Skip to main content
Log in

Meet the Producer: Exchange Rate Shocks, Media Salience, and the Legislative Importance of Economic Sectors in Argentina

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the last 15 years, considerable efforts have been directed towards understanding how currency shocks affect the clout of economic actors. Little research, however, has studied how currency shocks affect the salience of key economic actors and their organizations among the public. In this article, we test for the effect of currency shock on the media salience and legislative importance of economic actors. We use a novel empirical design that (1) measures the level of media salience of 23 Labor, Rural, Business, and Financial Associations and (2) measures the targets of legislation initiated in key Congressional committees. Results show that currency shocks have moderate effects on the media salience of economic actors and more pronounced policy consequences, reflected on the legislative importance of key economic jurisdictions in Congress.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is little research that analyzes the effect of economic shocks on the economic issue salience of actors. For a notable exception see Culpepper (2011), which describes how differences in issue salience affect corporate governance in Europe and Japan.

  2. La Nación (published since 1870) and Clarín (published since 1945) are the two most important newspaper in Argentina. La Nación is considered a conservative newspaper, with close ties to the church, the military, and businesses, targeted to a relatively wealthier and more conservative constituency. Clarín has a less-defined political leaning, targeted to wider readership of middle classes and the urban poor.

  3. Galiani et al. (2003) provide an excellent overview of the Convertibility policies and the causes of its collapse in 2001.

  4. See Murillo (2005) and Murillo and Gallardo (2007) for an excellent analysis of the process of privatization, deregulation, and re-regulation of the utility service markets in Latin America.

  5. The rise in the price of commodities has transformed the relationship with China, which has become one of Argentina’s main trading partners.

  6. Affiliation matrices are symmetric matrices describing the number of ties of a subject i with all other individuals in a network.

  7. Nodes in economic networks represent the different individual agents, which in this study represent interest groups and key government agencies, and where links between the nodes represent their interactions. The socioeconomic perspective has emphasized understanding how the strategic behavior of the interacting agents is influenced by relatively simple network architectures (Schweitzer et al. 2009).

  8. Centrality is defined as the number of links incident upon a node (i.e. the number of ties that an interest group has).

  9. The Phoenix Group included a number of local economists who sponsored an abandonment of the pegged currency policy, more flexible monetary management, and a pro-industry economic strategy.

  10. The increase of commodity prices was strongly influenced by a robust Chinese demand, especially in the prices of soy and its byproducts (Song et al. 2006).

  11. The articles from the Economics section of La Nación provide more reliable data than dyads drawn from Clarín, since the economic news usually contain more relevant information about meetings, agreements, and exchanges among economic actors. Political news, by contrast, contains editorialized information and considerable more noise. While we consider La Nación to provide more reliable economic information, we also use all news from Clarín to assess the robustness of our findings.

  12. It is important to note that we include dyads up to December of 2007. Therefore, our analysis does not include (and is not affected), by the highly publicized conflict between agro-producers and the government in regards to the change in retenciones (tax fee) proposed by the Decree 125 in 2008–2009. Explaining the determinants of this conflict over this particular policy is beyond the scope of this paper. For an analysis of the agro-conflict in 2008 see Fairfield (2011).

  13. Today, soybeans have replaced beef and wheat as the country’s leading export (Richardson 2008).

  14. It is worth reminding readers that a dyad indicates that two actors are mentioned in the same article. We do not include information on how many times they are mentioned in the same article.

  15. Gains in network proximity are particularly pronounced for estimates from La Nación and more moderate for Clarín. Such results are to be expected, given that data from La Nación includes economic articles while news from Clarín includes also political articles which often editorialize events.

  16. Data to analyze the content of executive law initiatives is also available from the authors and posted in http://www.bsos.umd.edu/gvpt/calvo/.

  17. Roughly 50 % of the legislation reported from Committee is later approved on the plenary floor.

  18. Notice that legislation can be sent to multiple committees. Consequently, there is no “undercount” in the data. If a bill is relevant for industry and agriculture, the bill will be sent to both of them.

References

  • Acuña C. "Business Interests, Dictatorship, and Democracy in Argentina." In Business and Democracy in Latin America, edited by Bartell and Payne. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press; 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker A. Why is trade reform so popular in Latin America? A consumption-based theory of trade policy preferences. World Polit. 2003;55(3):423–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker A. Who wants to globalize? Consumer tastes and labor markets in a theory of trade policy beliefs. Am J Polit Sci. 2005;49(4):924–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, Pranab K., Samuel Bowles, and Michael Wallerstein. Globalization and egalitarian redistribution. New York, Princeton, N.J.: Russell Sage Foundation; Princeton University Press; 2006

  • Bernhard, William, and David Leblang. Democratic institutions and exchange-rate commitments. Cambridge Journals Online. 1999

  • Bhagwati J. Protectionism. Cambridge: MIT Press; 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corrales J. Coalitions and corporate choices in Argentina, 1976–1994: the recent private sector support for privatizations. Stud Comp Int Dev. 1998;32(4):24–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culpepper PD. Quiet politics and business power : corporate control in Europe and Japan, Cambridge studies in comparative politics. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, Sebastian. Crisis and reform in Latin America. 1995.

  • Etchemendy, Sebastian, and Ruth Berins Collier. Down but not out: union resurgence and segmented neocorporatism in Argentina (2003 2007). 2007.

  • Evans P. Embedded autonomy. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fairfield T. Business power and protest: Argentina’s agricultural producers protest in comparative context. Stud Comp Int Dev (SCID). 2011;46(4):424–53. doi:10.1007/s12116-011-9094-z.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feinerer I. An introduction to text mining in R. R News. 2008;8(2):19–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, Jeffry. Exchange rate politics: contemporary lessons from American history. Review of International Political Economy, Spring; 1994 81–103.

  • Frieden JA. Debt, development, and democracy. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frieden JA. Labor and the Politics of Exchange Rates: The Case of the European Moneatry System. In: Sanford J, editor. In the workers of nations: industrial relations in a global economy. New York: Oxford U.P; 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, Jeffry A., and Laurence J. Broz. "The Political Economy of Exchange Rates." In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, edited by Barry Weingast and Donald Wittman. New York: Oxford; 2006 587–600.

  • Galiani S, Heymann D, Tomassi M. Expectativas frustradas: el ciclo de la Convertibilidad 3–44, April-June, 2003. Desarrollo Económico. 2003;43(169):3–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson E. The populist road to market reform: policy and electoral coalitions in Mexico and Argentina. World Polit. 1997;59(3):339–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourevitch P. Politics in hard times: comparative responses to international crises. Ithaca: Cornell University; 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E. Interest groups and trade policy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. "A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics." In NBER working paper series working paper 11014. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 2004. http://papers.nber.org/papers/W11014.

  • Haggard S, Sylvia M, Ben Ross S. Theories of Business and Business-State Relations. In: Sylvia M, Ben Ross S, editors. Business and the state in developing countries. Ithaca: Cornell U.P; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman A. Declining industries and political-support protectionist motives. Am Econ Rev. 1982;72(5):1180–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman A. The political economy of protection, fundamentals of pure and applied economics. London: Harwood; 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hiscox, Michael J. Class versus industry cleavages: inter-industry factor mobility and the politics of trade. Cambridge Journals Online. 2001.

  • Hiscox MJ. International trade and political conflict: commerce, coalitions, and mobility. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kollman K. Outside lobbying: public opinion and interest group strategies. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1998.

  • Magee, S. "Three simple tests of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem." In Issues in International Economics, edited by Oppenheimer. London: Oriel; 1982.

  • Midford P. International trade and domestic politics: improving on Rogowski's model of political alignments. Int Organ. 1994;47(4):535–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundell RA. A theory of optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev. 1961;51(4):657–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murillo MV, Gallardo CM. Political competition and policy adoption: market reforms in Latin American public utilities. Am J Polit Sci. 2007;51(1).

  • Murillo MV, Schrank A. With a little help from my friends: partisan politics, transnational alliances, and labor rights in Latin America. Comp Polit Stud. 2005;38(8):971–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murillo MV. Partisanship amidst convergence. Comp Polit. 2005;37(4):441–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murillo MV. Labor competition and partisan coalitions in Latin America: trade unions and market reforms. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2001.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Niemi RG, Bartels LM. New measures of issue salience: an evaluation. J Polit. 1985;47(04):1212–20. doi:10.2307/2130815.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O´Donnell, Guillermo. "Estado y Alianzas en Argentina." In Contrapunto, edited by Guillermo O´Donnell. Buenos Aires: Paidos; 1997.

  • O´Donnell, G. "State and Alliances in Argentina, 1955–1976." J Dev Stud. 1978;15(1):3–33.

  • Petrocik JR. Issue ownership in presidential elections, with a 1980 case study. Am J Polit Sci. 1996;40(3):825–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richardson NP. Export-oriented populism: commodities and coalitions in Argentina. Stud Comp Int Dev. 2008;44:228–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogowski R. Commerce and coalitions: how trade affects domestic political alignments. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose A. One money, one market: estimating the effect of common currencies on trade. Cambridge, MA.: National Bureau of Economic Research; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schamis H. Distributional coalitions and the politics of economic reform in Latin America. World Polit. 1999;52(2):236–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider BR. Business politics and the state in twentieth-century Latin America. Cambridge, NY: Cambridge University Press; 2004.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schweitzer F, Fagiolo G, Sornette D, Vega-redondo O, White DR. Economic networks : what do we know and what do we need to know. Science. 2009;325(5939):422–425.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sikkink K. Ideas and institutions: developmentalism in Brazil and Argentina. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Song B, Merchant, MA, Xu S. Competitive analysis of chinese soybean import suppliers – U.S., Brazil, and Argentina. 2006. Available from: http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/21109/1/sp06so03.pdf.

  • Spiller PT, Tommasi M. The institutional foundations of public policy in Argentina, political economy of institutions and decisions. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2007.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stokes S. "What do Policy Switches Tell Us about Democracy?" In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, edited by Adam Przeworski, Susan Stokes and Bernard Manin, 98–130. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tifft S, Jones A. The trust: the private and powerful family behind the New York Times. New York: Back Bay Books; 2000.

  • Wallerstein M, Moene KO. "Bargaining Structure and Economic Performance." In trade union behavior, pay bargaining, and economic performance. Oxford: Clarendon; 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein M, David A-S. Selected works of Michael Wallerstein : the political economy of inequality, unions, and social democracy, Cambridge studies in comparative politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo-Cumings M. The developmental state, Cornell studies in political economy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zaller J, Feldman S. A simple theory of the survey response: answering questions versus revealing preferences. Am J Polit Sci. 1992;36(3):579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

A special debt of gratitude goes to Michael Wallerstein (✡), with whom Ernesto Calvo first discussed the issue of measuring exchange rate shocks and legislative attention. We would also like to thank Andy Baker, Ingo Feinerer, Rob Franzese, Jeffry Frieden, Nathan Jensen, Daniel Verdier, three anonymous reviewers, and the participants of the conference “Politics and the Global Recession” at Washington University, St. Louis, who kindly provided feedback for this project.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ernesto Calvo.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Calvo, E., Ponce, A.F. Meet the Producer: Exchange Rate Shocks, Media Salience, and the Legislative Importance of Economic Sectors in Argentina. St Comp Int Dev 48, 331–355 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-013-9131-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-013-9131-1

Keywords

Navigation