Skip to main content
Log in

Regional differences in childcare environment, urbanization, and fertility decline

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Letters in Spatial and Resource Sciences Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We theoretically demonstrate that a decline in an economy’s total fertility rate occurs with urbanization. If there are no regional differences in fertility rates, the decline in the economy’s total fertility rate should be explained by a decrease in the number of children per woman. However, if there are regional differences in fertility rates, urbanization can depress the economy’s total fertility rate even if the number of children per woman does not decline due to urbanization. We construct an overlapping generations model with two regions (u and r). Region u has a lower fertility rate, but its higher wage keeps attracting more workers who will be parents. Since the economy’s total fertility rate is the weighted sum of the low fertility rate in region u and the high fertility rate in region r, urbanization and a decline in the economy’s total fertility rate are observed simultaneously, even if urbanization does not change the regional fertility rates. An implication for population policies aimed at increasing the economy’s total fertility rate is provided. Such policies must not only focus on increasing the fertility rate in each region, but also consider migration to regions with lower (higher) fertility rates.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Day (2016), Galor and Weil (1996, 1999), Galor and Weil (2000), Yakita (2018), Ohinata and Varvarigos (2020).

  2. The urbanization rate in a country is the ratio of the population in urban areas to the total population of the country.

  3. World Bank Open Data: https://data.worldbank.org/

  4. This model is an extension of the model of Hashimoto and Naito (2021), in which the provision of public childcare facilities and taxation are not explicitly considered.

  5. For regional differences in the waitlisted children issue, see Hashimoto and Naito (2021). As for the term “waitlisted children”, please see the following website: https://www.mhlw.go.jp/english/org/pamphlet/dl/serviceguide2022.pdf

  6. In general, there are two types of parents: those who do not want to use childcare facilities, and those who want to work part- or full-time and they would like to use childcare facilities. This model only considers the latter.

  7. If the assigned childcare facility does not support the work schedules of parents, they will be forced to significantly reduce their working time when they have children. Childcare facilities are less useful for parents when they open late, close early, or frequently call parents for various reasons.

  8. Restriction \(p_t > 0\) is valid. In reality, there are mismatches in the location of childcare facilities and the content of the services provided. Therefore, an increase in childcare facilities does not always alleviate the problem of waitlisted children. Kawabata (2014) presented an empirical study on location mismatches.

  9. We assume that \([p_t+(1-p_t)\mu ]zn_t^u <1\) is true. This ensures that the left side of (2) is positive, and it provides an upper bound for \(n_t^u>0\). \({\bar{z}}<1/ n_t^r\) is also assumed for \(s_t^r >0\). All of these restrictions and assumptions are attributed to a fundamental assumption that one unit of time endowed to each individual cannot be lent or borrowed between individuals.

  10. \(\lambda >0\) reflects the efficiency of the government’s provision of childcare facilities. The childcare facilities and capital stock are assumed to depreciate perfectly within a period.

  11. The sufficient condition for \(p_t < 1\) to hold for a given \(k_t\) gives the lower bound for capital/labor ratio in region u as follows: \((\lambda A (1-\gamma )^{1-\alpha } \tau )^\frac{-1}{\alpha } < \frac{k_t}{\phi _t}\),

  12. Appendix A provides the derivation of (16).

  13. The condition for \(p_t <1\) given in footnote 11 is revised in equilibrium as follows: \((\lambda A \left( 1-\gamma \right) ^{1-\alpha } \tau )^\frac{-1}{\alpha } < {{\bar{k}}}(\tau )\).

  14. See Appendix B.

  15. Although this is similar to Fig. 4 in Hashimoto and Naito (2021), the shift parameter of the graph in Fig. 4 in Hashimoto and Naito (2021) is the standby probability given exogenously.

  16. Notably, this model intentionally excludes the well-known channel through which wage rates and fertility are linked, although this link has been persuasively shown both theoretically and empirically in the literature.

References

Download references

Acknowledgements

The previous version of this paper was presented at the 69th Annual Meeting of North American Regional Science Council of the RSAI held in Montreal 2022 and the 62nd Annual Meeting of the Southern Regional Science Association held in Savannah 2023. We are grateful to John Winters and Akiko Sakanishi for helpful comments and discussions in these meetings. We also wish to the editor and the anonymous reviewers for comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiroyuki Hashimoto.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Derivation of (16)

Substituting (11) and (12) into (15), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\phi _{t}}{k_{t}}=\left\{ \frac{b}{(1-\tau )(1-\alpha )(1-\sigma )^{-\alpha }(1-\gamma )^{-\alpha }(1-\sigma )^{\frac{1}{1-\gamma }}}\left( \frac{1}{\mu }\right) ^{\frac{\gamma }{1-\gamma }}\left[ \mu +(1-\mu )p_{t} \right] ^{\frac{\gamma }{1-\gamma }}\right\} ^{\frac{-1}{\alpha }} \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Considering that \(p_t\) in (A.1) is a function of \(\frac{\phi _t}{k_t}\) as in (14), the derivative of \(\phi _t\) with respect to \(k_t\) is obtained as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\phi _{t}}{d k_{t}}=\frac{\phi _{t}}{k_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

Using the implicit function theorem for the case \(\frac{\phi _t}{k_t}>0\), \(\phi _t\) can be expressed as a function of \(k_t\):

$$\begin{aligned} \phi _t=\Phi (k_t;\tau ). \end{aligned}$$

Then, the integration of (A.2) shows that \(\phi _t\) is a linear function of \(k_t\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} \phi _t=\Omega (\tau ) k_t. \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Omega (\tau )\) is characterized by the parameters in (A.1).

Proof of convexity of \(\Psi _1\)

Considering that \(s^u_t\) and \(s^r\) are constant, as in (28) and (30), and differentiating (26) with respect to \(k_t\), we derive

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dk_{t+1}}{dk_t}=\frac{1}{m_t^2}\left\{ \frac{\partial \phi _t}{\partial k_t} (s_t^u-s^r) m_t -\left[ \phi _ts_t^u+(1-\phi _t)s^r \right] \frac{\partial m_t}{\partial k_t} \right\} >0. \end{aligned}$$
(B.1)

As \((s_t^u-s^r)\) is positive and \(\frac{\partial m_t}{\partial k_t}\) is negative, the sign of (B.1) is strictly positive. Moreover, differentiating (B.1) with respect to \(k_t\) yields the following derivative:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^2k_{t+1}}{dk_t^2}=-2\frac{1}{m_t^3} \frac{\partial m_t}{\partial k_t} \left\{ \frac{\partial \phi _t}{\partial k_t} (s_t^u-s^r) m_t -\left[ \phi _ts_t^u+(1-\phi _t)s^r \right] \frac{\partial m_t}{\partial k_t} \right\} >0. \end{aligned}$$
(B.2)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hashimoto, H., Naito, T. Regional differences in childcare environment, urbanization, and fertility decline. Lett Spat Resour Sci 17, 8 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12076-024-00369-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12076-024-00369-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation