Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Assessing Inequality in the Presence of Growth: an Expository Essay

  • Published:
The Review of Black Political Economy

Abstract

In a great deal of empirical work on distributional analysis, the only sorts of inequality measures employed are ‘relative’ ones. The present paper argues the case for a more plural approach to inequality measurement, in which both ‘absolute’ and ‘intermediate’ conceptualizations of inequality are admitted. In particular, it is suggested that there is a strong case for the employment of intermediate measures of inequality in assessing over time changes in inequality and, through that route, the inclusiveness or otherwise of the process of growth in per capita income. The purpose of the paper is two fold: exposition and persuasion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It should be clarified that there is an alternative dimension in terms of which the relative-absolute distinction is effected in the literature. This dimension is particularly a feature of the so-called ‘ethical’ indices of inequality, which measure inequality as the loss in social welfare occasioned by the presence of inequality. The notion of the ‘equally distributed equivalent income (ede)’—see Atkinson (1970)—is of salience here. Given an increasing and concave social welfare function defined over individual incomes, the ede income is defined as that level of income such that, if it were equally distributed, it would cause aggregate social welfare to be the same as that which obtains under the current (unequal) distribution of income. With a concave social welfare function, the ede income will not exceed the actual mean income of the distribution. An ethical measure of inequality can now be expressed—given the underlying social welfare function one is working with—as the deviation of the ede income from the actual mean income of the distribution under review. (This is the welfare loss due to inequality, measured in equivalent income units.). When the deviation is expressed as a proportion of the mean income, one has a ‘relative’ inequality measure; when the deviation is expressed in absolute terms, one has an ‘absolute’ inequality measure. This is the alternative ‘relative-absolute’ dichotomy that is sometimes invoked in the inequality measurement literature—and is not the dichotomy that constitutes the underlying motivation of the present paper, wherein the distinction turns on the difference between invariance restrictions placed on the inequality measure when the size of the distribution changes.

  2. The reader is referred, in this connection, to the work of Ravallion and Chen (2002), who introduce the notion of the ‘growth incidence curve’, which traces the quantile-specific rate of growth of income for all quantiles into which a distribution is partitioned, and provides a quick and immediate visual impression of whether growth has been more pronounced for the relatively lower or the relatively upper quantiles of the distribution. This is a useful device for effecting a quick assessment of the ‘inclusiveness’ or otherwise of growth, but within an essentially relative framework of analysis which is driven by growth rates rather than absolute growth amounts. The authors also proceed to derive a measure of what they call ‘pro-poor growth’, which requires computation of the average of the rates of growth of poor incomes. This, in turn, requires the specification of a well-defined money-metric poverty line. The present paper is not explicitly concerned with poverty as such: rather, it deals with the merits of relative, absolute, and intermediate conceptualizations of inequality in the dynamic ordering of income distributions in terms of inequality.

  3. Kolm was himself well aware of this. As he puts it [Kolm 1976a; p. 419]: ‘The topic was an equal increase in all incomes rather than an equal decrease in them. But it is the first point which is relevant in our progressive societies. Anyway, all that is said here is that it is no less legitimate to attach the inequality between two incomes to their difference than to their ratio. One view must not be judged from the other’s prejudice. The term “leftist” used below must not be taken too literally: the measure corresponds to this view of society in very important cases, not in all imaginable ones.’

  4. Symmetrically, of course, we would also require of an intermediate inequality measure I that for for all x ∈ X, λ ∈ (0, 1), and t < 0, [I(x) > I(λ x)] and I(x) < I(x + t), where t ≡ (t, …, t) and n(x) = n(t).

  5. For an alternative intermediate version of the Gini coefficient, the reader is referred to Atkinson and Brandolini (2004).

  6. Indeed, Kolm (1976a; p.419) anticipates the issue when he says: ‘When all incomes x i are multiplied by the same number, whereas [a relative inequality measure]… does not change, [an absolute inequality measure]… is multiplied by this number. Therefore, if we study variations of [an absolute inequality measure]… over time in an inflationary country, we must call x i the real incomes, discounted for inflation; or if we make international comparisons of [an absolute inequality measure]…, we must use the correct exchange rates. This need not be done if we use [a relative measure]. But these problems are exactly the same ones which are traditionally encountered in the comparisons of national or per capita incomes, and they can be given the same traditional solutions. Anyway, convenience could not be an alibi for endorsing injustice.’ Moyes (1987) strongly endorses this view of Kolm’s.

  7. This would also be true for any other distribution z. Del Rio and Alonso-Villar (2011) are careful to point out that in order to obtain a consistent inequality ranking of x, y, z,…, the iso-inequality curve employed must be the one drawn for a unique reference distribution, say x: one cannot, for instance, seek a ranking of x, y and z by employing x as the reference distribution for ranking x and y, and x and z, while employing y as the reference distribution for ranking y and z.

  8. Examples of significant empirical work whose conceptual basis is also clearly explained would include Atkinson and Brandolini (2004) and Bosmans et al. (2014) on disparities in the global distribution of income, and Del Rio and Ruiz-Castillo (2000, 2001) on inequality in the Spanish distribution of income.

  9. It should be noted, in Fig. 3, that whether we move directly from the first incremental unit of income to the third unit, or via the second unit, the iso-inequality curve will pass through the point C: this is the property of ‘path-independence’, by which judgements on equal inequalities do not depend on the particular route taken from one distribution to another. This is an important feature of Krtscha’s proposed ‘fair compromise’ procedure.

  10. The properties of sub-group decomposability and unit-consistency are uniquely a feature of a measure derived from allocation of one-half the incremental income to distribution according to existing shares and the other half to equal distribution. The ‘half-and-half’ division is necessary to secure these properties, which are thus special to the Krtscha measure. One generalization of Krtscha which preserves these properties, due to Zheng (2007), relates to the value of the exponential parameter in the expression for the Krtscha measure (see Eq. 3). An alternative route to generalization is based on the notion that the ‘half-and-half division’ is only one special, ‘centrist’, case of a general ‘alpha-and-one-minus-alpha division’, whereby one can have an entire spectrum of ‘left-to-right’ intermediate values of a parameter α which assumes values in the continuum (0,1). This is the route to generalization of Krtscha proposed by Yoshida (2005). (The generalization, however, does not accommodate sub-group decomposability and unit-consistency.)

References

  • Amiel, Y. amd F. A. Cowell. Thinking About Inequality. Distributional Analysis Research Programme: London School of Economics (PWD). 1999. Available at: http://darp.lse.ac.uk/papersdb/amiel_cowell_tai.pdf. (Published 1999: Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.)

  • Atkinson AB. On the measurement of inequality. J Econ Theory. 1970;2(3):244–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B., and A. Brandolini. ‘Global World Inequality: Absolute, Relative or Intermediate?’, paper prepared for the 28th General Conference of the International association for Research in Income and Wealth, Cork, Ireland, August 22–28, 2004. Available at: http://www.iariw.org/papers/2004/brand.pdf .

  • Azpitarte, F., and O. Alsonso-Villar ‘Ray-invariant intermediate inequality measures: a lorenz dominance criterion’, ECINEQ Working paper. 2011;2011–26.

  • Bosmans K, Decancq K, Decoster A. The relativity of decreasing inequality between countries. Economica. 2014;81(322):276–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bossert W, Pfingsten A. Intermediate inequality: concepts, indices and welfare implications. Math Soc Sci. 1990;19(2):117–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty SR, Tyagarupananda S. The sugroup decomposable absolute indices of inequality. In: Chakravarty SR, Coondoo D, Mukherjee R, editors. Quantitative economics: theory and practice, essays in honour of professor N. Bhattacharya. New Delhi: Allied Publishers Limited; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty SR, Tyagarupananda S. The subgroup decomposable intermediate indices of inequality. Span Econ Rev. 2009;11(2):83–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Rio C, Alonso-Villar O. New unit-consistent intermediate inequality indices. Economic Theory. 2010;42(3):505–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Rio C, Alonso-Villar O. Rankings of income distributions: a note on intermediate inequality indices. Vigo: Universidade de; 2011. Available at: http://webs.urigo.es/crio/REI.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Rio C, Ruiz-Castillo J. Intermediate inequality and welfare. Soc Choice Welf. 2000;17(2):223–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Rio C, Ruiz-Castillo J. intermediate inequality and welfare: the case of Spain. Rev Income Wealth. 2001;47(2):221–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayaraj, D., and S. Subramanian. On the interpersonal inclusiveness of India’s consumption expenditure growth. Econ Polit Wkly. 2012;XLVII(45):56–66.

  • Jayaraj D, Subramanian S. On the inter-group inclusiveness of india’s consumption expenditure growth. Econ Polit Wkly. 2013;10:65–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP, Jäntti M. Methods for summarizing and comparing wealth distributions’, ISER Working Paper 2005–05. Colchester: University of Essex, Institute for Social and Economic Research; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolm SC. Unequal inequalities I. J Econ Theory. 1976a;12(3):416–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolm SC. Unequal inequalities II. J Econ Theory. 1976b;13(1):82–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krtscha M. A new compromise measure of inequality. In: Eichhorn W, editor. Models and measurement of welfare and inequality. Heidelberg: Springer; 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moyes P. A new concept of lorenz domination. Econ Lett. 1987;23(2):203–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion M. The debate on globalization, poverty and inequality: why measurement matters. Int Aff. 2003;79(4):739–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion M, Chen S. Measuring pro-poor growth’. Econ Lett. 2002;78(1):93–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks AF. Aggregation issues in inequality measurement. In: Eichhorn W, editor. Measurement in economics: theory and applications in economic indices. Heidelberg: Physica Verlag; 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian, S. ‘Inequality Measurement with Subgroup Decomposability and Level-Sensitivity’, Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal. 2011. Vol. 5, 2011–9. doi:10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-9. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-9.

  • Subramanian, S., and D. Jayaraj. ‘The Evolution of Consumption and Wealth Inequality in India: A Quantitative Assessment’, Journal of Globalization and Development. 2013. (Published Online: 11/29/2013)

  • Yoshida T. Social welfare rankings of income distributions: a new parametric concept of intermediate inequality. Soc Choice Welf. 2005;24(3):557–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng B. Unit-consistent decomposable inequality measures. Economica. 2007;74(293):97–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zoli, C. ‘Characterizing Inequality Equivalence Criteria’, Department of Economics (University of Verona) Working Paper 32. 2012. Available at: http://leonardo3.dse.univr.it/home/workingpapers/IneqEquivRevision20wp20201220VR.pdf.

Download references

Acknowledgments

This is a revised version of a paper which was originally presented at a conference on ‘Inclusive Growth in Africa’ organized by UNU-WIDER, and held in Helsinki, Finland, over September 20th and 21st of 2013. I am grateful to UNU-WIDER for having made the paper possible. Two anonymous referees of the Review have provided elaborate and detailed comments on the paper, going far beyond the normal line of duty. I am genuinely indebted to them for their advice. The usual caveat, of course, applies. I also thank A. Arivazhagan for attending to the graphics in the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to S. Subramanian.

Appendix

Appendix

On the Parabolic Shape of the Krtscha Iso-Inequality Path

Let x = (x 1, x 2) be an unequal, increasingly ordered two-person distribution, with x 1 + x 2 ≡ X, and let y = (y 1, y 2), with y 1 + y 2 ≡ Y be a distribution derived from x through an increase of ∆ in total income from X to Y, so that Y − X = Δ > 0. Imagine now that ∆ is comprised of some K finite and equal increments, so that the rise in total income from X to Y is seen to be composed of a sequence of transitions from one distribution to another. These transitions are supposed to preserve inequality, and are of the following nature: from x to x 1 ≡ (x 11 , x 12 ) (with \( {x}_1^1+{x}_2^1\equiv {X}_1=X+\frac{\varDelta }{K} \)); from x 1 to x 2 ≡ (x 21 , x 22 ) (with \( {x}_1^2+{x}_2^2\equiv {X}_2={X}_1+\frac{\varDelta }{\operatorname{K}} \));… and from x K − 1 to x K ≡ (x K1 , x K2 ), with \( {x}_1^{\mathrm{K}}+{x}_2^{\mathrm{K}}\equiv Y={X}_{\operatorname{K}-1}+\frac{\varDelta }{\operatorname{K}} \). Note further that each income vector is required to be derived from the preceding income vector by distributing one-half the incremental total income \( \frac{\varDelta }{\operatorname{K}} \) in the proportions as they obtain in the preceding vector, and the other one-half equally between the two persons. The vectors x, x 1, x 2, …, x K − 1, x K are points on the Krtscha iso-inequality curve. Given how x 1 is derived from x, we can write:

$$ {x}_1^1={x}_1+\left(\frac{1}{2}\right)\left(\frac{x_1}{X}\right)\left(\frac{\varDelta }{K}\right)+\left(\frac{1}{2}\right)\left(\frac{\varDelta }{2K}\right)=\left(\frac{1}{4 KX}\right)\left(4 KX{x}_1+2\varDelta {x}_1+\varDelta X\right). $$

It follows then that the difference between the income-share of the poorer person in distribution x 1 and his income-share in distribution x is given by

$$ {\delta}_1\equiv \frac{x_1^1}{X_1}-\frac{x_1}{X}=\left(\frac{1}{4 KX\left( KX+\varDelta \right)}\right)\left(4K\mathrm{X}{x}_1+2\varDelta {x}_1+\varDelta X\right)-\left(\frac{x_1}{X}\right) $$
(A1)

It can be verified that the right hand side of Eq. (A2) simplifies to the following expression:

$$ {\delta}_1=\left(\frac{\varDelta }{4X\left(K\mathrm{X}+\varDelta \right)}\right)\left({x}_2-{x}_1\right)>0\ \mathrm{since},\mathrm{by}\ \mathrm{definition}\kern1em {x}_2>{x}_1. $$
(A2)

Defining δ 2,…,δ K analogously to δ 1, we can prove, exactly along the lines just demonstrated, that δ k  > 0 for all k = 2, …, K. That is to say, in order to preserve the level of inequality, the income-share of the poorer person has to keep increasing with every successive increment of income. This is the same thing as saying that the Krtscha iso-inequality locus will, in the limit, veer toward the ‘equal division’ outcome as income increases. Hence the parabolic shape of the locus, as featured in Fig. 3 in the text.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Subramanian, S. Assessing Inequality in the Presence of Growth: an Expository Essay. Rev Black Polit Econ 42, 179–199 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12114-014-9189-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12114-014-9189-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation