Skip to main content
Log in

Crime and International Tourism

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a panel data set of European countries, this paper investigates the impact of crime on international tourism. Violent crimes are negatively associated with incoming international tourists and international tourism revenue indicating that international tourists consider the risk of victimization when choosing a location to visit. This impact is smaller in magnitude in Southern European countries with a coastline which are generally more attractive tourist destinations in terms of sea tourism, suggesting that victimization risk and attractiveness of the destination may be substitutable traits.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. http://mkt.unwto.org/en/publication/unwto-tourism-highlights-2013-edition

  2. For example, using data from Caribbean, Maloney and Rojas (2005) find that income elasticity of tourism demand is 4.9. Vogt (2008) reports an elasticity of 2.7 for US tourism.

  3. Regarding the impact of word-of-mouth information on behavior, see Rincke and Traxler (2009).

  4. Maloney and Rojas (2005) and Vogt (2008) reports that the income elasticity of international tourism demand is greater than 2.

  5. This holds true even for the violent crimes. Some violent crimes, such as robberies, involve monetary returns. In addition, violent crimes may occur due to a property crime. For example, a pocket lifter may use their weapon to force the victim to surrender, if the victim notices their wallet/purse is being stolen.

  6. These authors do not find a relationship between tourism activity and violent crime. This may be because, when tourists (who are presumably wealthy) visit a country, the expected return to criminal activities such as theft and burglary goes up, since incoming tourists may increase the number of targets from whom valuable assets can be stolen by the potential criminals. However, there are no direct incentives for committing a violent crime, such as murder or rape. Therefore, the link from tourism to violent crime is expected to be much weaker.

  7. Specifically, these authors use one period lagged arrest rates to explain the variation in crime.

  8. Russia is an exception. This is because, the majority of Russian territory is located in the Northern Europe where the climate does not permit sea tourism.

  9. http://mkt.unwto.org/en/publication/unwto-tourism-highlights-2013-edition

  10. Russia is an exception. I excluded Russia from the Sea Tourism Available sample, because the majority of Russian territory is located in Northern Europe where the weather conditions are not suitable for sea tourism.

  11. http://whc.unesco.org/en/criteria/

  12. Although the coefficient of the homicide rate in the No Sea Tourism Opportunity sample is much larger than it is in the Sea Tourism Available sample, the mean of tourism revenue in the No Sea Tourism sample is larger as well. In addition, the mean of the homicide rate in the No Sea Tourism sample is smaller. As a result, the elasticity estimates are comparable.

References

  • Balaguer J, Cantavella-Jorda M (2002) Tourism as a long-run economic growth factor: the Spanish case. Appl Econ 34:877–884

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block M, Heineke J (1975) A labor theoretic analysis of the criminal choice. Am Econ Rev 65(3):314–325

    Google Scholar 

  • Corman H, Mocan N (2000) A time-series analysis of crime, deterrence and drug abuse in New York City. Am Econ Rev 90(3):584–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cullen J, Levitt S (1999) Crime, urban flight, and the consequences for cities. Rev Econ Stat 81(2):159–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eugenio-Martin J, Campos-Soria J (2011) Income and the substitution pattern between domestic and international tourism demand. Appl Econ 43:2519–2531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama E, MacBeth J (1973) Risk, return, and equilibrium: empirical tests. J Pol Econ 81(3):607–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feridun M (2011) Impact of terrorism on tourism in Turkey: empirical evidence from Turkey. Appl Econ 43:3349–3354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleischer A, Buccola S (2002) War, terror, and the tourism market in Israel. Appl Econ 34:1335–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garin-Munoz T, Amaral T (2000) An econometric model for international tourism flows to Spain. Appl Econ Lett 7:525–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gunduz L, Hatemi JA (2005) Is the tourism-led growth hypothesis valid for Turkey? Appl Econ Lett 12:499–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howsen R, Jarrell S (1987) Some determinants of property crime: economic factors influence criminal behavior but cannot completely explain the syndrome. Am J Econ Sociol 4(46):445–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howsen R, Jarrell S (1990) Transient crowding and crime: the more “Strangers” in an area, the more crime except for murder, assault and rape. Am J Econ Sociol 4(49):483–494

    Google Scholar 

  • Levantis T, Gani A (2000) Tourism demand and the nuisance of crime. Int J Soc Econ 27:959–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt S (1998) Juvenile crime and punishment. J Pol Econ 106:1156–1185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyssiotou P (2000) Dynamic analysis of British demand for tourism abroad. Empir Econ 15:421–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maloney W, Rojas G (2005) How elastic are sea, sand and sun? Dynamic panel estimates of the demand for tourism. Appl Econ Lett 12:277–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McPheters L, Stronge W (1974) Crime as an environmental externality of tourism: Miami, Florida. Land Econ 50(3):288–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mello M, Pack A, Sinclair T (2002) A system of equations model of UK tourism demand in neighboring countries. Appl Econ 34:509–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patuelli R, Mussoni M, Candela G (2013) The effects of world heritage sites on domestic tourism: a spatial interaction model for Italy. J Geogr Syst 15:369–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peri G (2004) Socio-cultural variables and economic success: evidence from Italian provinces. B.E. J Macroecon Top 4(1), article 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson R, Loomis J (2004) Adaptive recreation planning and climate change: a contingent visitation approach. Ecol Econ 50(1–2):83–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rincke J, Traxler C (2009) Deterrence through word of mouth. CESifo working paper series 2549. CESifo Group, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Sequeira T, Nunes P (2008) Does tourism influence economic growth? A dynamic panel data approach. Appl Econ 40:2431–2441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegfried J, Zimbalist A (2000) The economics of sports facilities and their communities. J Econ Perspect 14(3):95–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smyth R, Nielsen I, Mishra V (2009) I’ve been to Bali too’ (and I will be going back): are terrorist shocks to Bali’s tourist arrivals permanent or transitory? Appl Econ 41:1367–1378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogt M (2008) Determinants of the demand for US exports and imports of tourism. Appl Econ 40:667–672

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Duha T. Altindag.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Altindag, D.T. Crime and International Tourism. J Labor Res 35, 1–14 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-014-9174-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-014-9174-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation