Skip to main content
Log in

Emil Lederer and Joseph Schumpeter on Economic Growth, Technology and Business Cycles

  • Published:
Forum for Social Economics

Abstract

This paper compares Joseph Schumpeter and Emil Lederer with respect to their visions concerning the notions of economic growth, technology and business cycles. Their theoretical investigations in a number of thematic areas seem to converge to similar views. More precisely, both Schumpeter and Lederer regard the capitalist economy as a dynamic system where the introduction of innovations is its distinctive characteristic. In such a system, static analysis based on the concept of equilibrium is useful as an expository device to describe the adjustment mechanisms of the economic system. They also paid attention to the emergence of large oligopolistic firms and considered this development as being interwoven with technological progress. Both economists used similar arguments to emphasize the link between economic development and technological change. In their analyses, Schumpeter and Lederer referred to psychological factors motivating the entrepreneur, in order to explain the forces that set in motion the process of innovation and thus economic development. The concept of technological unemployment is also described in a similar manner by both of them. Regarding the issue of business cycles, Schumpeter and Lederer considered them to be a result of endogenous processes within a capitalist economy. Lederer in his late works, argued in a way analogous to Schumpeter, that economic fluctuations are caused from the disruptions created by innovations, which are introduced discontinuously into the economic system. Conclusively, Schumpeter and Lederer delivered theses which are similar in scope and conclusions probably because they were developed in the same social, political, theoretical and ideological environment and were also well acquainted with each other’s ideas.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. McCraw (2007, 345), by making full use of Schumpeter's diaries, argued that Schumpeter’s prodigious output was due to his “isolation and self-doubt”, which was later enhanced by the death of his beloved ones that made him use academic work “as a means of harnessing his personal grief” (ibid, 160). This attitude of his certainly was not evident in his public manner.

  2. At this point it is interesting to note that despite the fact that he was world famous by that time, he was also penniless. As McCraw (2007, 4) emphatically stressed, Schumpeter had to make paid speeches in order to be able to buy his transatlantic ticket.

  3. This journal published path-breaking articles such as Weber’s “The Protestant ethic and the ‘spirit’ of capitalism” (1905) and Kondratieff’s “The Long Waves in Economic Life” (1926). See Hagemann (2005).

  4. For Lederer’s attempt to sociologically understand the main features of war, especially World War I, see Lederer (2006).

  5. In his History of Economic Analysis he wrote: “[S]o far as pure theory is concerned Walras is in my opinion the greatest of all economists” and suggested that Walras’s work “will stand comparison with the achievements of theoretical physics” (Schumpeter 1954, 827).

  6. According to Shionoya (1997, 38), for Schumpeter the essential feature is the type of man which is defined as a “leader”, who overthrows the existing order by creating a new direction.

  7. For a discussion of the central importance of trust in a market economy, the unstable nature of market economies and the so-called “corporatist” approach see Perelman (1998, 1994, 2006).

  8. Lederer noted that “the low wages are due to the oversupply of workers, and as a result of mechanization and improving efficiency they are not likely to find employment easily” (Lederer and Lederer-Seidler 1938, p. 255)

  9. Here Mongiovi (2005) rightfully stressed that one of Lederer’s main criticisms on Keynes’ General Theory was exactly Keynes’s neglect of the phenomenon of technological unemployment.

  10. Here Schumpeter refers to: (1) the construction of new plants and the rebuilding of old plants, (2) new firms which are founded for the purpose of capitalising on specific innovations, and (3) the rise to leadership of new men (Schumpeter 1939, 68–71).

  11. According to Schumpeter, economic systems do not achieve equilibrium but move into “neighborhoods of equilibrium […] in which the system approaches a state which would, if reached, fulfill equilibrium conditions” (Schumpeter 1939, 45).

  12. For a discussion on entrepreneur’s motives and personality in Schumpeter’s works see de Vecchi (1995, 16–19).

  13. As is well known, in the subsequent editions of his Theory of Economic Development, Schumpeter omitted the seventh chapter and rewrote the second chapter. It is argued (e.g. Shionoya 1997, 167–71) that these changes signify important shifts regarding the role of the entrepreneur.

  14. Disproportional developments in the producer and consumer goods sectors in the course of the business cycle constitute a common point between Lederer’s 1925 analysis and Schumpeter’s work on business cycles (Allgoewer 2003, 333). While Schumpeter acknowledged the importance of disproportionality (“[T]his idea […] is moreover easy to substantiate from certain very obvious facts” [Schumpeter 1954, 1133]) he avoided attributing a causative role to them. He stressed the importance of looking for “the definite factors that are to account for it” and concluded that “those factors and not disproportionality per se will individuate an author’s theory” (ibid, 1133).

  15. For an insightful discussion of whether Lederer should be classified as an underconsumptionist see Allgoewer (2003, 342–3)

  16. According to Diebolt (2006, 4) the deeper roots of Lederer's views could be traced back even to Malthus (1836) and Sismondi (1827).

References

  • Allgoewer, E. (2003). Emil Lederer: business cycles, crises, and growth. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 25.3, 327–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandler Jr., A. (1962). Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clemence, R. V. (1951). Essays of economic topics of J. A. Schumpeter. Port Washington: Kennikat.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vecchi, N. (1995). Entrepreneurs, institutions and economic change: The economic thought of J. A. Schumpeter (1905–1925). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt, C. (2006). Progrès technique et cycles économiques dans la pensée allemande de l’entre-deux-guerres: l’apport d’Emil Lederer. Association Française de Cliométrie Working Paper 9.

  • Haberler, G. (1950). Joseph Alois Schumpeter: 1883–1950. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64, 333–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann, H. (2004). The German historical approach to economics. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, 22-A, 399–411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann, H. (2005). Dismissal, expulsion and emigration of German-speaking economists after 1933. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 27.4, 405–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. (2007). Marshall, Schumpeter and the shifting boundaries of economics and sociology. Greece: University of Athens Draft of 31/01.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, A. (2000). Memorie. In M. Salvati (Ed.), Da Berlino a New York (pp. 231–240). Milan: Bruno Mondadori.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kessler, M. (1961). The synthetic vision of Joseph Schumpeter. Review of Politics, 23, 334–355 July.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirsch, H. (1979). Joseph Alois Schumpeter. Journal of Economic Issues, 13.1, 141–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazonick, W. (1990). Competitive advantage on the shop floor. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederer, E. (1925). Konjuktur und Krisen. In Grundriss der Sozialoekonomik (pp. 354–413). Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr.

  • Lederer, E. (1931). Technischer Fortschritt und Arbeitslosigkeit. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederer, E. (1933). Les progrès techniques et le chômage. Revue Internationale du Travail, XXVIII.1, 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederer, E. (1936). Developments in economic theory. The American Economic Review. Supplement, Papers and Proceedings of the Forty-eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, March, 26.1, 151–160.

  • Lederer, E. (1938). Technical progress and unemployment. Geneva: King and Son.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederer, E. (2006). On the sociology of world war. Archive of European Sociology, XLVII.2, 241–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lederer, E., & Lederer-Seidler, E. (1938). Japan in transition. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T. R. (1836). Principles of political economy considered with a view to their practical application. London: W. Pichering.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCraw, T. K. (2007). Prophet of innovation: Joseph Schumpeter and creative destruction. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaelides, P., & Milios, J. (2004). Hilferding’s influence on Schumpeter: A first discussion, European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy, Proceedings of 16th Annual International Conference (CD), Crete, Greece, October 28–31.

  • Michaelides, P., & Milios, J. (2005a). Did Hilferding influence Schumpeter? History of Economics Review, 41, 98–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaelides, P., & Milios, J. (2005b). The influence of the German historical school on Schumpeter, European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy, Proceedings of the 17th Annual International Conference (CD), Bremen, Germany, November 10–12.

  • Michaelides, P., & Milios, J. (2008). Joseph Schumpeter and the German Historical School, Cambridge Journal of Economics, doi:10.1093/cje/ben052 , published online November 18, 2008 (in Press).

  • Milios, J., Dimoulis, D., & Economakis, G. (2002). Karl Marx and the classics. An essay on value, crises and the capitalist mode of production. Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mongiovi, G. (2005). Émigré economists and American neoclassical economics 1933–1945. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 27.4, 427–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moszkowska, N. (1935). Zur Kritik moderner Krisentheorien. Prag: M. Kacha.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgenstern, O. (1951). Joseph A. Schumpeter, 1883–1950. Economic Journal, 61, 197–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perelman, M. (1994). Retrospectives: fixed capital, railroad economics and the critique of the market. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8.3, 189–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perelman, M. (1998). The neglected economics of trust. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57.4, 381–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perelman, M. (2006). Railroading economics: the creation of the free market mythology. Monthly Review.

  • Porter, M. (1985). Competitive advantage. New York: Free.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1982). Inside the black box, technology and economics. Cambridge University Press.

  • Scherer, F. (1984). Innovation and growth. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1912). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press 1934, 1951, 1961.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1928). The instability of capitalism. Economic Journal, 38.151, 361–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1935). The analysis of economic change. Review of Economic Statistics, 14.4, 2–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles. New York: McGraw-Hill 1964.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper and Row 1950.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1954). History of economic analysis. London: Routledge 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shionoya, Y. (1997). Schumpeter and the idea of social science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sismondi, L. S. De (1827). Nouveaux principes d’économie politique. Paris: Delaunay.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Panayotis G. Michaelides.

Additional information

Feedback from participants of the 9th Conference of Greek Historians of Economic Thought in May 2007, the participants of an International Research Workshop on Political Economy organized by the University of London (International Initiative for Promoting Political Economy) and the University of Crete in September 2007 and the participants of the 19th Annual International Conference of the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy (EAEPE) in November 2007 is gratefully acknowledged. Also, the authors are indebted to Claude Diebolt and Elisabeth Allgoewer for kindly providing useful material. Finally, we would like to thank the two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Michaelides, P.G., Milios, J., Vouldis, A. et al. Emil Lederer and Joseph Schumpeter on Economic Growth, Technology and Business Cycles. For Soc Econ 39, 171–189 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12143-009-9032-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12143-009-9032-2

Keywords

Navigation