Skip to main content
Log in

Of families and inheritance: law and development in England before the Industrial Revolution

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine how pre-Industrial-Revolution English caselaw development on land, inheritance, and families affected, and was affected by, economic and demographic outcomes. Our yearly measures of caselaw development are derived from existing topic-model estimates that reflect a comprehensive corpus of reports on pre-1765 court cases. We estimate a structural VAR model using these caselaw time-series in combination with measures of real per-capita income and vital rates. Pre-industrial caselaw development profoundly shaped economic development. Strikingly, the areas of caselaw that stimulated real-income growth are on families and inheritance, not land. Caselaw on families and inheritance was especially important as a driver of real income and birth rates after 1710. Caselaw developments were spurred primarily by changes in real income, not by changes in vital rates. Incorporation of endogenous caselaw development leaves intact the findings of the existing literature that examines pre-industrial economic-demographic interactions. However, our findings do imply that any Malthusian trap that was present in pre-industrial England was made less severe as a result of developments in caselaw on families and inheritance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Clark (2007), Wrigley and Schofield (1981), Nicolini (2007), Lee and Anderson (2002), Crafts and Mills (2009, 2020), Møller and Sharp (2014), Kelly and Ó Gráda (2012, 2013).

  2. Certainly, this direct link has been implicit on the works of economic historians for centuries. We are referring in this paper to a recent literature in economics as a whole that has spurred increasing interest in this question outside the community of economic historians. The seminal works in this strand of the general economics literature are North and Weingast (1989) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2005).

  3. Even confining oneself to the hugely significant studies would entail a list that is far too long to include here. Baker (2019) provides a recent compelling synthesis. In Sect. 2, we cite further specific examples of relevant works.

  4. See Cornish et al. (2019 p. 6–10) and Harris (2004) for an overview of the literature debating the importance of law (or lack thereof) for early industrial development. The influence of society on legal development is implicit in many works by legal historians. However, the effect of socioeconomic developments on caselaw development in the pre-industrial era has not been subjected to systematic quantitative scrutiny.

  5. See, for example, Coffman, Leonard and Neal (2013), McCloskey (2010), Klerman and Mahoney (2005), Murrell (2017), Murrell (2021), Neal (2000), O'Brien (2011), Sussman and Yafeh (2006).

  6. For this reason, we do not provide detailed references of sources. Sections 2 and 3 are based on our synthesis of the information contained in many papers and books. Most important among these are Abramowicz (1999), Baker (2019) Barclay (2017), Bonfield (1983a, 1983b, 1986), Cust and Lake (2020), English and Saville (1983), Erickson (1990, 2002, 2005), Feldman (2003), Forster (1983), Healey (2019), McDonagh (2017), Roebuck (1978), Seymour (1994), Solar (1995), Spring (1984), and Tait (2014).

  7. Under coverture, a bride surrendered her personal property to the groom unless that property was isolated in a separate estate.

  8. In topic modeling, topics are distributions over vocabulary. Documents are distributions over topics.

  9. The land theme corresponds to the theme that Grajzl and Murrell name real property. We assigned this particular theme a different name because the themes of families and inheritance are both relevant to real-property.

  10. See Gennaro and Ash (2022) for an analogous methodological approach that relies on researchers' judgment and knowledge of institutional context to construct broader themes on the basis of estimated topics.

  11. The complete list of keywords and detailed justification of each topic, with extracts from reports featuring a given topic prominently, are provided in appendices D and E in Grajzl and Murrell (2021a).

  12. In contrast, the cumulative sum of the time series up to a certain year (i.e., cumulative attention) reflects the overall development by that year of the applicable area of law.

  13. Thus, relative lack of attention to a specific area of law in a given time period does not necessarily imply that the relevant law was not a fixture of the legal system in that era. Given the nature of the English Reports, a set of legal ideas that are thoroughly accepted will not garner as much attention as one that is undergoing lively development.

  14. See, e.g., Bailey and Chambers (1998), Lee and Anderson (2002), Nicolini (2007), Crafts and Mills (2009), Møller and Sharp (2014), Rathke and Sarferaz (2014), and Crafts and Mills (2020). These contributions utilize Wrigley and Schofield's (1981) data in diverse ways and employ different empirical approaches, including standard VAR analysis, cointegrated VAR, and non-VAR based structural modeling.

  15. Full results on this point are available on request.

  16. The sequential modified LR statistic, final prediction error, and Akaike information criterion all suggest the use of four lags. The Schwartz and Hannan-Quinn information criteria suggest an even smaller number of lags.

  17. The serjeants were the very small pool of elite lawyers from whom future judges would be appointed.

  18. We have explored the consequences of an alternative ordering assumption, whereby unanticipated developments in law affect demographic and economic variables with a lag, but shocks to demographic and economic variables exert a contemporaneous effect on attention to law. None of our key findings change as a result.

  19. If instead we use 95-percent confidence intervals, the innovations in law on families still exert a statistically significant positive effect on the birth rate and real per-capita income. The positive effect of innovations in inheritance law on real per-capita income and the negative effect of innovations in land law on real per-capita income become marginally statistically insignificant.

  20. See Hodgson (2022: Ch 3) who provides an overview of the pertinent work by social and legal historians on this point.

  21. Interestingly, by combining our estimates of the effect of innovations in land law on all three demographic and economic variables, we can obtain an estimate of changes in real income. This begins to grow only 30 years after the shock.

  22. Specifically, using Broadberry et al.'s (2015) data, Crafts and Mills (2017) demonstrate that the annual trend growth of English real GDP per capita was equal to 0.03 percent before 1663 and 0.84 percent between 1663 and 1707.

  23. Expressed in Blackstone's Commentaries on the Laws of England.

  24. The mean of yearly structural shocks to law on families between 1662 and 1666 equals about one quarter of one standard deviation of the magnitude of yearly structural shocks between 1556 and 1764.

  25. The mean of yearly structural shocks to law on inheritance during 1661–1662 equals about 1.9 standard deviations of the magnitude of yearly structural shocks between 1556 and 1764.

  26. After 1722, counterfactual income slightly overshoots actual income and then slowly converges toward actual income.

  27. The difference in the estimated constant actual annual growth rate of real per-capita income between 1661 and 1688 (this paragraph) versus between 1662 and 1688 (previous paragraph) arises because of a sizeable increase in real per-capita income between the years 1661 and 1662.

  28. Historical decompositions show that changes in the death rate are driven mostly by its own shocks.

  29. For evidence on economic-demographic interactions during the pre-industrial era outside of England, see for example Chiarini (2010), Chiarini and Marzano (2019), Jensen et al. (2022), and Pedersen et al. (2021).

  30. To construct the time series of attention to NTL we followed exactly the same procedure as described in Sect. 4.2. The resultant time series is displayed in Fig. 16 in Appendix F.

  31. The complete set of results is available upon request.

  32. See McCloskey (2010 pp. 310–345) for a summary of the relevant literature, which exemplifies the focus on the security of property. The statement in the text is a generalization, of course, and two important exceptions should be emphasized. First, the tenor in the legal history literature referenced in Sects. 2 and 3 is very different from that in the economic history literature, and indeed in the history literature in general. Second, Bogart and Richardson (2011) have emphasized the facilitative role of 18th-century legislation that changed specific property rights. However, this legislation did not create new general legal rules but rather used the existing legal framework to facilitate economic projects.

  33. "…numerous modern historians, and in particular intellectual historians, have followed Mill in approaching the common law as a subordinate discipline. Principally, Restoration common law has been treated as an instrument of the king's or Parliament's will…This tendency to assume that the common lawyers carried out the will of their superiors is even more acute among historians of early modern sovereignty" Kearns (2019).

  34. McCloskey (2010), for example, states: "As many economic historians before and after me have noted, the institutions relevant to the economy [emphasis in the original] of Britain in fact did not change much in the very late seventeenth century, or even over the long eighteenth century 1688–1815.".

References

  • Abramowicz S (1999) English child custody law, 1660–1839: the origins of judicial intervention in parental custody. Columbia Law Rev 99(5):1344–1392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2005) Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2012) Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Random House, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen RC (2001) The great divergence in European wages and prices from the middle ages to the first world war. Explor Econ Hist 38(4):411–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen RC (2009) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson M, Lee R (2002) Malthus in state space: macro economic-demographic relations in English history, 1540 to 1870. J Popul Econ 15(2):195–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey RE, Chambers MJ (1993) Long term demographic interactions in pre-census England. J R Stat Soc Ser A 156(3):339–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker J (2019) An introduction to English legal history, 5th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay K (2017) Natural affection, the patriarchal family and the “strict settlement” debate: a response from the history of emotions. Eighteenth Century 58(3):309–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blei DM (2012) Probabilistic topic models. Commun ACM 55(4):77–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogart D, Richardson G (2011) Property rights and Parliament in industrializing Britain. J Law Econ 54(2):241–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonfield L (1983a) Marriage settlements, 1601–1740. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bonfield L (1983b) Marriage, property & the “affective family.” Law Hist Rev 1(2):297–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonfield L (1986) Affective families, open elites and strict family settlements in early modern England. Econ Hist Rev 39(3):341–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry S, Campbell BMS, Klein A, Overton M, van Leeuwen B (2015) British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiarini B (2010) Was Malthus right? The relationship between population and real wages in Italian history, 1320 to 1870. Explor Econ Hist 47(4):460–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiarini B, Marzano E (2019) Urbanisation and agricultural productivity: why did the splendour of the Italian cities in the sixteenth century not lead to transition? Kyklos 72(1):3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano LJ, Eichenbaum M, Evans CL (1999) Monetary policy shocks: what have we learned and to what end? In: Taylor JB, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 65–148

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2007) A farewell to alms: a brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2010) The macroeconomic aggregates for England, 1260–2008. Res Econ Hist 27:51–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coffman D, Leonard A, Neal L (eds) (2013) Questioning credible commitment: perspectives on the rise of financial capitalism. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornish W, Banks S, Mitchell C, Mitchell P, Probert R (2019) Law and society in England 1750–1950, 2nd edn. Hart Publishing, Oxford, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Crafts N, Mills TC (2009) From Malthus to Solow: how did the Malthusian economy really evolve? J Macroecon 31(1):68–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crafts N, Mills TC (2017) Six centuries of British economic growth: a time-series perspective. Eur Rev Econ Hist 21(2):141–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crafts N, Mills TC (2020) The race between population and technology: real wages in the first industrial revolution. Warwick Economics Research Papers No. 1298

  • Cust R, Lake P (2020) Gentry culture and the politics of religion: Cheshire on the eve of civil war. Manchester University Press, Manchester, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • David PA (1990) The dynamo and the computer: an historical perspective on the modern productivity paradox. Am Econ Rev 80(2):355–361

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio P, Nag M, Blei D (2013) Exploiting affinities between topic modeling and the sociological perspective on culture: application to newspaper coverage of U.S. government arts funding. Poetics 41(6):570–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • English B, Saville J (1983) Strict settlement: a guide for historians. University of Hull Press, Kingston upon Hull, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Erickson AL (1990) Common law versus common practice: the use of marriage settlements in early modern England. Econ Hist Rev 43(1):21–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erickson AL (1993) Women and property in early modern England. Routledge, London, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Erickson AL (2005) Coverture and capitalism. Hist Work J 59(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman D (2003) Migrants, immigrants and welfare from the old poor law to the welfare state. Trans R Hist Soc 13:79–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernihough A (2013) Malthusian dynamics in a diverging Europe: northern Italy, 1650–1881. Demography 50(1):311–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forster GCF (1983) Government in provincial England under the later Stuarts. Trans R Hist Soc 33:29–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankenreiter J, Livermore MA (2020) Computational methods in legal analysis. Ann Rev Law Soc Sci 16:39–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaro G, Ash E (2022) Emotion and reason in political language. Econ J 132(643):1037–1059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldie M (2001) The unacknowledged republic: officeholding in early modern England. In: Harris T (ed) The politics of the excluded, c. 1500-1850. Palgrave, London, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Grajzl P, Murrell P (2016) A Darwinian theory of institutional development two centuries before Darwin. J Econ Behav Org 131:346–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grajzl P, Murrell P (2021a) A machine-learning history of English caselaw and legal ideas prior to the industrial revolution I: generating and interpreting the estimates. J Inst Econ 17(1):1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Grajzl P, Murrell P (2021b) A machine-learning history of English caselaw and legal ideas prior to the industrial revolution II: applications. J Inst Econ 17(2):201–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Habakkuk J (1979) Presidential address: the rise and fall of English landed families, 1600–1800. Trans R Hist Soc 29:187–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris R (2004) Government and the economy, 1688–1850. In: Floud R, Johnson P (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern Britain, vol I. Industrialization, 1700–1860. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp 204–237

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Haskins GL (1977) Extending the grasp of the dead hand: reflections on the origins of the rule against perpetuities. Univ Pa Law Rev 126(1):19–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healey J (2019) Coping with risk in the seventeenth century: the first age of the English old poor law: a regional study. In: Masayuki T, Wong RB (eds) Public goods provision in the early modern economy: comparative perspectives from Japan, China, and Europe. University of California Press, Oakland CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2022) The wealth of a nation: institutional foundations of English capitalism 1300–1820. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ (forthcoming)

  • Hodgson GM (2017) 1688 and all that: property rights, the Glorious Revolution and the rise of British capitalism. J Inst Econ 13(1):79–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphries J, Weisdorf J (2019) Unreal wages? Real income and economic growth in England, 1260–1850. Econ J 129(623):2867–2887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen PS, Pedersen MU, Radu CV, Sharp PR (2022) Arresting the sword of Damocles: the transition to the post-Malthusian era in Denmark. Explor Econ Hist 84:101437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kearns D (2019) Sovereignty and common law judicial office in Taylor’s Case (1675). Law Hist Rev 37(2):397–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelly M, Gráda ÓC (2012) The preventive check in medieval and preindustrial England. J Econ Hist 72(4):1015–1035

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelly M, Gráda ÓC (2013) Numerare est errare: agricultural output and food supply in England before and during the Industrial Revolution. J Econ Hist 73(4):1132–1163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilian L (2009) Not all oil price shocks are alike: disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market. Am Econ Rev 99(3):1053–1069

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilian L, Lütkepohl H (2017) Structural vector autoregressive analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Klerman DM, Mahoney PG (2005) The value of judicial independence: evidence from eighteenth century England. Am Law Econ Rev 7(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy FJ (1982) How information spread among the gentry, 1550–1640. J Br Stud 21(2):11–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey DN (2010) Bourgeois dignity: why economics can’t explain the modern world. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey DN (2016) Bourgeois equality: how ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Møller NF, Sharp P (2014) Malthus in cointegration space: evidence of a post-Malthusian pre-industrial England. J Econ Growth 19(1):105–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murrell P (2017) Design and evolution in institutional development: the insignificance of the English Bill of Rights. J Comp Econ 45(1):36–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murrell P (2021) Did the independence of judges reduce legal development in England, 1600–1800? J Law Econ 64(3):539–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neal L (2000) How it all began: the monetary and financial architecture of Europe during the first global capital markets, 1648–1815. Financ Hist Rev 7(2):117–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicolini EA (2007) Was Malthus right? A VAR analysis of economic and demographic interactions in pre-industrial England. Eur Rev Econ Hist 11(1):99–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Weingast BR (1989) Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. J Econ Hist 49(4):803–832

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien P (2011) The nature and historical evolution of an exceptional fiscal state and its possible significance for the precocious commercialization and industrialization of the British economy from Cromwell to Nelson. Econ Hist Rev 64(2):408–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogilvie S, Carus AW (2014) Institutions and economic growth in historical perspective. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 403–513

    Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen M, Riani C, Sharp P (2021) Malthus in preindustrial northern Italy? J Popul Econ 34(5):1003–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey VA (2016) Macroeconomic shocks and their propagation. In: Taylor JB, Uhlig H (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 71–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Rathke A, Sarferaz S (2014) Malthus and the industrial revolution: evidence from a time-varying VAR. CESifo Working Paper No. 4667

  • Reich J, Tingley D, Leder-Luis J, Roberts ME, Stewart B (2014) Computer-assisted reading and discovery for student generated text in massive open online courses. J Learn Anal 2(1):156–184

    Google Scholar 

  • Renton AW (1900–1932) The English reports. W. Green & Sons: Edinburgh, UK

  • Roberts ME, Stewart BM, Airoldi EM (2016) A model of text for experimentation in the social sciences. J Am Stat Assoc 111(515):988–1003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts ME, Stewart BM, Tingley D, Lucas C, Leder-Luis J, Gadarian SK, Albertson B, Rand DG (2014) Structural topic models for open-ended survey responses. Am J Polit Sci 58(4):1064–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roebuck P (1978) Post-restoration landownership: the impact of the abolition of wardship. J Br Stud 18(1):67–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seymour J (1994) Parens patriae and wardship powers: their nature and origins. Oxf J Leg Stud 14(2):159–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solar PM (1995) Poor relief and English economic development before the industrial revolution. Econ Hist Rev 48(1):1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spring E (1984) Law and the theory of the affective family. Albion 16(1):1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sussman N, Yafeh Y (2006) Institutional reforms, financial development and sovereign debt: Britain 1690–1790. J Econ Hist 66(4):906–935

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tait AA (2014) The beginning of the end of coverture: a reappraisal of the married woman’s separate estate. Yale J Law Fem 26(2):165–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley EA, Schofield RS (1981) The population history of England 1541–1871. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Niels Framroze Møller and Paul Sharp for sharing their data. For helpful comments and suggestions, we thank Boragan Aruoba, Amy Erickson, Rafael González-Val, participants at the 15th Conference on Empirical Legal Studies, 26th annual conference of the Society for Institutional and Organizational Economics and seminar at Washington and Lee University, and two anonymous reviewers.

Funding

None.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Grajzl.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

None.

Data availability statement

The data generated and analyzed in the current study are available from the corresponding author on request.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

See Figs. 8 , 9 and 10

Fig. 8
figure 8

The time series of the attention to topics comprising the Land theme

Fig. 9
figure 9

The time series of the attention to topics comprising the Inheritance theme

Fig. 10
figure 10

The time series of the attention to topics comprising the Families theme

Appendix B

See Fig. 11

Fig. 11
figure 11

Accumulated responses of demographic and economic variables to law shocks. 90-percent confidence intervals computed using Kilian's (1998) bootstrap method

Appendix C

This appendix presents the results concerning the effect on economic development at the sectoral level of legal developments in the three areas of caselaw under consideration (land, inheritance, and families). To this end, we use Broadberry et al.'s (2015) data on real output in the agriculture, industry, and service sectors, expressed in the form of index numbers (the base year is 1700), and on England's population, expressed in millions. (The data in electronic format are available on the Bank of England's website under the heading A Millennium of Macroeconomic Data.)

For each of the three sectors (agriculture, industry, and service), we compute the real output index per one million people. Specifically, let \({q}_{t}\) denote the (unobserved) real output of a particular sector in year \(t\). Then, the (observed) index of real output in year \(t\) equals \(({q}_{t}/{q}_{1700})\times 100\), and the index of real output per one million people in the same year is

$$\frac{\frac{{q}_{t}}{{q}_{1700}}\times 100}{{pop}_{t}}\equiv \left(\frac{{q}_{t}}{{pop}_{t}}\right)\times \left(\frac{100}{{q}_{1700}}\right),$$
(C1)

where \({pop}_{t}\) is year \(t\) population measured in millions. The first term on the right-hand side of (C1) is the (unobserved) real sectoral output per one million people. The second term on the right-hand side of (C1) is time-invariant. Applying natural logarithms to (C1) and first-differencing the resulting expression with respect to time, \(t\), then shows that relative changes over time in (C1) perfectly reflect the relative changes over time in the (unobserved) real sectoral output per capita.

We estimate an expanded version of the VAR developed in Sect. 5. Specifically, we replace logged real per-capita income in vector \({{\varvec{y}}}_{t}\), defined by expression (2), with our logged measures of real per-capita sectoral output, \({agric}_{t}\), \({ind}_{t}\), and \({serv}_{t}\), as defined in (C1). We add all three variables to the model at once. Our new vector \({{\varvec{y}}}_{t}\) therefore contains eight variables. We retain all other assumptions of the model as developed in Sect. 5.

In the resultant expanded VAR, we approach identification as follows. Intuitively, agricultural output, both arable and pastoral, reflects activity (planting, acquisition of cattle etc.) from many months ago. Shocks to the industrial and service sectors will thus normally not affect agricultural output in the same year. Similarly, industrial production relies heavily on the use of physical capital (machinery and equipment), the stock of which increases only with investment. Shocks to the service sector will therefore plausibly not affect industrial output in the same year. Accordingly, for identification, we place the new variables at the very end of the vector \({{\varvec{y}}}_{t}\) (the position occupied by \({income}_{t}\) in the main model) and order them as \({agric}_{t}\), \({ind}_{t}\), \({serv}_{t}\). We have verified, however, that our findings are fully robust to alternative orderings within the sub-vector of the three newly-included variables.

The relevant subset of the estimated (non-accumulated) impulse-responses is shown in Fig. 12 . As emphasized in Sect. 6.1, innovations in caselaw on families and inheritance increase per-capita output of the industrial sector (Figs. 12e, f), but do not exert a discernible effect on per-capita output in agriculture and services sectors (Fig. 12b, c, h, i). Innovations in caselaw on land have a discernible negative effect on per-capita output of the agricultural and industrial sectors (Fig. 12a, b). However, only the negative effect on the agricultural sector is statistically significant at extended horizons.

Fig. 12
figure 12

Responses (non-accumulated) of sectoral real per-capita output variables to law shocks. 90-percent confidence intervals computed using Kilian's (1998) bootstrap method

Appendix D

This appendix presents and discusses the (non-accumulated) impulse-responses of attention to different areas of caselaw to law shocks. The results are summarized in Fig. 13.

Fig. 13
figure 13

The non-accumulated responses of law variables to law shocks. 90-percent confidence intervals computed using Kilian's (1998) bootstrap method

The response in attention to law in one domain as a consequence of a shock in attention to law in another domain shows the coevolutionary character of caselaw. For example, when innovations in one area of law require complementary adjustments in another area of law, then shocks to the first area of law will lead to heightened attention in the second area of law. Law on inheritance and law on families evidence such coevolution (Fig. 13f, g). Innovations in one area of law can resolve issues in another area of law, implying that shocks to the first area of law will lead to reduced attention to the second area of law. In addition, reductions in attention in a given area of law following a shock in another area of law could be a consequence of substitution effects arising from constraints on the time and resources of the courts. While only a subset of the corresponding impulse-responses is statistically significant, this is the nature of the relationship between either law on families or law on inheritance on the one side and law on land on the other side (Fig. 13b, d, g and c).

Finally, following a shock to any single legal domain, later attention to that legal domain initially rises and then gradually declines (Fig. 13a, e and i). External shocks, such as legislation, thus do not immediately result in the resolution of all problems, but rather cause heightened attention to the relevant area of law for an extended time. This is especially true for law on land.

Appendix E

See Figs. 14 and 15

Fig. 14
figure 14

Structural shocks (averages for five-year bins) to the three areas of law

Fig. 15
figure 15

Structural shocks (averages for five-year bins) to demographic and economic variables

Appendix F

See Figs. 16 , 17 and 18

Fig. 16
figure 16

The time series of the attention to the topic Non-Translated Latin

Fig. 17
figure 17

Impulse-responses (non-accumulated) when replacing the Family Law series with the Non-Translated Latin (NTL) series. 90-percent confidence intervals computed using Kilian's (1998) bootstrap method

Fig. 18
figure 18

Impulse-responses (accumulated) when replacing the Family Law series with the Non-Translated Latin (NTL) series. 90-percent confidence intervals computed using Kilian's (1998) bootstrap method

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Grajzl, P., Murrell, P. Of families and inheritance: law and development in England before the Industrial Revolution. Cliometrica 17, 387–432 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-022-00255-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-022-00255-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation