Skip to main content
Log in

On-The-Job Training and Learning: Formal Training versus Learning by Doing

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper looks at and compares two methods of on-the-job training: formal training and learning by doing. The former involves an intensive training period prior to the employee directly taking on the position for which he or she was hired for, while the latter, the employee begins immediately and is expected to learn on his or her own through experience over time. The former method allows less room for shirking but involves a period of investment in the form of the value of output or service that is effectively foregone as a result of the more resource-intensive training regime. Perhaps surprisingly, even if the formal training program does not significantly improve upon the probability of future success in production or service provision, formal training can provide higher net benefits to the training firm than learning by doing because the savings from the reduction in shirking can be greater than the cost of foregone output.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In some models of on-the-job capital accumulation, it is assumed that there is an initial period of training where no production takes place. See for example, Kräkel (2016) and Stevens (1994). In others, a worker’s productivity gradually improves over time, as a result of job experience (Gibbons and Waldman 1999 and 2006). This latter process, in contrast to the former, is consistent with learning by doing while the former is what we define as formal training on the job.

  2. To avoid notational clutter, we drop the superscript “\(l\)” as we will derive the solution to each learning regime in separate sections of the paper.

  3. The argument made here is analogous to that made by Schmitz (2005a).

  4. The expression \(c/({p}_{1}^{d}-q)\) is what the transfer would be for all periods in a similar model without learning (as derived in Appendix 1) and it is larger than the transfer \(c/({p}_{2}^{d}-q)\) under learning by doing.

  5. The author would like to thank an anonymous referee for making and emphasizing this point.

References

  • De Grip A, Sauermann J, Sieben I (2016) The role of peers in estimating tenure-performance profiles: evidence from personnel data. J Econ Behav Org 126:39–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R, Waldman M (1999) A theory of wage and promotion dynamics inside firms. Q J Econ 114(4):1321–1358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R, Waldman M (2006) Enriching a theory of wage and promotion dynamics inside firms. J Lab Econ 24(1):59–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kräkel M (2016) Human capital investment and work incentives. J Econ Man Strat 25(3):627–651

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kräkel M, Schöttner A (2012) Internal labor markets and worker rents. J Econ Behav Org 84:491–509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuven E (2005) The economics of private sector training: a survey of the literature. J Econ Surveys 19(1):91–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pi J (2014) Job design with sequential tasks and outcome externalities revisited. Econ Letters 125:274–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz PW (2005a) Allocating control in agency problems with limited liability and sequential hidden actions. Rand J Econ 36(2):318–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz PW (2005b) Should contractual clauses that forbid renegotiation always be enforced. J Law Econ Org 21(2):315–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz PW (2013) Job design with conflicting tasks reconsidered. Eur Econ Rev 57:108–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Starr E (2019) Consider this: training, wages, and the enforceability of covenants not to compete. InterLab Rev 72(4):783–817

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens M (1994) A theoretical model of on-the-job training with imperfect competition. Oxf Econ Papers 4:537–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

None.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Not Applicable.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kevin Siqueira.

Ethics declarations

Ethical Statement

See Below.

Ethical Approval

Not Applicable.

Financial or Non-Financial Interests

None.

Informed Consent

Not Applicable.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

In the two-period moral hazard model with limited liability but without learning by doing, let \(q\) be the probability of production success if the worker shirks and \({p}_{1}\) the probability of production success in the first and second period if the worker exerts high effort. As before, high effort costs the agent \(c\) whereas shirking costs the agent nothing. The incentive compatibility constraints for the second period are:

$$\begin{array}{c}{p}_{1}{t}_{ss}+\big(1-{p}_{1}\big){t}_{sf}-c\ge q{t}_{ss}+\big(1-q\big){t}_{sf},\\ {p}_{1}{t}_{fs}+\big(1-{p}_{1}\big){t}_{ff}-c\ge q{t}_{fs}+(1-q){t}_{ff},\end{array}$$

where the two are designed respectively, to implement high effort in the event of production success or in the event of failure in the first period. These can rewritten as:

$$\begin{array}{ccc}({p}_{1}-q)({t}_{ss}-{t}_{sf})\ge c& \mathrm{and}& ({p}_{1}-q)({t}_{fs}-{t}_{ff})\ge c\end{array},$$

or as:

$$\begin{array}{ccc}{t}_{ss}-{t}_{sf}\ge \frac{c}{{p}_{1}-q}& \mathrm{and}& {t}_{fs}-{t}_{ff}\ge \frac{c}{{p}_{1}-q}.\end{array}$$

The first-period incentive compatibility constraint is:

$$\begin{array}{l}{p}_{1}\big[{t}_{s}+\big({p}_{1}{t}_{ss}+\big(1-{p}_{1}\big){t}_{sf}-c\big)\big]+ \big(1-{p}_{1}\big)\big[{t}_{f}+\big({p}_{1}{t}_{fs}+\big(1-{p}_{1}\big){t}_{ff}-c\big)\big]-\mathrm{c}\ge \\ \mathrm{q}[{t}_{s}+ \big({p}_{1}{t}_{ss}+\big(1-{p}_{1}\big){t}_{sf}-c\big)]+(1-q)[{t}_{f}+({p}_{1}{t}_{fs}+\big(1-{p}_{1}\big){t}_{ff}-c)],\end{array}$$

Rearranging we have:

$$\left({p}_{1}-q\right)\left[{t}_{s}-{t}_{f}+{p}_{1}\left({t}_{ss}-{t}_{fs}\right)+\left(1-{p}_{1}\right)\left({t}_{sf}-{t}_{ff}\right)\right]\ge c,$$

or:

$$\left[{t}_{s}-{t}_{f}+{p}_{1}\left({t}_{ss}-{t}_{fs}\right)+\left(1-{p}_{1}\right)\left({t}_{sf}-{t}_{ff}\right)\right]\ge \frac{c}{\left({p}_{1}-q\right)}.$$

Using similar arguments as in the text, the firm would like the transfers, to be made in the event of unsuccessful production, to be as low as possible but because of the limited liability constraints, they can only go as low as zero. Hence \({t}_{f}={t}_{sf}={t}_{ff}=0\) and from the binding second-period incentive compatibility constraints: \({t}_{ss}={t}_{fs}=c/({p}_{1}-q)\). Given these results, we can see that the first-period incentive compatibility constraint (the last equation above) is independent of any adjustments to second-period transfers (and the resulting agent’s second-period rent) to save on motivating the agent in the first period as \({t}_{ss}={t}_{fs}\), \({t}_{sf}={t}_{ff}\) and \({t}_{f}=0\). As the first period incentive constraint is binding, we have \({t}_{s}=c/({p}_{1}-q)\), which is also the same as the second-period incentive payments to the agent.

Appendix 2

For convenience, we first state our result again which is then followed by the proof.

Result

Given \({p}_{1}^{\tau }={p}_{1}^{d}={p}_{1}\) and \({p}_{2s}^{\tau }={p}_{2}^{d}={p}_{2}\), if the quality of second period production under learning by doing is such that \({\alpha }_{2}<\widehat{{\alpha }_{2}}\) with \(\widehat{{\alpha }_{2}}=1-\left[\frac{({p}_{1}+1)}{{p}_{2}}\theta +{\alpha }_{1}\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{2}}\right]\) and \(\theta ={p}_{2}-{p}_{2f}^{\tau }\) along with the probability of first-period success being sufficiently high, \({p}_{1}>\widehat{{p}_{1}}\), then formal training results in higher expected payoffs compared to learning by doing.

Proof

Given the assumptions of the proposition, the expression for the difference in the expected value of production can be written as:

$$\left[{p}_{1}{p}_{2}+\left(1-{p}_{1}\right){p}_{2f}^{\tau }-{\alpha }_{1}{p}_{1}-{\alpha }_{2}{p}_{2}\right]V$$

or as

$$\left[{p}_{1}{p}_{2}+\left(1-{p}_{1}\right)({p}_{2}-\theta )-{\alpha }_{1}{p}_{1}-{\alpha }_{2}{p}_{2}\right]V.$$

The term in brackets will be weakly positive if

$${p}_{2}-\big(1-{p}_{1}\big)\theta -{\alpha }_{1}{p}_{1}-{\alpha }_{2}{p}_{2}\ge 0,$$

or as long as the following condition holds:

$$\widehat{{\alpha }_{2}}=1-\left[\frac{\left(1-{p}_{1}\right)}{{p}_{2}}\theta +{\alpha }_{1}\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{2}}\right]\ge {\alpha }_{2}.$$

Note that it can be shown that \({p}_{2}\ge {\alpha }_{1}\) is sufficient for the sum in the bracketed term to be less than one. To show that the difference in costs can be negative, we can use the result in the proof of Proposition 2 since the expressions for the cost difference are the same. Thus there exists a range of \({p}_{1}\) such that if \({p}_{1}\ge \widehat{{p}_{1}}\), then \(\Lambda \le 0\), and the costs are higher under learning by doing.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Siqueira, K. On-The-Job Training and Learning: Formal Training versus Learning by Doing. J Labor Res 44, 181–198 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-023-09350-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-023-09350-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation