Skip to main content
Log in

Examining the Micro-level Foundations of Japan’s Two-party System Following Government Alternation

  • Published:
East Asia Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A consensus exists among political scientists and the media that a two party system has become firmly established in Japan, and power alternation following the 2009 House of Representatives election seemed to confirm this trend. In contrast, in this study I draw on both election and public opinion data to illustrate that Japan's two-party system rests on fragile micro foundations, particularly since the change of government, and may therefore not constitute a stable equilibrium. Specifically, the two-party system is sustained by the logic of competition in single member districts, but lacks strong backing among a large proportion of the public. Evidence in support of this argument include 1) decreasing vote shares for both the Liberal Democratic Party and the Democratic Party of Japan in the 2010 House of Councillors election, and 2) a weakening relationship between support for these two parties in monthly polls, in contrast to previous years when LDP and DPJ ratings mirrored one another. I discuss some potential implications of these developments, such as the growing prominence of regional parties and prospects for electoral rule changes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This coalition comprised of the Japan Socialist Party (JSP), Japan Renewal Party (JRP), Komeito, Japan New Party (JNP), Democratic Socialist Party (DSP), New Party Sakigake, and Socialist Democratic Federation (SDF). (Listed in descending order of seats) These parties won a combined total of 243 seats (out of 511) to the LDP’s 223.

  2. 300 House of Representatives seats are allocated in SMDs, and 200 (later reduced to 180) seats are proportionally distributed in nine regional blocs.

  3. This does not imply that citizens are politically unsophisticated. For example, Kabashima and Reed [15] cite evidence from survey analysis that the electorate as a whole was able to make sense of rapidly shifting coalition arrangements.

  4. The DPJ more than doubled its House of Representatives seats from 115 to 308 in the 2009 election, while the LDP plummeted from 300 to 119. Nevertheless, despite its large majority, the DPJ formed a coalition with the much smaller Social Democratic Party of Japan (SDPJ; 7 seats) and the People's New Party (PNP; 4 seats). The SDPJ withdrew from the coalition in May 2010 due to disagreement over policies toward relocating U.S. military bases in Okinawa.

  5. The most recent redistricting to reflect population change took place in 2006, resulting in twenty-nine single-member, twelve 2-member, five 3-member, and one 5-member districts at each election. Under the previous round of redistricting, in effect between 2000-2006, there were twenty-seven single-member, fifteen 2-member, four 3-member, and one 4-member districts in each election. For details see the House of Councillors website: http://www.sangiin.go.jp/japanese/san60/s60_shiryou/senkyo.htm.

  6. Reed and Shimizu note that the LDP and DPJ “appear divided by an unbridgeable gulf” over both the role of the Self-Defense Forces in the Iraq and Afghanistan wars, and debates over public pension records ([37]:19-20), but the former topic has since declined in salience, and the latter is more a valence than a positional issue.

  7. Only one district, Tokyo, elects more than three upper house members. We do not include this case in Table 2 since a change in district magnitude from 4 to 5 in 2007 hinders longitudinal comparison.

  8. The DPJ committed this over-nomination error in 2010, fielding two candidates in ten of the twelve 2-member districts (whereas the LDP put up only one nominee). This strategy failed everywhere.

  9. Komeito did not nominate any candidate, and both the SDPJ and the newly founded Sunrise Party did so only in one out of twelve 2-member districts, while the JCP followed its traditional strategy of putting up a standard-bearer everywhere (including SMDs).

  10. Your Party was founded in August 2009 by a LDP defector, Watanabe Yoshimi, and campaigned on a platform of reducing powers of the bureaucracy and decentralization. It won 13.6% of the list vote (10.2% of district vote) in 2010, up from 4.3% in the 2009 lower house election.

  11. Figure 3 is based on monthly polls from NHK, Japan’s public broadcaster. Polls are conducted using random digit dialing, with average sample size slightly over 1000. Results are available on http://www.nhk.or.jp/bunken/research/yoron/seijiishiki/list_seijiishiki1.html.

  12. The correlation between support for the DPJ and for the government as a whole (i.e., LDP plus Komeito) during the same period is even higher (-0.743).

  13. Support for the LDP and the new government as a whole (DPJ, SDPJ and PNP during September 2009-May 2010, DPJ and PNP thereafter) is also weakly correlated at -0.511.

  14. Similarly, Iida [12] posits that government alternation would be less likely if voters disappointed by the LDP government did not see a credible alternative in the DPJ.

  15. Correlations between the percentage of independents and support for Komeito, JCP, SDPJ, and Your Party since September 2009 are -0.122, -0.280, -0.376, and -0.124, respectively. One must exercise caution when interpreting these numbers due to lack of variation, since support for each of these parties almost never exceeded five percent.

  16. Using Duverger's classification, Japanese parties are mostly internally rather than externally created, which impedes strong party identification based on social cleavages.

  17. Official members pay higher dues and have a greater say in party activities and policy formulation. For details see the DPJ website: http://www.dpj.or.jp/info/volunteer.

  18. Annual reports available at the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications website: http://www.soumu.go.jp/senkyo/seiji_s/data_seiji/index.html.

  19. One plausible reason is that the LDP continues to suffer from “incomplete adaptation to the new electoral environment because of its institutionalized party organization”, which caused the party’s defeat in the 2009 election ([19]:255).

  20. Other regional parties include those in Shiga (founded in 2006), Iwate (2010), Ehime (2010), and Saitama (2011) prefectures.

  21. This election was precipitated by a referendum in February 2011, in which voters overwhelmingly endorsed the mayor’s (and Tax Reduction Party founder) call for an early dissolution of the municipal assembly (Yomiuri Shimbun, February 7, 2011). The election took place under a multi-member single non-transferable vote (SNTV), with district magnitudes from two to seven.

  22. Many LDP politicians cultivated personal (rather than party-based) organizations know as koenkai as means of mobilizing voters during elections [1, 3, 19], particularly in rural areas. This partly explains why the DPJ remained uncompetitive in rural seats [44] until the late 2000s.

  23. Instead, the LDP candidate’s main opponent was a nominee from the Tax Reduction Party. This may presage patterns in future contests in areas where regional parties have a strong presence.

  24. The LDP received 33.4% to the DPJ’s 39.0% in the district tier, and 24.1% to the DPJ’s 31.6% in the PR tier. The DPJ naturally won more list seats (16 to 12), but the LDP benefited from districting bias to secure 39 district seats to the DPJ’s 28.

  25. For example, one MP argued that several geographically contiguous prefectures with small populations should be combined into one single-member district, while the upper house speaker went further to advocate abolition of the district tier altogether, creating nine PR blocs instead (Yomiuri Shimbun, March 1, 2011).

  26. From 2001 onward the PR component of House of Councillors elections is open-listed, but cumulatively only three candidates were elected through this provision in elections from 2001 to 2010.

  27. While governments do not require confidence of the House of Councillors, several cabinets resigned following severe losses in upper house polls (e.g., Uno in 1989, Hashimoto in 1998, Abe in 2007).

References

  1. Bouissou, J.M. (1999). “Organizing one’s support base under the SNTV: the case of Japanese Koenkai,” In B. Grofman, S.C. Lee, E.A. Winckler, B. Woodall (eds.), Elections in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan under the single non-transferable vote: the comparative study of an embedded institution. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Christensen, R.V. (1994). “Electoral reform in Japan: How it was enacted and changes it may bring,” Asian Survey 34 (7), 589-605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Christensen, R. (1998). “The effect of electoral reforms on campaign practices in Japan: putting new wine into old bottles,” Asian Survey 38 (10), 986-1004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Cox, K.E. & Schoppa L.J. (2002). “Interaction effects in mixed-member electoral systems: Theory and evidence from Germany, Japan, and Italy,” Comparative Political Studies 35 (9), 1027-1053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Curtis, G.L. (1999). The logic of Japanese politics: Leaders, institutions, and the limits of change. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Druckman, J.N., Martin L.W., Michael F. Thies (2005). “Influence without confidence: Upper chambers and government formation,” Legislative Studies Quarterly 30 (4), 529-548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Duverger, M. (1954). Political parties: Their organization and activity in the modern state. London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Herron, E.S. & Nishikawa M. (2001). “Contamination effects and the number of parties in mixed-superposition electoral systems,” Electoral Studies 20 (1), 63-86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Hickman, J.C. & Kim C.L. (1992). “Electoral advantage, malapportionment, and one party dominance in Japan,” Asian Perspective 16 (1), 5-25.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Horiuchi, Y. & Saito J. (2003). “Reapportionment and redistribution: Consequences of electoral reform in Japan,” American Journal of Political Science 47 (4), 669-682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Iida, T. (2009). “’Shitsubo’ to ‘Kitai’ ga umu Seiken Kotai,” in A. Tanaka et al., 2009-nen, naze Seiken Kotai datta no ka. Tokyo: Keiso Shobo.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Kabashima, I. (2004). “Prospects for a two-party system in Japan,” Social Science Japan 29, 14-16.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Kabashima, I. & Ishio Y. (1998). “The instability of party identification among eligible Japanese voters: A seven-wave panel study, 1993-6,” Party Politics 4 (2), 151-176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Kabashima, I. Reed S.R. (2000). “Voter reactions to ‘strange bedfellows’: The Japanese voter faces a kaleidoscope of changing coalitions,” Japanese Journal of Political Science 1 (2), 229-248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Kabashima, I. & Yamada M. (1995). “Seito Shiji no Hendo to Mutohaso no Keisei,” Senkyo 48 (8), 1-17.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Kabashima, I., Marshall J., Uekami T., Hyun D.S. (2000). “Casual cynics or disillusioned Democrats? Political alienation in Japan,” Political Psychology 21 (4), 779-804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Kohno, M. (1997). “Voter turnout and strategic ticket-dplitting under Japan’s new electoral rules,” Asian Survey 37 (5), 429-440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Krauss, E.S. & Pekkanen R. (2011). The rise and fall of Japan’s LDP: Political party organizations as historical institutions. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Laakso, M. & Taagepera R. (1979). “’Effective’ number of parties: A measure with application to west Europe,” Comparative Political Studies 12 (1), 3-27.

    Google Scholar 

  21. LeBlanc, R.M. (2008). “The potential and limits of antiparty electoral movements in local politics,” in S.L. Martin & G. Steel (eds.), Democratic Reform in Japan: Assessing the Impact. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Lijphart, A. (1999). “SNTV and STV compared: Their political consequences in Japan, Ireland, and Malta,” In B. Grofman, S.C. Lee, E.A. Winckler, B. Woodall (eds.), Elections in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan under the single non-transferable vote: The comparative study of an embedded institution. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Maeda, K. (2006). “The general election in Japan, September 2005,” Electoral Studies 25 (3), 621-627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Maeda, K. (2009). “Has the electoral-system reform made Japanese elections party-centered?” In S.R. Reed, K.M. McElwain, K. Shimizu (eds.), Political change in Japan: Electoral behavior, party alignment, and the Koizumi reforms. Stanford: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center.

    Google Scholar 

  25. McCargo, D. (2010). “An incomplete change of course: Japan’s landmark 2009 Lower House elections and their aftermath,” Representation 46 (4), 471-479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Mizusaki, S. & Mori S. (1998). “Tokuhyo Deta kara mita Heiritsusei no Mekanizumu,” Senkyo Kenkyu 13, 50-59.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Miyake, I. (1989). Tohyo Kodo. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Moenius, J. & Kasuya Y. (2004). “Measuring party linkages across districts: Some party system inflation indices and their properties,” Party Politics 10 (5), 543-564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Norris, P. (1999). “Introduction: The growth of critical citizens?” In P. Norris (ed.), Critical citizens: Global support for Democratic government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Otake, H. (1996). “Forces for political reform: The Liberal Democratic Party’s young reformers and Ozawa Ichiro,” Journal of Japanese Studies 22 (2), 269-294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Pempel, T.J. (ed.) (1990). Uncommon democracies: The one-party dominant regimes. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Pogunkte, T. (1996). “Anti-party sentiment – conceptual thoughts and empirical evidence: Explorations into a minefield,” European Journal of Political Research 29 (3), 319-344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Rae, D.W. (1967). The political consequences of electoral laws. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Reed, S.R. (1990). “Structure and behaviour: Extending Duverger’s law to the Japanese case,” British Journal of Political Science 20 (3), 335-356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Reed, S.R. (1999). “Political reform in Japan: Combining scientific and historical analysis,” Social Science Japan Journal 2 (2), 177-193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Reed, S. (2005). “Japan: Haltingly towards a two-party system,” In M. Gallagher & P. Mitchell (eds.), The politics of electoral systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Reed, SR. & Shimizu K. (2009). “Avoiding a two-party system: The Liberal Democracy Party versus Duverger’s law,” In S. R. Reed, K.M. McElwain, K.Shimizu (eds.), Political change in Japan: Electoral behavior, party alignment, and the Koizumi reforms. Stanford: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Reed, S.R. & Thies M.F. (2001). “The consequences of electoral reform in Japan,” In M.S. Shugart & M.P. Wattenberg (eds.), Mixed-member electoral systems: The best of both worlds? Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Reif, K. & Schmitt H. (1980). “Nine second-order national elections: A conceptual framework for the analysis of european election results,” European Journal of Political Research 8 (1), 3-44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Richardson, B. (1991). “Japanese voting behavior in comparative perspective,” In S. Flanagan, et al., The Japanese Voter. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Riker, W.H. (1982). “The two-party system and Duverger’s law: An essay on the history of political science,” American Political Science Review 76 (4), 753-766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Sasaki, T. (1999). Seiji Kaikaku 1800-nichi no Shinjitsu. Tokyo: Kodansha.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Schaap, R.D. (2005). “The House of Representatives election in Japan, November 2003,” Electoral Studies 24 (1), 136-142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Scheiner, E. (2006). Democracy without competition in Japan: Opposition failure in a one-party dominant state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Shiratori, R. (1995). “The politics of electoral reform in Japan,” International Political Science Review 16 (1), 79-94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Siaroff, A. (2003). “Spurious majorities, electoral systems and electoral system change,” Commonwealth and Comparative Politics 41 (2), 143-160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Taaegpera, R. (1999). “The number of parties as a function of heterogeneity and electoral system,” Comparative Political Studies 32 (5), 531-548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Taagepera, R. & Shugart M.S. (1989). Seats and voters: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Tanaka, A. (1997). “’Seito Shiji nashi’ zo no Ishiki Kozo: Seito Shiji Gainen no Sai-kento no Shiron,” Leviathan 20, 101-129.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Tanaka, A. & Martin S. (2003). “The new independent voter and the evolving Japanese party system,” Asian Perspective 27 (3), 21-51.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Taniguchi, M., Shiro S., Chihiro O., Hideaki U. (2010). “Nisenjunen Sangiin Senkyo,” Sekai 809 (October), 58-69.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Thies, M.F. (2002). “Changing how the Japanese vote: The promise and pitfalls of the 1994 electoral reform,” In J.F.S. Hsieh & D. Newman (eds.), How Asia votes. New York: Chatham House.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Wada, J. (1996). The Japanese election system: Three analytical perspectives. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Weisberg, H.F. (1980). “A multidimensional conceptualization of party identification,” Political Behavior 2 (1), 33-60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  55. Weisberg, H.F. (1998). “Nonlinear models of electoral change: The implications of political time and chaos theory for the study of mass political behavior,” Electoral Studies 17 (3), 369-382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  56. Weisberg, H.F. & Tanaka A. (2001). “Change in the spatial dimensions of party conflict: The case of Japan in the 1990s,” Political Behavior 23 (1), 75-101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Weiner, R.J. (2009). “Declining electoral competitiveness in Japan: Postreform trends and theoretical pessimism,” In S.R. Reed, K.M. McElwain, K. Shimizu (eds.), Political change in Japan: Electoral behavior, party alignment, and the Koizumi reforms. Stanford: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Willy Jou.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jou, W. Examining the Micro-level Foundations of Japan’s Two-party System Following Government Alternation. East Asia 29, 255–274 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12140-012-9174-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12140-012-9174-3

Keywords

Navigation