1 Introduction

Government agencies regularly alter and pass new regulations that companies must comply with. This leaves the entire business sector in a continual state of uncertainty as to if, when, and how new economic policy proposals will be signed into law. Uncertainty alone can lead to serious economic repercussions (Bloom 2009) by, among other things, depressing corporate investment activities (e.g., Kang et al. 2014; Baker et al. 2016). Real options theory attempts to explain such behavior by the desire of corporate managers to avoid costly mistakes. By postponing part of their investment projects, perhaps even indefinitely, managers try to wait until the uncertainty is removed and more informed decisions can be made (Bernanke 1983; McDonald and Siegel 1986; Ingersoll and Ross 1992; Dixit and Pindyck 1994).

In light of the sharp rise of policy-related uncertainty in Europe—heavily fueled by Britain’s withdrawal from the European Union—we seek to advance this debate by investigating cross-sectional differences in the investment sensitivity of public and private European firms to Baker et al. (2016) Economic Policy Uncertainty (EPU) index. Despite private firms typically accounting for the largest share of a country’s GDP (see Giannetti 2003), most of the empirical literature on uncertainty focuses exclusively on publicly listed firms (e.g., Gulen and Ion 2016; Kim and Kung 2017). However, private companies are fundamentally different from their public counterparts. They must comply with different legal requirements and operate under different ownership structures. Such fundamental differences can lead to diverging investment sensitivities to growth opportunities (Mortal and Reisel 2013; Asker et al. 2015; Gilje and Taillard 2016) and may thus also lead to contrasting investment decisions under uncertainty. Therefore, we are convinced that including private firms in our analysis and exploring possible differences between the two types of firms represents a more comprehensive and appropriate approach to gauge the actual impact of policy uncertainty on corporate investment.

The goal of this paper is threefold. First, we analyze whether EPU can depress investment decisions of private firms. Second, we examine whether there are significant differences in the investment sensitivity of public and private firms to EPU. Third, do public and private firms invest more efficiently in times of policy-related uncertainty?

Our firm-level analysis is based on a dataset containing financial information on a large set of public and private European firms from nine countries between 2009 and 2017. Firm-level information comes from the Amadeus Database by Bureau van Dijk.

To preview our results, we find a negative contemporaneous relation between private firms’ fixed asset investment and uncertainty surrounding future economic policy decisions. This result withstands a range of sensitivity tests, including specifications aimed at eliminating potential endogeneity concerns and alternative sample selection criteria. It shows that the theoretical prediction of real options theory, which aims to capture the value of managers’ temporal flexibility—independent of their work domain—seems to apply not only to public but also to private firms. Moreover, we demonstrate that the impact of EPU on investment is not felt equally by all firms. Public firms reduce their investments by about 50% more than private firms in response to an increase in policy-related uncertainty. We find suggestive evidence that this cross-sectional heterogeneity can be attributed to public firms’ management being typically subject to greater scrutiny and myopic pressure from their shareholders than private firms’ management (e.g., Asker et al. 2015; Gao et al. 2017). Specifically, we show that increases in shareholder power, transparency requirements, and liability standards are associated with fewer investments under uncertainty. This indicates that managers under higher shareholder scrutiny are likely to anticipate more severe negative consequences in the event of poor investment decisions, which fosters a larger degree of uncertainty averse decisions.

There are at least three possible explanations for why private European firms should face a lower baseline level of shareholder scrutiny in comparison to their public counterparts.

First, private firms are often managed by the major shareholder (founder) (see Asker et al. 2015), making it impossible to veto or fire the CEO. In contrast, CEOs of public firms act as mere agents of shareholders, leaving them principally vulnerable to being fired. In fact, Fisman et al. (2014) note that public shareholders are prone to call for the CEO’s dismissal when short-term performance deteriorates, even if such events are entirely outside the CEO’s control. Unsurprisingly, public firms display higher CEO turnover rates and have greater CEO and top management turnover-performance sensitivities than private firms (Lel et al. 2014; Gao et al. 2017).

Second, unlike private firms, public firms are obligated to hold an annual ordinary shareholders’ meeting at which management is subject to open examination by their shareholders.

Third, while European law obliges private firms to report annual financial statements, public listed firms face even stricter disclosure requirements based on the Transparency Directive 2004/109/EC and country-specific stock exchange rules. The Transparency Directive, which was modified in 2013 by Directive 2013/50/EU, requires, among other things, the publication of half-yearly financial reports.Footnote 1 As a result, public firm managers should increasingly be aware of the ease and frequency with which shareholders can identify poor investment decisions.

In light of these differences, we expect public firm managers to cut their investments more acutely than private firm managers in times of uncertainty, as they should be even more concerned about having to account for their investment mistakes or getting laid off because of them.

As to whether public and private firms invest more efficiently in periods of uncertainty, our findings suggest that only public firms adapt to these changing circumstances. We find that in response to increases in policy-related uncertainty, public firms invest relatively more in high yielding projects. In comparison, the consolidated investments of private firms do not predict a significant increase in relative profitability when faced with uncertainty. Although insightful, these findings do not necessarily permit the conclusion that being publicly listed is the superior form of organization to adequately cope with spells of uncertainty. This is because private firms, unlike public ones, could (theoretically) always invest in the most efficient manner and therefore simply cannot invest even more efficiently in uncertain times.

From a time-series point of view, we observe that EPU negatively affects the investment activities of both public and private firms for an approximate duration of two years. After this period the negative impact begins to subside and will even turn positive for public firms. It is conceivable that this cross-sectional variation in recovery responses several years after the initial shock might be connected to the idiosyncratic increase in investment profitability rates in uncertain times. This could encourage public firms to pursue new investments at a higher rate than before. As far as private firms are concerned, their inability to identify the projects that would justify immediate implementation the most potentially leads them to refrain from offsetting the initial investment decline in later periods.

Our paper contributes to the general literature on real options theory (e.g., Schwartz and Trigeorgis 2004; Grenadier and Malenko 2010). We show that the organizational form of a firm—public listed or private—is of critical importance in assessing the impact of policy-related uncertainty on corporate investment decisions. Having identified differences in the degree of shareholder scrutiny as a plausible explanation for this finding, this study contributes to the works of Baker et al. (2016), Gulen and Ion (2016), and Kim and Kung (2017) in demonstrating that the link between EPU and investment is not just a function of government dependencies or the degree of investment irreversibility. Thus, this study underscores the role of investor protection laws (La Porta et al. 1998, 2006; Djankov et al. 2008) in periods of uncertainty.

Assuming private firms do not always invest in the most efficient way possible, our results support the policy implication that if they were to adopt the decision-making processes of public companies in uncertain times, this could help them prioritize those projects that most warrant immediate implementation. Thus, when confronted with uncertainty, private firm decision-makers should be more transparent about their planned investments and actively seek and incorporate feedback from their peers.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the data and sampling methods used in the study. Section 3 details our empirical results, starting with the analysis of the relationship between policy-related uncertainty and private firms’ investments. This is followed by the examination of cross-sectional differences between the investment sensitivities of public and private firms to uncertainty and the channel that serves to explain their heterogeneous responses. Section 4 tests whether public and private firms invest more efficiently in periods of uncertainty. Section 5 analyzes the link between policy-related uncertainty and investment over time. Section 6 contains robustness tests. Section 7 concludes.

2 Data

Our dataset comprises firms from nine European countries covering the period 2009 to 2017. We obtain firm-level fundamentals from the Amadeus Database by Bureau van Dijk. Amadeus provides accounting data for a set of public and private European firms. These data are available because European law obligates private firms to disclose annual financial reports. Public firms face even stricter disclosure requirements.

The focus of this study is to analyze the effect of economic policy uncertainty on corporate investment. However, the Amadeus Database does not report any investment measure such as capital expenditures. For this reason, we follow Asker et al. (2015) and define Investment as the annual change in total fixed assets scaled by beginning-of-year total assets. To capture the impact of uncertainty related to future economic policies, the firm-level data are complemented by Baker et al.’s (2016) EPU index.

2.1 Economic policy uncertainty

As of January 2020, the website www.policyuncertainty.com provides policy uncertainty measures for ten European countries based on the methodology of Baker et al. (2016). Separate monthly policy uncertainty indexes are created for France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom by Baker et al. (2016). Additionally, the same index has been calculated for Greece by Fountas et al. (2018), for Ireland by Zalla (2017), for the Netherlands by Kroese et al. (2015), and for Sweden by Armelius et al. (2017). A policy uncertainty index is also available for Russia, but following Giannetti (2003) and Mortal and Reisel (2013), we exclude firms from Eastern European countries from our sample due to insufficient data availability in the Amadeus Database. Thus, our empirical analysis is limited to nine European countries.

To measure economic policy uncertainty, newspaper articles are: (1) counted that include keywords regarding: policy, economic, and uncertainty; and (2) set in proportion to the total count of articles publicized by the corresponding newspaper outlet in the same month. The list of keywords varies from country to country depending on the native language and regional peculiarities. The index draws on leading newspapers in individual countries, e.g. Le Monde in France or Financial Times in the U.K. To generate an index at the country-level, “[...] each monthly newspaper-level series [is standardized] to unit standard deviation [...] and [averaged] across the papers by month” (Baker et al. 2016, p. 1599) before being normalized to an average value of 100 prior to 2011.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Economic Policy Uncertainty in the U.K

Figure 1 shows the monthly time-series of the economic policy uncertainty index for the U.K. As expected, Fig. 1 illustrates that the highest values are achieved around the Brexit referendum. This observation supports the assumption that the index is a reliable indicator of economic policy-related uncertainty. Regardless of this meaningful observation, Baker et al. (2016) also conduct several formal tests to ensure that their measure adequately captures the uncertainty pertaining to future economic policies. Besides, Fig. 1 shows that the time-series does not only indicate rare events—such as elections or referendums—but also exhibits substantial fluctuations over the entire sample period.

2.2 Control variables

On firm-level, we control for growth opportunities, cash flow, and size in all regressions. The investment literature typically uses Tobin’s q or sales growth as a measure of growth opportunities. Tobin’s q is commonly defined as the ratio between the market value of the company and the book value of its assets. However, the market values of private firms cannot be determined as they are not listed on a stock exchange. Therefore, similar to Mortal and Reisel (2013) and Gilje and Taillard (2016), we utilize sales growth as an alternative measure of growth opportunities because it can be calculated for both types of firms. Sales growth is calculated as the change in the firm’s turnover scaled by the turnover of the previous year.

Cash flow is reported in the Amadeus Database for all firms. For our analysis, the cash flow variable is scaled by beginning-of-year total assets. We measure the size of a company by the natural logarithm of its total assets. To account for the macroeconomic environment in a country, we include the annual GDP growth and inflation rate as provided by the World Bank as additional control variables.

Although we rely on the classic corporate finance literature to select firm-level control variables (e.g., Mortal and Reisel 2013; Foucault and Fresard 2014), we recognize that our list of controls is not exhaustive. For example, prior empirical studies find that a firm’s payout policy influences its investment behavior (Almeida et al. 2016; Wang et al. 2021) while being significantly correlated with Baker et al.’s (2016) EPU index (Smietanka et al. 2018; Pirgaip and Dinçergök 2019; Attig et al. 2021; Anolick et al. 2021). Unfortunately, information about private companies’ payout policies is not available. As a consequence, we must be conservative in the causal interpretation of our results.

2.3 Sample construction

Our sample covers the period 2009–2017. We classify firms into public listed and private firms. The Amadeus Database includes an identifier that indicates the listing status of every company. However, this identifier only provides information on the contemporaneous listing status and does not contain historical information. Therefore, we supplement this variable by extracting information on initial public offering (IPO) and delisting dates from the Osiris dataset by Bureau van Dijk. This allows us to elicit the annual listing and delisting status of every company in our sample. Consequently, a firm-year is indicated as ‘listed’ if the firm is quoted on a stock exchange in a given year and was reported to be unlisted prior to its IPO. Likewise, a firm-year is classified as ‘unlisted’ if the firm is not quoted on a stock exchange in a given year and was reported to be listed prior to its delisting. In line with Mortal and Reisel (2013), we classify private firms by their legal form as indicated in the dataset and exclude from our sample cooperatives, foreign companies, foundations, government enterprises, sole proprietorships, and unlimited partnerships.

In a manner similar to Baker et al. (2003) and McLean and Zhao (2014), we omit firm-years with total assets less than 10 million euros to reduce undue effects of small businesses. In addition, we exclude financial and (regulsated) utility firms from our sample—that is, firms with a one-digit SIC code of six and a two-digit SIC code of 49. All firm-level variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% level in order to mitigate the impact of outliers.

In a last step, we drop all firm-year observations with missing data for Investment, Sales growth, Cash flow, or Size. These filters result in 291,415 private firm-year observations. The number of private firm-year observations is substantially larger than the number of public listed firm-year observations. They only amount to 4.5% of the private firm-year observations. Table 1 shows that the full sample covers 56,802 unique private firms and only 2,301 unique public listed firms.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

There are large differences between the public listed and private firm samples, especially with regard to their total assets. The average public firm has about 22 times more assets than the average private firm. To improve the comparability of these samples, we follow (Gilje and Taillard 2016) and try to find for every public company the private company that is most similar in terms of total assets in the same industry, country, and year. In those cases where there is no suitable match in the same industry and country with an overall similar asset amount for a public firm in the year of entering the sample, we attempt to find a match in the following year. Matched private and public listed firms stay in the sample for the entire duration of the public firm’s existence. In the event that a matched private firm stops existing, we try to identify a new match for the public firm during the exact same year, thus ensuring that the public firm will continue to belong to the matched sample. Similar to Asker et al. (2015) and Gilje and Taillard (2016), our matching procedure is based on replacements, allowing us to take within-firm effects into account in our analyses. To the degree that large private firms behave more like public firms, this matching procedure has the potential to bias the estimates towards detecting no differences between them.

The determined matched sample includes 18,912 firm-year observations. It comprises 2238 unique private firms and 1786 unique public listed firms. The difference in total assets reduces dramatically. In the full sample, the average public listed firm has about 22 times more assets than the average private firm. In the matched sample, the average public firm has only 1.6 times more assets than the average private firm.

For our matching procedure, we apply a caliper of 0.05 on the maximum total asset difference and use three-digit SIC industries. In Table 11 in the Appendix, we show that our results are robust to using other calipers (\(\pm \, 0.04\)), two-digit SIC, or four-digit NAICS industries.

Table 2 presents country-specific summary statistics for our main macroeconomic variables. As expected—due to the Brexit referendum—the country with the highest average EPU index in our sampling period is the U.K. The Netherlands and Sweden have the lowest mean EPU scores and are therefore the countries least affected by economic policy uncertainty in our sample. The mean values of GDP growth and Inflation are relatively similar across all nine European countries. The average GDP growth ranges between 0.184% and 2.696%. There are only two outliers: Ireland (6.657%) and Greece (− 2.942%). Both countries were heavily affected by the euro crisis in the late 2000s, but starting in 2012 the Irish economy began to recover significantly. The average Inflation varies from 0.307% in Spain to 1.666% in the U.K. Only Greece has a slightly negative average Inflation of − 0.384%.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics by country

3 The relationship between policy uncertainty and public and private firms’ investment decisions

We begin our empirical analysis by estimating whether private firms’ fixed asset investments are sensitive to changes in economic policy uncertainty. The existing empirical literature finds a negative link between policy-related uncertainty and the investment decisions of public firms (e.g. Kang et al. 2014; Gulen and Ion 2016; Baker et al. 2016). However, because private firms differ fundamentally from their public counterparts in terms of their legal requirements or ownership structures, we cannot draw reliable conclusions about private firms’ investment sensitivity to EPU based purely on public firm results. Mortal and Reisel (2013), Asker et al. (2015), and Gilje and Taillard (2016), for example, show that public and private firms adjust their investments very differently to changing economic circumstances; the same may thus also apply in times of economic policy uncertainty. Therefore, we run the following regression model for our sample of only private European firms:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} Investment_{i,t}&= \alpha _{i} + \alpha _{t} + \beta _{1} \ log(EPU_{j,t}) + \beta _{2} \ SG_{i,t} + \beta _{3} \ CF_{i,t}\\&\quad + \beta _{4} \ Size_{i,t} + \beta _{5} \ GDP\ growth_{j,t} + \beta _{6} \ Inflation_{j,t} + \epsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where i indexes firms, t indexes years, and j denotes countries. The dependent variable, Investment, is the annual change in total fixed assets scaled by beginning-of-year total assets. The variables \(\alpha _{i}\) and \(\alpha _{t}\) are firm and year fixed effects, respectively. Our independent variable of interest is log(EPU). It is the natural logarithm of Baker et al. (2016) economic policy uncertainty measure. SG stands for sales growth and it captures the change in the firm’s turnover scaled by the turnover of the previous year. CF is cash flow, which is scaled by beginning-of-year total assets. Firm Size is captured by the natural logarithm of total assets. GDP growth is the annual percentage change in GDP and Inflation is measured by the annual GDP deflator. In all regressions reported, standard errors are double clustered at the firm- and year-level.

In line with previous literature, regression 1 in Table 3 shows that the variable of interest (EPU) has a negative relationship with public firm-level investment. Similarly, regression 2 reveals that an increase in policy-related uncertainty is associated with a significant decrease in private firms’ investment decisions. This demonstrates that the theoretical prediction of real options theory applies not only to public but also to private firms. Specifically, the coefficient on the natural logarithm of EPU is \(-\,0.031\) (t-statistic = \(-\,3.052\)) and Investment in our private firm sample has a mean value of 0.018. This implies that, ceteris paribus, a 10% increase in the level of policy uncertainty is associated with a contemporaneous decline in private firm Investment equivalent to \(0.031/(10\times 0.018)\) = 17.222% of the sample mean. Hence, this finding is both statistically significant as well as economically relevant. With regard to the additional control variables, which remain qualitatively similar in all specifications, their relations with Investment do not exhibit salient discrepancy to the extant empirical finance literature.

Table 3 Baseline investment regressions

In regression 3, we estimate the same equation for our full sample of public listed and private firms, consisting of 304,543 firm-year observations. The coefficient on log(EPU) loads negatively at the 1% significance level. It indicates that, on average, a rise in EPU is associated with a reduction in public and private firms’ investment.

To investigate potential cross-sectional differences in investment sensitivities between public listed and private firms, we introduce an additional interaction term to Eq. (1). It interacts the natural logarithm of EPU with an indicator variable which is equal to unity if the firm is listed on a stock exchange, and zero if it is a private firm. The results are reported in regression 4. They show that the relationship between policy uncertainty and corporate investment is a function of the organizational form of the firm. The negative and significant interaction term of \(-\,0.018\) (t-statistic = \(-\,2.024\)) demonstrates that investments of public listed firms are more sensitive to economic policy uncertainty than investments of private firms. To quantify the total impact of EPU on public firm investment, we need to aggregate the coefficients on log(EPU) and on the log(EPU)-Public listed interaction term. The log(EPU) coefficient in this regression is \(-\,0.031\). Thus, a 10% increase in EPU is associated with a decrease in public firm Investment of about \((-0.031-0.018 \times 1)/10 = -\,0.005\). Investment in our full sample has a mean value of 0.019,Footnote 2 so this represents a reduction equivalent to 26.316% of the sample mean. As for private firms, Investment only declines by 16.316% relative to the sample mean, which corresponds to approximately three fifth of the decrease of public firms.

Regressions 5 and 6 in Table 3 are based on our matched sample. Their results are comparable to those observed in the full sample. Focusing on the non-uniformity in the cross-section, regression 6 provides additional evidence that the relationship between EPU and corporate investment is a function of the type of firm—that is, being public listed or private. The coefficient on the interaction term is \(-\,0.034\) (t-statistic = \(-\,4.595\)). Investment in our matched sample has a mean of 0.028. These results imply that when EPU assumes a level 10% higher as what is used to be, public firm Investment is 23.929% lower (relative to the sample mean) than before the increase. This compares to a reduction in Investment by 11.786% of the sample mean if the firm were not listed on a stock exchange. Hence, public firms cut their investments by about 50% more than private firms in response to an increase in policy-related uncertainty.

In the following subsection, we provide empirical evidence that this cross-sectional variation is likely to be related to public firms’ management being typically subject to greater shareholder scrutiny than private firms’ management.

3.1 Shareholder scrutiny

Real options theory predicts that when confronted with uncertainty, managers tend to respond by reducing their contemporaneous investment activity in anticipation that they would otherwise make costly investment mistakes (e.g., Bernanke 1983; Dixit and Pindyck 1994). We argue that this wait-and-see behavior should intuitively be reinforced when managers are aware that they are under a higher level of scrutiny and will face more severe consequences if such mistakes were indeed to occur.

Prior literature suggests that the management of public companies typically faces greater shareholder scrutiny and myopic pressure than the management of private companies (e.g., Asker et al. 2015; Gao et al. 2017). Consequently, this should help explain the heterogeneous investment-EPU sensitivities observed in Table 3.

We submit that there are at least three reasons why public European firms should be exposed to higher levels of scrutiny from their shareholders compared to their private counterparts.

First, most private firms are managed by the owner (major shareholder) (see Asker et al. 2015). This frequently makes it impossible to veto their decisions, let alone fire them. In contrast, the CEOs of public firms are merely agents of their shareholders, which theoretically puts them in constant danger of being dismissed. For instance, Fisman et al. (2014) find that public shareholders are quick to demand the CEO’s removal when short-term performance deteriorates, even when such events are completely outside the CEO’s control. Not surprisingly, public firms display higher CEO turnover rates and exhibit greater CEO and top management turnover-performance sensitivities than private firms (Lel et al. 2014; Gao et al. 2017).

Second, listed firms are required by law to hold an annual ordinary shareholders’ meeting at which management is in principle subject to open scrutiny by their shareholders. Conversely, private firms are not legally compelled to hold such a meeting and thus do not have to publicly answer to their shareholders.

Lastly, while European law obliges private firms to report annual financial statements, public listed firms face even stricter disclosure requirements. According to the Transparency Directive 2004/109/EC—amended by Directive 2013/50/EU in 2013—public firms are required to publish half-yearly financial reports. Accordingly, public firm managers should be increasingly conscious of the ease and frequency with which shareholders can pinpoint poor investment decisions.

Given these differences in ownership structures and legal requirements, we expect managers of public firms to become even more apprehensive about making investments amidst the uncertainty, as they should be even more concerned than their private firm counterparts about having to account for their investment mistakes or getting laid off because of them.

In order to (indirectly) test this hypothesis, we rely on cross-country differences in public firms’ minority shareholder rights (Djankov et al. 2008; La Porta et al. 1998), disclosure requirements, and liability standards (La Porta et al. 2006). If there is any truth to our argument, we would expect publicly traded firms from countries with stronger shareholder rights and higher disclosure and liability standards to reduce their investments more acutely to an increase in EPU. As public and private firms are confronted with similar differences in legal requirements as the countries in our sample, the underlying intuition of such public firm results should principally be transferable to the public versus private firm domain as well. We test this prediction with the following regression model:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} Investment_{i,t}&= \alpha _{i} + \alpha _{t} + \beta _{1} \, log(EPU_{j,t}) + \beta _{2} \, log(EPU_{j,t}) \times Inv.\,Protection_{j} \\&\quad +\beta _{3}\, SG_{i,t} + \beta _{4} \, CF_{i,t} + \beta _{5} \, Size_{i,t} + \beta _{6} \, GDP\ growth_{j,t} + \beta _{7} \, Inflation_{j,t} + \epsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where Inv. Protection stands for four mean-centered investor protection measures: Anti-Self, Anti-Dir, Disclosure, and Liability. We define each of these country-level legal variables in detail in the Appendix. According to our hypothesis, we expect \(\beta _{2}\) to be negative and statistically significant.

The estimation results of Eq. (2) are reported in Table 4. In regressions 1 and 2, we alternatively use two minority shareholder rights indexes (Anti-Self and Anti-Dir) to directly quantify shareholders’ theoretical control over the decision-making processes within a listed firm. Intuitively, the greater the control of (minority) shareholders over corporate decision-making processes, the lower the ability of CEOs and top management to act independently and they should therefore be more cautious of their own shareholders. The negative and significant coefficients on the interaction term indicate that the better the shareholder protection in a country, the greater the investment reduction of public firms to policy-related uncertainty. Specifically, in regression 1, the coefficient on the interaction term between the natural logarithm of EPU and the mean-centered Anti-Self variable is \(-\,0.115\) (t-statistic = \(-\,5.789\)). Investment in our public firm sample has a mean of 0.035. Thus, a 10% increase in EPU is associated with a decline in Investment equivalent to 8.000% of the sample mean for a public firm that resides in a country with an average level of shareholder protection (e.g., Italy). This compares to a reduction in Investment by 19.500% relative to the sample mean if the firm were located in the U.K., the country with the highest level of Anti-Self of 0.35 in our sample. This is nearly two and a half times as strong a reaction as that of an average Italian firm.

Table 4 Investment regression with investor protection variables

Regressions 3 and 4 interact our measures of disclosure requirements (Disclosure) and liability standards (Liability) with the natural logarithm of EPU, respectively. While stricter disclosure requirements increase the company’s transparency towards its shareholders, stronger liability standards allow investors to place managers under greater (legal) scrutiny if they provide misleading information. In both regressions, the coefficients on the interaction term load negatively at the 1% level. They indicate that the stronger the disclosure and liability standards, the greater the reduction in public firms’ investment in times of heightened economic policy uncertainty.

These results suggest that different levels of shareholder scrutiny—induced by varying minority shareholder rights and disclosure and liability standards—can explain cross-countries differences in public firms’ investment sensitivities to EPU. Since public and private European firms differ to a similar extent with regard to the legal requirements they need to adhere to, these findings provide some (indirect) explanation for the non-uniform reaction between the two types of companies as well.

4 Policy uncertainty and future operating performance

This section explores whether public and private firms invest more efficiently when exposed to increasing policy-related uncertainty. Theoretically, return on investment should be comparatively high when EPU is high as both public and private firms significantly reduce their investments due to their increasing fear of making costly mistakes (see Table 3). Consequently, both firms should primarily invest in their most valuable projects, i.e. those projects that justify immediate implementation rather than postponement. This line of reasoning is related to McLean and Zhao’s (2014) findings. They demonstrate that when firms’ financing costs are high, some of their projects will have to be abandoned. The ensuing consolidation of investments is then carried out in such a manner that the firms primarily realize their most profitable projects. Therefore, we run the following regression for both public and private firms:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} Average ROA_{i,t\;to\;t+2}&= \alpha _{i} + \alpha _{t} + \beta _{1} \ Investment_{i,t} \\&\quad + \beta _{2} \ Investment_{i,t} \times log(EPU_{j,t}) + \beta _{3} \ log(EPU_{j,t}) + {\textbf {X}}'_{i,t} + \epsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The dependent variable is the average annual return-on-assets (ROA) measured over a 3-year period including the year in which the investment is undertaken. Annual ROA is captured by the variable used in the Amadeus Database for the return on total assets. It is defined as profit before taxation scaled by total assets. \({\textbf {X}}'\) denotes our typical set of control variables. According to our hypothesis, we expect the interaction term between investment and the natural logarithm of EPU to be positive and significant for both types of firms.

Table 5 presents the results of the operating performance regressions. We divide our matched sample into public and private firms. For expositional clarity, we only present the coefficients of interest (\(\beta _{1}\) to \(\beta _{3}\)). Regression 1 examines public firms. The coefficient on the interaction term between investment and the natural logarithm of EPU is 0.050 (t-statistic = 2.593). It shows that the greater the threat of policy-related uncertainty, the more efficiently public firms invest. In detail, a one unit increase in Investment portends a 0.011 rise in public firms’ ROA whenever they experience the average level of uncertainty of 163.240 in our sample. If EPU were to reach its maximum of 542.766 in our sample, public firms’ average ROA would increase by 0.071, which is more than six times as much as before. This result demonstrates that public firms invest relatively more in their most valuable projects when they have to deal with mounting economic policy uncertainty. Or, put differently, the quality of realized investments improves as uncertainty increases.

Table 5 Investment, EPU, and Ex post efficiency

In regression 2—in contrast to public firms—the coefficient on the Investment-log(EPU) interaction term is insignificant. This estimate implies that a greater level of policy uncertainty is not associated with an increase in private firms’ investment profitability.

In summary, the estimates show that when faced with uncertainty, only public firms invest in a more profitable manner than in tranquil periods. Since both types of firms significantly reduce their investments in uncertain times, this suggests that public firms are more capable of identifying their most valuable projects—that is, those projects that warrant immediate execution rather than deferral.Footnote 3

We suspect that these cross-sectional differences are again related to the fact that managers of public firms have to be more concerned about potential costly investment mistakes and the associated consequences than their private firm counterparts. This is because if they decided to pursue uncertain investments and they later prove to be underperforming, they would be more likely to lose their jobs than private firm decision-makers (Lel et al. 2014; Gao et al. 2017). Embracing the decision-making processes of public firms in uncertain times could therefore aid private firms in detecting those investment opportunities that most justify immediate implementation.

Consequently, in the face of uncertainty, private company decision-makers should increasingly incorporate feedback from their peers into their investment strategy. Having to present and justify investment ideas to others may not put their jobs at risk, but at least their reputation. This should increase the propensity to invest in projects with the highest degree of certainty for a given rate of expected profitability, i.e. easy-to-justify investments. This idea is related to the literature that finds that when investors have to engage and explain their investment decisions to human brokers instead of anonymously trading online (Barber and Odean 2001, 2002; Konana and Balasubramanian 2005) or when they have to justify their decisions to other members of an investment club (Barber et al. 2003), they tend to prefer investing in projects with lower levels of uncertainty. Konana and Balasubramanian (2005) find that online investors are partially afraid of their interactions with traditional brokers as they do not want to be judged by them of lacking in knowledge about the economics of the stock market.

We conclude this section with a small caveat regarding the interpretation of our results. On first sight, it might be tempting to deduce that public firms operate more profitably than private ones in uncertain times. While this might be the case, our results do not necessarily imply that. This is because private firms might have higher initial profitability rates that simply do not change during periods of uncertainty, but are still greater than the increased profitability rates of public firms in uncertain times.

5 The dynamic relationship between policy uncertainty and investment decisions

This section examines the evolving relation over time between policy uncertainty and fixed asset investment for both public and private firms. The most commonly used method for studying such dynamic relationships is the estimation of vector autoregressions (VARs) with the subsequent computation of impulse response functions (IRFs). IRFs would allow us to assess and visualize the endogenous investment reaction to an initial EPU shock across subsequent points in time. Consequently, we start by estimating VARs based on our standard set of variables: log(EPU), Cash flow, Sales growth, Size, GDP growth, Inflation, and Investment. The VARs are run on annual data from 2009 to 2017, using a lag structure of one. To calculate the IRFs, we apply a Cholesky decomposition using the same variable order outlined above.Footnote 4

Fig. 2
figure 2

Effect of a policy uncertainty shock on corporate investment 

Both IRFs are displayed in Fig. 2. As shown in the top panel, we observe that a one unit shock to EPU has a negative and statistically significant impact on public firms’ fixed asset investment for an approximate duration of two years, reaching its trough 1 year after the shock. This finding is in accordance with real options theory. As (policy-related) uncertainty increases, the urge of firm managers to inform themselves (about government commitments) becomes more valuable than investing immediately in uncertain projects. Thus, the option value of an investment delay exceeds the value of immediate investment. This causes companies to postpone part of their investments. However, when focusing on later periods, we discover a rebound effect that starts towards the end of the third year and lasts almost until the end of the fourth year after the initial shock. This observation is in line with the notion that although uncertainty may trigger investment delays, once it is cleared up, the levels of investment will rise to meet pent-up demand. These results are similar to those of Gulen and Ion (2016), who find that in times of policy-related uncertainty spells, public U.S. firms experience an initial decline in investment for about two and a half years, which is attenuated by a rebound effect in later periods.

The bottom panel of Fig. 2 indicates that, comparable to public firms, a one unit shock to EPU has a negative and significant impact on private firms’ fixed asset investment for about two years. Again, the IRF reaches its trough 1 year after the shock. However, contrary to public firms, we fail to detect a statistically significant rebound in investments at any time in the future. Thus, consistent with real options theory, both public and private firms postpone part of their investments, whereas private firms delay them indefinitely.

It is possible that this cross-sectional variation in recovery responses several years after the initial shock might be connected to the idiosyncratic increase in investment profitability rates in uncertain times. This could encourage public firms to pursue new investments at a higher rate than before. As far as private firms are concerned, their inability to identify the projects that would justify immediate implementation the most potentially leads them to refrain from offsetting the initial decline in later periods. Consequently, no significant rebound in their investments can be observed.

6 Robustness

6.1 Omitted variable bias

In this subsection, we adopt multiple specifications to assess the robustness of our baseline finding of a negative relation between EPU and private firms’ investment decisions. One potential point of concern with our analysis thus far is that the EPU index may track some macroeconomic information pertaining to investment opportunities, despite the efforts of Baker et al. (2016) to ensure that it does not merely reflect macroeconomic conditions. Several authors point out that economic uncertainty is counter-cyclical (e.g., Bloom 2009; Baker et al. 2016). As policy-makers often feel the urge to implement policy changes to combat prevailing poor economic conditions, it appears reasonable to assume that EPU is also counter-cyclical and thus negatively correlates with investment opportunities. Consequently, if our current control variables in the form of GDP growth and Inflation do not fully reflect firms’ overall investment chances, our estimates might suffer from a potential omitted variable bias.

In order to alleviate such concerns, we estimate Eq. (1) for our full sample of 291,415 private firm-years with the addition of two country-level economic indicators that are likely to impact corporate investment decisions. These controls consist of annual GDP per capita (GDP per capita) and annual exports plus imports scaled by GDP (Trade).

The results are reported in Table 6. Regression 1 shows that despite the inclusion of GDP per capita and Trade, the magnitude and significance of the EPU coefficient remain virtually unchanged. Specifically, the coefficient on log(EPU) is \(-\,0.030\) (t-statistic = \(-\,2.737\)). Thus, a 10% increase in EPU stands in association to reduce private firms’ Investment by about 16.667% of the sample mean. Compared to the initial decline of 17.222% reported in regression 1 in Table 3, this provides us with substantiated evidence that our results are not compromised by omitted investment opportunity measures. Similarly, in regression 2, we use the first principal component from a different set of control variables developed to capture investment opportunities. This set of variables follows (Greenland et al. 2019) and comprises the forecasted real GDP growth (Predicted RGDP growth), the Composite Leading Indicator (CLI), the Business Confidence Indicator (BCI), and the Consumer Confidence Indicator (CCI). All variables are obtained from the OECD database. Nevertheless, despite the inclusion of the Economic condition, first PC variable, the coefficient on log(EPU) remains negative and significant.Footnote 5

Table 6 Full private firm sample: further macroeconomic control variables

A second potential concern to which the previous literature has already alerted is that the EPU index may simply reflect macroeconomic uncertainty, which is not necessarily tied to future policy decisions (see Gulen and Ion 2016; Greenland et al. 2019). Since events such as recessions, wars, and financial crises do not only increase policy-related uncertainty but also contribute to intensifying overall macroeconomic uncertainty, firms facing policy uncertainty may also experience uncertainty about other elements of their operations (e.g., supply chain issues).

To address this matter, we include two alternative measures of macroeconomic uncertainty. First, we use one of the most frequently applied proxies of general macroeconomic uncertainty as perceived by the stock market (e.g., Bloom 2009; Taglioni and Zavacka 2013). We therefore calculate the time-series volatility of realized monthly returns on the respective main stock exchange in each of our nine European countries (Return volatility). The monthly return data are from the Thomson Reuters Eikon database. Second, in line with Bloom (2009) we also utilize the cross-sectional standard deviation of sales growth for all firms in each country included in our sample (CS std. dev. of sales growth) to measure macroeconomic uncertainty. Regression 3 in Table 6 shows that while the coefficients on Return volatility and CS std. dev. of sales growth have a negative relationship with private firm investment, only CS std. dev. of sales growth is statistically distinguishable from zero. Crucially, these controls have little impact on our point estimate of interest, which remains qualitatively unaffected. Lastly, regression 4 demonstrates that economic policy uncertainty affects private firm investment in a way that is consistent with our model, even when investment opportunities and general macroeconomic uncertainty are included in a single specification.

While the estimates of Table 6 are based on our full sample of 291,415 private firm-years, Table 7 presents estimates based on the private firm observations used in our matched sample. Regarding the primary covariate, the results show no salient discrepancies from the previous table. Hence, Tables 6 and 7 are in line with our baseline finding. The negative relationship between economic policy uncertainty and investment decisions of private firms does not systematically depend on the omission of investment opportunity and macroeconomic uncertainty measures.

Table 7 Matched private firm sample: further macroeconomic control variables

6.2 Instrumental variable analysis

The existing literature on corporate investment has long acknowledged the difficult task to discriminate between uncertainty and bad investment opportunities. Another important objective is to ensure that EPU reflects only uncertainty related to future economic policies and does not capture the uncertainty surrounding future macroeconomic developments in general. As demonstrated above, we deal with this challenge by controlling for these interfering factors using various measures of investment opportunities and overall macroeconomic uncertainty. However, the effectiveness of this strategy hinges critically on the precision and appropriateness of the measures employed. We thus use an instrumental variable (IV) approach to mitigate the risk that the measures may not completely eliminate potential endogeneity problems present in our previous analysis.

We propose one such variable, namely the relative strength of right-wing parties in government (Gov. right). It is based on the “gov_right2” index taken from the Comparative Political Data Set 1960-2017 (CPDS).Footnote 6 It measures the percentage of parliamentary seats held by right-wing parties in government. Intuitively, this index ranges from 0 to 100, taking a value of 0 if no right-wing party is represented in parliament and 100 if all parliamentary seats are held by right-wing parties.

We expect to find a positive link between Gov. right and policy-related uncertainty. The rationale for this positive relationship is straightforward: In recent decades, the rising popularity of right-wing populist parties has become a central issue in the European political environment (Trumm 2018). In some countries, they were already part of the government or strongly associated with it, such as the Lega Nord (LN) in Italy or the Partij voor de Vrijheid (PVV) in the Netherlands. With their anti-establishment and pro-national stance, these parties have created much instability in the political system and in the business world (de Sousa et al. 2020). Even if these parties are not directly part of the government, they influence the positions of the established parties (Muis and Immerzeel 2017). The established parties feel they have to adapt some of the positions of the right-wing populist parties in order to win back their voters. For example, one of the greatest successes of European right-wing populist parties was in 2015, when UKIP forced the ruling Tories to hold the Brexit referendum in 2016, leading to dramatic economic policy uncertainty across the European continent (Bale 2018).

Thus, we expect that a higher percentage of right-wing parties in government increases the impact of populism on the political system, which should lead to greater policy-related uncertainty. Therefore, our measure should meet the relevance condition as an instrument. In contrast, it is not apparent how the composition of the government affects business investments, except through its influence on economic policy uncertainty. Correspondingly, we are certain that our proposed instrumental variable should also meet the exclusion restriction.

In Table 8, we re-run our baseline regression for the full and matched sample of private firms using the index as outlined above as an instrument for economic policy uncertainty. The results of the first-stage regression show that the Gov. right variable is a significant and strong determinant of the natural logarithm of EPU. In particular, the coefficient on log(1 + Gov. right) is 0.111 (t-statistic = 3.765) for the full private firm sample. The F-statistic is 14.18, indicating that we are not suffering from a weak instrument problem. The results imply that a doubling of the relative power position of right-wings parties in government is associated with a 11.1% increase in policy-related uncertainty.

Table 8 Instrumental variables analysis

The second-stage regression estimates show that EPU, indeed, has an exogenous impact on investments of private firms that is not attributable to other distorting factors. The impact of EPU is still negative and significant. Therefore, we are confident that our previously presented results are not significantly compromised by endogeneity issues, but are in fact linked to the exogenous impact of the uncertainty surrounding future economic policy decisions.

6.3 Alternative matching procedure

Thus far, our matching procedure is comparable to that of Mortal and Reisel (2013), Asker et al. (2015), and Gilje and Taillard (2016). Specifically, based on a caliper of 0.05, each public firm is matched with a private firm that is most similar in terms of total assets in the same industry, country, and year. While this drastically reduces the difference in average firm size between these two types of firms, it unfortunately leads to an increase in heterogeneity in sales growth (see Table 1).

To mitigate the possibility that our results are in any way distorted by this circumstance, we create a new matched sample using an alternative matching procedure. It uses nearest neighbor matching in each year based on Sales growth, Cash flow, and Size in the same industry and country. Table 14 in the Appendix shows that in this newly created sample, the differences between public and private firms with respect to all three variables are smaller compared to our unmatched sample.

Regression 1 in Table 9 reports estimation results of Eq. (1). The coefficient on log(EPU) is − 0.055 (t-statistic = − 4.177), indicating that an increase in economic policy uncertainty continues to be significantly associated with depressing the investment behavior of public and private European firms. Compared with the coefficient on log(EPU) in regression 5 in Table 3 of − 0.051, this result suggests that the effect of EPU is almost independent of the matching procedure applied.

Table 9 Investment regressions based on alternatively matched sample

To examine whether the two types of firms continue to differ significantly in their investment responses to policy uncertainty, a log(EPU) \(\times\) Public listed interaction term is introduced in regression 2. Similar to our baseline results, the coefficient on the interaction term is negative and statistically significant. It implies that public firms reduce their investments more than private firms to an increase in EPU. Therefore, we are confident that our baseline results are not simply attributable to the adoption of the matching approach of Mortal and Reisel (2013), Asker et al. (2015), and Gilje and Taillard (2016).

7 Conclusion

This paper studies whether Baker et al.’s (2016) economic policy uncertainty index can depress investment decisions of private firms and whether their reaction differs significantly from that of public ones. Our analyses are conducted in a large sample of public and private firms from nine European countries between 2009 and 2017.

The results show that private firms invest significantly less in times of uncertainty. This finding is robust in different specifications aimed at eliminating potential endogeneity concerns. Further, we observe that public firms reduce their investments by about 50% more than private firms in response to an increase in uncertainty. We attribute these results to the greater inclination of public firm management to avoid scrutiny by their shareholders, which fosters a larger degree of uncertainty averse decisions. When examining how the relationship between policy uncertainty and investment varies at different points in time, we find that unlike private firms, public firms experience a rebound effect in their investment levels. This variation in recovery responses might be connected to our observation that only public firms invest more efficiently when confronted with increases in policy-related uncertainty. This could encourage public firms to pursue investments at a higher rate than before whereas private firms refrain from offsetting their initial decline in later periods.

In terms of policy implications, our results suggest that if private companies do not always invest in the most efficient manner, they may benefit from adopting the decision-making processes of public companies in uncertain times, as this could help them identify the projects that justify immediate implementation the most. Therefore, when faced with uncertainty, private company decision-makers should proactively gather and consider feedback from their peers on future investments.

We see an avenue for future research to explore other channels that could help further explain the different investment responses of public and private firms to uncertainty. For example, Michaely and Roberts (2012) argue that public firms face greater public scrutiny than private firms because analysts only track and monitor listed companies.