Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Unemployment Risks and the Origins of Unemployment Compensation

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper focuses on the distribution of sectoral unemployment risks and the role of political regimes in the foundational moments of unemployment compensation. The institutionalization of unemployment compensation is a function of two factors. First, it depends on the distribution of unemployment risks by economic sectors. Second, the effect of risk inequality is conditional upon the political regime type. I employ event history analysis of 144 countries throughout the world for the long historical period from 1880 to 2000. The results show that an overall societal level of unemployment risk and inequality of sectoral unemployment risks in a society are positively associated with the likelihood of the institutionalization of unemployment compensation. In addition, the effect of risk inequality is much higher under democracy than under dictatorship. A broader implication is that the creation of unemployment compensation is not only a function of homogeneous working class power but also a function of working class conflict that stems from the heterogeneity of unemployment risks among workers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The so-called class analysis is intrinsically based on the Marxian zero-sum nature of social interests—“the interests of capital and the interests of wage labor are diametrically opposed to each other” (Marx 2001[1847]: 39). So, in a pure form of class analysis, it follows that the possibility of cross-class compromise is almost infeasible by assumption, and even if it happens, it is not a sustainable equilibrium. About the conditions under which the compromise can occur, see Przeworski’s seminal article, “Proletariat into a Class: The Process of Class Formation” (1985). The power resources theory, one of the dominant approaches in the welfare state literature, is also fundamentally predicated in class analysis, while it focuses more on the link between the state (leftist party in the parliament and the cabinet) and society (labor movement; e.g., Stephens 1979; Korpi 1983; Esping-Andersen 1990; Huber and Stephens 2001).

  2. A systemic exploration about the role of unions is beyond the scope of this paper. Yet, one thing clear from Baldwin (1992) and Mares (2003a, b) is that unlike a standard class analysis or “laborist approach” that focus on well-organized union movements exclusively based on class solidarity, many historical cases show that unions’ positions on issues of unemployment compensation greatly varied across countries precisely for the extent of the division among “risk categories” within unions. A typical example is a chronic division between craft skilled-based unions and unskilled unions in the working class movement. Indeed, it is well conceived in the class formation literature that a “class in itself” does not automatically translate into a “class for itself” (see Przeworski 1985). Concerning the issue of an institutional design of unemployment compensation, European trade unions revealed a varying degree of preferences. For example, French trade unions demanded a compulsory unemployment insurance (Mares 2003b: 111–113), and the British union movement “condemned the introduction of a compulsory scheme” (Harris 1972: 304), while Norwegian union leaders opposed the new unemployment insurance system and boycotted its implementation (Alber 1981: 153), and unions had no position on this issue in Switzerland (Harrington 1998: 209).

  3. The study of welfare policy as the public provision of insurance has been recently burgeoning. Barr (1998, 2001) provides a generic social insurance model that explains the state intervention when social risks are differentiated. Hindriks and De Donder’s model (2003) incorporates people’s different risks and incomes in the context of provision of social insurance. Baldwin (1992), Harrington (1998), and Mares (2003a, b), as mentioned in the text, historically trace the origins of European welfare states, focusing on the importance of social risks. Inspired by Foucault’s notion of “governmentality,” Francois Ewald (1991) presents a sharp analysis about the relationship between the social insurance technique and the emergence of concept of unemployment as a risk. In a similar vein, Walters (2000) traces the history of governing unemployment as risk management. Moss (2002) employs the theory of risk management and analyzes the history of American social security. See also Rosanvalon (2000) and Kim (2007a).

  4. Notice that a homogeneous low-risk society may appear in societies other than an agricultural society. A society where firms have difficulty or are not willing to fire workers (due to tight government employment policies, enterprise-based compensation, or labor hoarding) shows low unemployment rates. But these practices stem from a society’s employment system, not from its industrial configurations.

  5. The notion of unemployment was invented along with the advent of industrial society. In contrast to prior beliefs and practices that viewed unemployment as an individual risk, resulting from idleness or unwillingness to work due to moral shortcomings of the worker, the “modern” notion of unemployment stresses the social determinations of this risk and the fact that unemployment is a natural, if regrettable by-product of a particular organization of work in the modern enterprise (Piore 1987).

  6. About the data sources, see footnote 5. The number of countries declines from 170 to 144 in the statistical analysis, since the most important independent variables—the inequality and magnitude of risks—have missing observations in 37 countries.

  7. Empirical studies supporting the sectoral variation of unemployment are abundant. See among others Creedy (1981).

  8. In addition to the Gini index, I have constructed other similar indices such as the Theil index and coefficient of variation (CV) and found they are almost identical.

  9. Although it was officially adopted by many international organizations (the UN, ILO, FAO, and UNESCO) in 1968, this classification had been historically used long before. I have found that many historical data follows this classification of nine sectors with one- digit codes.

  10. This data set is the most comprehensive and consistent for my purpose in that the number of employed, unemployed, and labor force (or economically active population) are all collected with a consistent classification of sectors (the nine sectors), the longest time coverage and the largest number of countries in a single data-file. The data I used to calculate sectoral unemployment rates covers 43 countries from 1970 to 2000.

  11. One might wonder that the calculated unemployment rates instead of these scales should be assigned to capture degrees of risk among sectors. However, it is not certain that these degrees of risk can be universally applied in the earlier years. Since the main purpose of this operationalization is to establish the rank of risks by sectors, I minimize this uncertainty and standardize the degrees of risk, by using ordered cardinal values fall between 1 and 9 with one unit interval. Yet both scales produce substantively similar results.

  12. An important aspect is that I have grouped the data of the nine sectors, so the above standard equation of the Gini index needs to be modified. Notice that here workers not sectors are arranged in ascending order among the whole sample, N. Although workers’ risk values are the same within the same sector, they are treated as if they are arranged in ascending order in calculating the Gini coefficient. What differentiates workers is the sectoral risk values which workers are entitled by being employed in their sectors (find that ascending orders are multiplied by the sectoral risk values). Thus, the modified equation with grouped data is as follows: \( {\text{Gini}} = 1 + \left( {1/N} \right) - \left[ {\left( {1/2} \right){N^2}\mu } \right] \times \left[ {{y_5}\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{{n^5}} { + {y_2}} } \right.\sum\nolimits_{i = {n^5} + 1}^{{n^2}} { + {y_3}} \sum\nolimits_{i = {n^2} + 1}^{{n^3}} { + {y_6}} \sum\nolimits_{i = {n^3} + 1}^{{n^6}} { + {y_8}} \sum\nolimits_{i = {n^6} + 1}^{{n^8}} { + {y_7}} \sum\nolimits_{i = {n^8} + 1}^{{n^7}} { + {y_9}} \sum\nolimits_{i = {n^7} + 1}^{{n^9}} { + {y_4}} \sum\nolimits_{i = {n^9} + 1}^{{n^4}} { + {y_1}} \left. {\sum\nolimits_{i = {n^4} + 1}^{{n^1}} {} } \right] \).

  13. In the original ACLP, a regime type variable is coded 1 for dictatorships and 0 for democracies. I switched the value from 0 to 1 for democracies to interpret the results in terms of democracy.

  14. To fully capture the movement, a variable of trade unions should be included instead. However, due to the paucity of data on unionization, which covers only several data points for advanced capitalist countries, I take this measure as a rough proxy for the strength of the working class movement. In fact, based on the limited union density figures taken from Stephens (1979: Table 4.8), I found a relatively high correlation between unionization and this variable in early western European countries, 0.69. Nevertheless, I acknowledge the deficiency of the measure and accordingly draw the inferences with caution until better indicators of unionization for developing countries can be found.

  15. An alternative method is to use likelihood ratio tests that are done against the three hypotheses (i.e., whether the model is lognormal, Weibull, or exponential) regarding the relevant parameters from the generalized gamma model (Box-Steffensmeier and Jones 2004: 41). I found that none of the three null hypotheses can be rejected, suggesting any of the three models—exponential, Weibull, and lognormal—is a possibility.

  16. The AIC is defined as: \( AIC = - {\text{2ln}}\;L + { 2}\left( {a + c} \right) \); where L is log-likelihood, a is the number of model covariates, and c the number of model-specific distributional parameters. I estimated the models with the second lowest values as well, and their results are substantively similar to the ones with the lowest values. The AIC values are as follows:

    Model

    Column I-1

    Column I-2

    Column I-3

    Column I-4

    Exponential

    175.2592

    170.4933

    114.9370

    108.7093

    Weibull

    169.9436

    166.5987

    116.0559

    110.2988

    Lognormal

    172.7879

    169.0764

    115.3998

    109.8569

    Gompertz

    177.1857

    172.3642

    116.8854

    110.6769

    Log-logistic

    176.9449

    172.8055

    118.8065

    111.6032

  17. This method is better than the use of a series of dummy variables, since the number of years in my sample is too great, resulting in the loss of many degrees of freedom. Alternatively, I employed more flexible semiparametric models of the generalized additive model and the Cox model and found that the results remain intact. The results are available on request.

  18. Specifically, for risk inequality, the estimated hazard rate increases by 0.197%, that is, \( \exp \left[ {\left( {{{\hat \beta }_{\text{RiskInequality}}} \times 2} \right) - \left( {{{\hat \beta }_{\text{RiskInequality}}} \times 1} \right)} \right]/\left( {{{\hat \beta }_{\text{RiskInequality}}} \times 1} \right) \). For risk level, the increase is 4.640 and 2.781 for democracy.

  19. In fact, the conditional effect upon dictatorial regimes is (0.31)F′(·), which is higher than the one upon democratic regimes.

  20. Risk level is set at 3.91, working class at 13.98%, income at $2,943.30, and time at 42.54.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J. Why did the west extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Q J Econ. 2000;115:1167–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alber J. Government responses to the challenge of unemployment: the development of unemployment insurance in Western Europe. In: Flora P, Heidenbeimer A, editors. The development of welfare states in Europe and America. New Brunswick: Transaction; 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alt J, King G, Signorino C. Aggregation among binary, count, and duration models: estimating the same quantities from different levels of data. Polit Anal. 2001;1:21–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amsden A. Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin P. The politics of social solidarity: class bases of the European Welfare State 1975–1975. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr N. The economics of the welfare state. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr N. The welfare state as piggy bank. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barraclough G. An introduction to contemporary history. Middlesex: Penguin; 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck N, Katz J, Tucker R. Taking time seriously: time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. Am J Polit Sci. 1998;42:1260–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blaustein S. Unemployment insurance in the United States. Kalamazoo: W.E. UPJOHN Institute for Employment Research; 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaustein S et al. An international review of unemployment insurance 26 schemes. Kalamazoo: W.E. UPJOHN Institute for Employment Research; 1977.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bramber T, Clark W, Golder M. Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analysis. Polit Anal. 2005;14(1):63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier J, Jones B. Event history modeling: a guide for social scientists. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cleves M, Gould W, Gutierrez R. An introduction to survival analysis using stata. College Station: Stata; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier D, Messick R. Prerequisites versus diffusion: testing alternative explanations for social security adoption. Am Polit Sci Rev. 1975a;69(4):1299–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier D, Messick R. Prerequisites versus diffusion: testing alternative explanations of social security adoption. Am Polit Sci Rev. 1975b;69(41):299–1315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Creedy J. Unemployment insurance in Britain. In: Creedy J, editor. The economics of unemployment in Britain. London: Butterworths; 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crotty J, Lee K-K. The effects of neoliberal ‘reforms’ on the post-crisis Korean economy. Rev Radic Polit Econ. 2006;38(4):669–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen G. The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen G. Social foundations of postindustrial economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1999.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Estevez-Abe M, Inversen T, Soskice D. Social protection and the formation of skills: a reinterpretation of the welfare state. In: Hall P, Soskice D, editors. Varieties of capitalism: the institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001. p. 145–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans P. Embedded autonomy: state and industrial transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ewald F. Insurance and risk. In: Burchell G et al., editors. The foucault effect: studies in governmentality. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gandhi J, Przeworski A. Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion under dictatorship. Econ Polit. 2006;18(1):1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard S, Kaufman R. Development, democracy, and welfare states: Latin America, East Asia and Eastern Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall P, Soskice D. Varieties of capitalism: the institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington M. Trade and social insurance: the development of national unemployment insurance in advanced industrial democracies. Ph.D. Dissertation. Los Angeles: University of California; 1998.

  • Harris J. Unemployment and politics: a study of British social policy, 1886–1914. Oxford: Clarendon; 1972.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heston A, Summers R. The Penn World Table (Mark 6.1). Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks A. Social democracy and welfare capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hindriks J, De Donder P. The politics of redistributive social insurance. J Public Econ. 2003;87(12):2639–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber E. Options for social policy in Latin America: neoliberal versus social democratic models. In: Esping-Andersen G, editor. Welfare states in transition: national adaptations in global economies. London: Sage; 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber E, Stephens J. Development and crisis of the welfare state: parties and policies in global markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Labor Organization. The world employment report 1998–99. Geneva: ILO; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Labor Organization. World labor report 2000: income security and social protection in a changing world. Geneva: ILO; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen T. Capitalism, democracy, and welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen T, Cusack T. The cause of welfare state expansion: deindustrialization and globalization. World Polit. 2000;52:313–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen T, Soskice D. An asset theory of social policy preferences. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2001;95:875–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim W. Social risk and social insurance: political demand for unemployment insurance. Ration Soc. 2007a;19(2):229–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim W. Social insurance expansion and political regime dynamics in Europe, 1880–1945. Soc Sci Q. 2007b;88(2):494–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koo H. Korean workers: the culture and politics of class formation. Ithaca: Cornell University Press; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korpi W. The democratic class struggle. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul; 1983.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran T. Private truths, public lies: the social consequence of preference falsification. Massachusetts: Harvard University Press; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert P. The distribution and redistribution of income. Manchester: Manchester University Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee E. The Asian financial crisis: the challenge for social policy. Geneva: ILO; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindert P. Growing public. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A. The world economy: historical statistics. Paris: OECD; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mares I. The sources of business interest in social insurance: sectoral versus national differences. World Polit. 2003a;55:229–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mares I. The politics of social risk: business and welfare state development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003b.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K. Wage-labor and capital. New York: International Publishers; 2001[1847].

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer A, Richard S. A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ. 1981;89:914–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moene K, Wallerstein M. Inequality, social insurance and redistribution. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2001;95:859–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moss D. When all else fails: government as the ultimate risk manager. Massachusetts: Harvard University Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Leary C, Wander S. Unemployment insurance in the United States: analysis of policy issues. Kalamazoo: W.E. UPJOHN Institute for Employment Research; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Employment outlook 1988. Paris: OECD; 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pampel F, Williamson J. Age, class, politics, and the welfare state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierson C. Beyond the welfare state: the new political economy of welfare. Cambridge: Polity Press; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piore M. Historical perspectives and the interpretation of unemployment. J Econ Lit. 1987;25(4):1834–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi K. The great transformation: the political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon; 2001[1944].

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski A. Capitalism and social democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski A. Economic reforms, public opinions, and political institutions: Poland in the Eastern European perspective. In: Pereira LCB et al., editors. Economic reforms in new democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski A et al. Democracy and development: political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosanvallon P. The new social question: rethinking the welfare state. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein B. Labor-market institutions and working-class strength. In: Steinmo S et al., editors. Structuring politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudra N, Haggard S. Globalization, democracy, and effective welfare spending in the developing world. Comp Polit Stud. 2005;38(9):1015–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J. Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper Torchbooks; 1975[1942].

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A. On inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons B, Elkins Z. The globalization of liberalization: policy diffusion in the international political economy. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2004;98(1):171–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephens J. The transition from capitalism to socialism. Champaign: University of Illinois Press; 1979.

    Google Scholar 

  • Social Security Administration. Social security programs throughout the world. Washington DC: US Government Printing Office; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tang K-L. Social welfare development in East Asia. New York: Palgrave; 2000.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Therborn G. The rule of capital and the rise of democracy. New Left Rev. 1977;103:3–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toft C. State action, trade unions, and voluntary unemployment insurance in Great Britain, Germany, and Scandinavia, 1900–1934. Eur Econ Rev. 1995;39:565–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G. Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walters W. Unemployment and government: geneologies of the social. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Western B. Between class and market: postwar unionization in the capitalist democracies. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Moises Arce, Jen Gandhi, Mark Gasiorowski, Adam Przeworski, Sebas Saiegh, Shanker Satyanah, and Seung Jong Won for their thoughtful comments and discussions on the various aspects of this project and earlier drafts of this paper. I also thank Seung Jong Won for his help in data collection. I am especially indebted to the anonymous reviewers and the editors for their insightful comments and helpful suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wonik Kim.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Table 2 Countries of analysis

Appendix 2. Historical Data on Sectoral Employment

ILO data sets: LABORSTAT (web edition of Yearbook of Labour Statistics, covering from 1969 to 2000). http://laborsta.ilo.org; Yearbook of Labour Statistics. Geneva: ILO. The data before 1969 (the data during the period between 1969 and 2000 are in LABORSTAT) are found only in the printed editions of the Yearbook. The editions used are 1976, 1974, 1968, 1965, 1963, 1960, 1957, 1955, 1949–1950; Yearbook of Labour Statistics: Retrospective Edition on Population Censuses, 1945–89. 1990. Geneva: ILO; Key Indicators of the Labour Market. 2002. Geneva: ILO.

UN and the League of Nations (LON) data sets: Statistical Yearbook 45. 2002. New York: UN. CD-ROM; Statistical Yearbook. New York: UN. The editions used are 1990/1991, 1985/1986, 1982; Statistical Yearbook for Asia and the Pacific/the Far East. Bangkok: Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East). The editions used are 2000, 1990, 1984, 1974, 1968; African Statistical Yearbook. New York: Economic Commission for Africa). The editions used are 1988/1989, 1987, 1985, 1974; Demographic Yearbook 1949–1950. 1950. New York: UN; LON. Statistical Yearbook of the League of Nations. Geneva: LON. The editions used are 1931, 1930, 1929; LON. 1927. International Statistical Yearbook. Geneva: LON.

Other data sets: Flora, Peter et al. 1987. State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 18151975, Vol. II: The Growth of Industrial Societies and Capitalist Economies. London. Macmillan Press; Mitchell, B. R. 1998. International Historical Statistics: Africa, Asia Oceania 17501993; International Historical Statistics: The Americas 1750–1993; International Historical Statistics: Europe 1750–1993. Fourth edition. London: MacMillan; Committee on Latin America Studies. 1959. Statistical Abstract of Latin America for 1957. Los Angeles: University of California; US Department of Commerce. 1975. Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970. DC: Bureau of the Census.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kim, W. Unemployment Risks and the Origins of Unemployment Compensation. St Comp Int Dev 45, 57–82 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-009-9057-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-009-9057-9

Keywords

Navigation