honkapohja S (2003) Expectations and the stability problem for optimal monetary policies. Rev Econ Stud 70:807–824

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, Honkapohja S (2006) Monetary policy, expectations and commitment. Scand J Econ 108:15–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, McGough B (2007) Optimal constrained interest rate rules. J Money Credit Bank 39:1335–1356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, McGough B (2008) Implementing optimal monetary policy in New-Keynesian models with inertia. Working paper

  • Jensen C, McCallum B (2002) The non-optimality of proposed monetary policy rules under timeless-perspective commitment. Econ Lett 77(2):163–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum BT, Nelson E (2004) Timeless perspective vs. discretionary monetary policy in forward looking models. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 86(2):43–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Q J Econ 100:1169–1190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waters GA (2005) Dangers of commitment: monetary policy with adaptive expectations. J Econ Finan 30(1):93–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waters GA (2009) Learning, commitment and monetary policy. Macroecon Dyn 13(4):421–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (1999) Commentary: how should monetary policy be conducted in an era of price stability? In: New challenges for monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp 277–316

  • Woodford M (2003) Interest and prices. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George A. Waters.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Waters, G.A. Dangers of commitment under rational expectations. J Econ Finan 35, 371–381 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-010-9127-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-010-9127-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation