Appendix 1
An example
The methods are best illustrated through an example. In the case of Saudi Arabia, gasoline demand in 2010 totalled roughly 24,165,966,000 liters (IEA 2016a), while the average fuel economy of the total stock of passenger cars was 8.387 kilometers per liter. Multiplying gasoline consumption by the average fuel economy yields the total demand for driving in gasoline-vehicles in Saudi Arabia in 2010:
$$ {S}_0=\eta {E}_0=8.387\ast \mathrm{24,165,966,000}=\mathrm{202,679,956,842}\ vkt $$
(A.1)
According to the World Bank (2016), the price of gasoline in Saudi Arabia in 2010 was 16.0 cents per liter. The implicit price of driving was then calculated to be \( \frac{16.0}{8.387}=1.908 \) cents per kilometer in that year.
Given the total demand for driving and the implicit price of driving, the scale parameter can be calibrated. This however requires an assumption on the size of the elasticity \( {\varepsilon}_{S,{P}_S} \), also denoted by β, which reflects the size of the direct rebound effect. According to Dahl (2012), the gasoline price elasticity in Saudi Arabia is \( {\varepsilon}_{E,{P}_E}=-0.1 \). If the Saudi road sector is described as single-energy single-service, then \( {\varepsilon}_{S,{P}_S}={\varepsilon}_{E,{P}_E}=-0.1 \). Therefore,
$$ K=\frac{S_0}{{P_{S,B}}^{\beta }}=\frac{\mathrm{202,679,956,842}}{1.908^{-0.1}}=\mathrm{216,206,447,130} $$
(A.2)
Calculating the benefits
If a 10% improvement in energy efficiency occurred, the implicit price of driving would fall to \( \frac{16.0}{9.226}=1.734 \) cents per kilometer. We can then calculate the total surplus gained by consumers because of this 10% improvement:
$$ {B}_{CS}={\frac{K}{\beta +1}}^{\ast}\left[{P_{S,B}}^{\beta +1}-{P_{S,A}}^{\beta +1}\right]={\frac{216,206,447,130}{0.9}}^{\ast}\left({1.908}^{0.9}-{1.734}^{0.9}\right)=\$354,327,680 $$
(A.3)
Part of this gain is due to the monetary savings:
$$ {B}_{MS}=\left({P}_{S,B}-{P}_{S,A}\right)\ast {S}_0=\left(1.908-1.734\right)\ast 202,679,956,842=\$352,663,125 $$
(A.4)
The other part is due to the direct rebound effect:
$$ {B}_R={B}_{CS}-{B}_{MS}=\left(\$\mathrm{354,327,680}-\$\mathrm{352,663,125}\right)=\$\mathrm{1,664,555} $$
(A.5)
Thus, the consumer surplus gained from the direct rebound effect would have been about half a percent of the total gain in consumer surplus. This is not surprising given that the elasticity in this example was small. For larger elasticities, the portion of consumer surplus gained from rebound rises considerably.
The final benefit of improved energy efficiency stems from the reduction in external costs through reduced gasoline demand, assuming no rebound. The IMF (2016) data shows that the external costs of GHG emissions and air pollution associated with each liter of gasoline consumption in Saudi Arabia were 8.3 and 2.5 cents per liter, respectively (δE = 10.8 cents per liter). Assuming no rebound, a 10% improvement in energy efficiency would have reduced gasoline demand in Saudi Arabia to \( \frac{\mathrm{24,165,966,000}}{\left(1+10\%\right)}=\mathrm{21,969,060,000} \) liters. Thus,
$$ {B}_{EC}=\left({E}_0-{E}_{NR}\right)\ast {\delta}_E=\left(24,165,966,000-21,969,060,000\right)\ast 10.8=\$237,265,848 $$
(A.6)
In summary, a 10% improvement in the energy efficiency of gasoline-based cars in Saudi Arabia would have yielded a total benefit of:
$$ {B}_{EE}={B}_{MS}+{B}_R+{B}_{EC}=\$\mathrm{591,593,528} $$
(A.7)
Calculating the costs
When rebound occurs, both the demand for gasoline and driving increase. With an elasticity of β = − 0.1, the rebound effect would cause the demand for driving to rise from 202,679,956,842 to:
$$ {S}_R=K{P_{S,A}}^{-0.1}=\mathrm{216,206,447,130}\ast {1.734}^{-0.1}=\mathrm{204,627,373,960}\ vkt $$
(A.8)
The gasoline consumption associated with this new level of driving is obtained as follows:
$$ {E}_R=\frac{S_R}{\eta \ast \left(1+10\%\right)}=\frac{\mathrm{204,627,373,960}\ }{8.387\ast 1.1}=\mathrm{22,180,146,109}\ \mathrm{liters} $$
(A.9)
According to the IMF (2016), the external costs of air pollution and GHG emissions are δE = 10.8. The increase in energy-related external costs can thus be calculated as follows:
$$ {C}_E=\left({E}_R-{E}_{NR}\right)\ast {\delta}_E=\left(22,180,146,109-21,969,060,000\right)\ast 10.8=\$22,797,300 $$
(A.10)
According to the IMF (2016), the external costs of congestion and accidents associated with each kilometer of driving in Saudi Arabia were 4.9 and 6.6 cents per kilometer (δS = 11.5 cents per kilometer). The increase in service-related external costs can thus be calculated as follows:
$$ {C}_S=\left({S}_R-{S}_0\right)\ast {\delta}_S=\left(204,627,373,960-202,679,956,842\right)\ast 11.5=\$223,952,968 $$
(A.11)
The total cost associated with the direct rebound effect is the sum of the energy- and service-related external costs:
$$ {C}_R={C}_E+{C}_S=\$\mathrm{246,750,268} $$
(A.12)
Assuming zero capital costs, the total cost of the improvement is equal to the total cost of the direct rebound effect:
$$ {C}_{EE}={C}_R=\$\mathrm{246,750,268} $$
(A.13)
At this point, we can produce preliminary estimates of the benefit-to-cost ratio for both the direct rebound effect and the energy efficiency improvement. But these estimates would not account for the impact on the government, which may subsidize or tax gasoline. In the case of Saudi Arabia, an energy efficiency improvement will lead to a net gain for the government so long as the direct rebound effect is less than 100%, since any fall in gasoline consumption will lead to a fall in the implicit subsidy for gasoline. According to Platts (2016), the average international market price for gasoline at Jebel Ali port in 2010 was 54.1 cents per liter, compared to a domestic price of 16.0. Therefore, the total gain to the government because of the 10% energy efficiency improvement was:
$$ {G}_{EE}=\left({P_E}^{\ast }-{P}_E\right)\ast \left({E}_0-{E}_R\right)=\left(54.1-16.0\right)\ast \left(24,165,966,000-22,180,146,109\ \right)=\$756,597,379 $$
(A.14)
It is possible to isolate the part of this gain that is purely due to the direct rebound effect. In the case of Saudi Arabia, the direct rebound effect causes a loss to the government as it increases gasoline consumption above a scenario in which there was no rebound. This loss can be calculated as follows:
$$ {G}_R=\left({P_E}^{\ast }-{P}_E\right)\ast \left({E}_{NR}-{E}_R\right)=\left(54.1-16.0\right)\ast \left(21,969,060,000-22,180,146,109\ \right)=-\$80,423,808 $$
(A.15)
The minus sign indicates that the rebound effect leads to a loss for the government.
Benefit-to-cost ratios
With all the necessary components calculated, we can proceed to estimating the benefit-to-cost ratio for the direct rebound effect,
$$ {BCR}_R=\frac{B_R}{C_R-{G}_R}=\frac{\$\mathrm{1,664,555}}{\$\mathrm{246,750,268}+\$\mathrm{80,423,808}}=0.005 $$
(A.16)
Given that the direct rebound effect leads to a cost for the government, GR is placed in the denominator of Eq. (A.16).
In the case of the energy efficiency improvement,
$$ {BCR}_{EE}=\frac{B_{EE}+{G}_{EE}}{C_{EE}}=\frac{\$\mathrm{591,593,528}+\$\mathrm{756,597,379}}{\$\mathrm{246,750,268}}=5.47 $$
(A.17)
Given that energy efficiency leads to a net gain for the government, GEE is placed in the numerator of Eq. (A.17). Thus, the benefit-to-cost ratio reveals that the benefits of a free energy efficiency improvement are considerably larger than the costs, even when accounting for the negative welfare reduction caused by the direct rebound effect.
Appendix 2
The potential welfare implications of the direct rebound effect in other energy services
An improvement in the efficiency of lighting or cooling for example would give rise to a rebound effect that generates external costs in air pollution and GHG emissions only (there may be some other minor external costs). We can roughly approximate the potential welfare implications of such an improvement by setting the external costs of congestion and accidents to zero and then re-estimating the benefit-to-cost ratio of the direct rebound effect.
In the case of driving, most of the cost associated with the direct rebound effect is due to congestion and accidents. According to Parry et al. (2014), the average external cost of air pollution and GHG emissions together was 10.7 US cents per liter, while the average external cost of congestion and accidents amounted to 43.5 US cents per liter (both averages taken across all 100 countries for 2010). Service-related externalities thus accounted for over 80% of the total cost of the direct rebound effect in driving.
Table 3 presents the welfare results from an analysis of the direct rebound where congestion and accident external costs are set to zero. This leaves behind only the air pollution and GHG emissions costs in the analysis. Of course, the external costs associated with air pollution and GHG emissions from burning a liter of gasoline in a car differ from the external costs associated with burning natural gas or coal to produce electricity. Nevertheless, we maintain the same fuel-related external costs just to show rough, indicative results of what the welfare outcomes might be for other energy services.
Table 3 The benefit-to-cost ratio of the direct rebound effect following a 10% energy efficiency improvement, assuming zero service-related external costs Table 3 reveals welfare enhancing direct rebound effects in most cases, given that the costs associated with direct rebound are considerably lower than before. This suggests that there may be a need to review the conventional wisdom that rebound is a negative phenomenon that requires mitigation. In fact, such welfare enhancing rebound effects may help improve the welfare outcomes of energy efficiency when accounted for, thus making energy efficiency more attractive to policymakers.
On a final note, we must emphasize that these results are suggestive. To accurately quantify the welfare implications of the direct rebound effect in energy services such as cooling and lighting, a different empirical framework would be needed. First, a demand curve for each energy service would need to be estimated and calibrated. Second, the external costs associated with the energy service would need to be estimated for each country. Nevertheless, the results in Table 3 suggest a pathway for future empirical research in this area.