Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Shadow bureaucracies and the unilateral control of international secretariats: Insights from UN peacekeeping

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While formal decision power in most international organizations rests with the member states, the member states often delegate the preparation of decisions to international secretariats. To prepare decisions, secretariats gather and analyze information and subsequently provide the member states with an assessment on the alternative courses of action. In this process, secretariats may accumulate an information surplus over the member states. They can use this advantage to suggest options close to their own interests. This article argues that, to counter such agency problem, the member states unilaterally invest in shadow bureaucracies with the aim to reduce informational asymmetries. Shadow bureaucracies are, however, costly. Member states have to weigh agency costs against the costs of domestic administrative capability. Strong states with outlier preferences are most likely to invest in shadow bureaucracies. They have most to gain. The use of shadow bureaucracies not only reduces agency costs. It also allows states more control over policy in international organizations. This article uses insights from peacekeeping in the United Nations to illustrate the argument.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Feldman et al. present an organizational critique on this economic decision-making model.

  2. See Waterman and Meier (1998) for how principal-agent models work if these assumptions are not met.

  3. The member states acting as a collective principal (Nielson and Tierney 2003) may, in exceptional cases, have the same preferences as the secretariat, yet this does not prevent individual member states from trying to influence the secretariat (Urpelainen 2012).

  4. In addition, secretariats have institutional preferences such as an appetite for larger budgets, more competences and staff (e.g., Vaubel 1986; Pollack 2003; Vaubel et al. 2007; Niskanen 1971).

  5. Some states may have similar preferences as the secretariat. They will thus benefit from secretariat agency and will try to resist collective oversight.

  6. A difference with the model of McCubbins and Schwartz (1984) is that the emphasis in this article is on decision-making rather than implementation. Whereas police-patrols deal with ‘hidden action’, shadow bureaucracies are about uncovering ‘hidden information’ (Arrow 1985).

  7. Panke (2012) finds that within the European Union, the United Kingdom, France, Spain, Finland, Denmark and Germany lobby institutional actors most. These are strong member states with intensive policy preferences. Shadow bureaucracies require more administrative capacity than lobby activities. It is therefore likely that this finding holds as well in the case of shadow bureaucracies.

  8. Multiple agents can also be beneficial in a domestic context. The US State Department, for example, can use the UN assessment to not fully rely on the Department of Defense.

  9. One of the lessons in the keynote Brahimi report is that the Secretariat should not self-censor and be frank with the Security Council (UN 2000, paragraph 59).

  10. Chapter VI provides a legal basis for the “pacific settlement of disputes”, while Chapter VII is about “action with respect to threat to the peace” (UN 1945).

  11. As South Sudan’s biggest oil importer, China has significantly improved its relations with South Sudan since 2011 and takes an increasingly hands-on approach with regard to security issues. It has even contributed an engineering unit to UNMISS. In 2011, China played however much less of a role in the UN negotatiations.

  12. A direct consequence of the intervention was the establishment of the UN Interim Security Force for Abyei (UNISFA). The Ethiopian Prime Minister, Meles Zenawi, decided to send some 4,200, mostly Ethiopian, troops to Abyei under UN flag to deter further violence.

  13. The United States did not even informally discuss the draft resolution with the UN officials, who had planned the mission and would have the responsibility to implement the mission (interviews UN officials).

References

  • Abbott, K., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states act through formal international organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(1), 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aberbach, J. (1987). The congressional committee intelligence system: information, oversight, and change. Congress and the Presidency, 14(1), 51–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aberbach, J. (1990). Keeping a watchful eye: The politics of congressional oversight. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, S., & Yuen, A. (2014). The politics of peacekeeping: UN security council oversight across peacekeeping missions. International Studies Quarterly. doi:10.1111/isqu.12086.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1963). Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. The American Economic Review, 53(5), 941–973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1985). The economics of agency. In J. Pratt & R. Zechhauser (Eds.), Principals and agents: The structure of business. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barston, R. (2013). Modern diplomacy (4th ed.). Harlow: Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bendor, J., Taylor, S., & Van Gaalen, R. (1985). Bureaucratic expertise versus legislative authority: a model of deception and monitoring in budgeting. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 1041–1060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benner, T., Mergenthaler, S., & Rotmann, P. (2011). The new world of UN peace operations: Learning to build peace? Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Breakley, H., & Dekker, S. (2014). Weak links in the chain of authority: the challenges of intervention decisions to protect civilians. International Peacekeeping. doi:10.1080/13533312.2014.928572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broome, A. (2014). Back to basics: the great recession and the narrowing of IMF policy advice. Governance. doi:10.1111/gove.12098.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bull, H. (1977). The Anarchical Society: a study of order in world politics. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charlemagne (2014). The euro’s hellhound. The Economist, 1 February. http://www.economist.com/news/europe/21595432-it-time-reform-troika-handles-euro-zone-bail-outs-euros-hellhound. Accessed 10 March 2014.

  • Comprehensive Peace Agreement (9 January 2005). http://peacemaker.un.org/sites/peacemaker.un.org/files/SD_060000_The%20Comprehensive%20Peace%20Agreement.pdf. Accessed 27 May 2013.

  • Copelovitch, M. (2010). Master or servant? common agency and the political economy of IMF lending. International Studies Quarterly, 54(1), 49–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunliffe, P. (2009). The politics of global governance in UN peacekeeping. International Peacekeeping, 16(3), 323–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day, J. (2013). Letter from the chairman of the joint intelligence committee to the prime minister on Syria: Reported chemical weapons use. London: White Hall, Cabinet Office. 29 August.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra, H. (2012). Efficiency versus sovereignty: delegation to the UN secretariat in peacekeeping. International Peacekeeping, 19(5), 581–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra, H. (2013). Policy-making in EU security and defense: An institutional perspective. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra, H. (2015). Functionalism, multiple principals and the reform of the NATO secretariat after the cold war. Cooperation and Conflict. doi:10.1177/0010836714532919.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, R. (1974). Supplier-induced demand: some empirical evidence and implications. In M. Perlman (Ed.), The economics of health and medical care (pp. 162–173). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M. (1989). Order without design: Information production and policy making. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M., & March, J. (1981). Information in organizations as signal and symbol. Administrative Science Quarterly, 26(2), 171–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. (1982). Legislative choice of regulatory forms: legal process or administrative process? Public Choice, 39(1), 33–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French Government (2013). Programme chimique syrien: Cas d’emploi passés d’agents chimiques par le régime: Attaque chimique conduite par le régime le 21 août 2013, 2 September. http://www.gouvernement.fr/sites/default/files/fichiers_joints/syrie_synthese_nationale_de_renseignement_declassifie_02_09_2013.pdf. Accessed 28 January 2014.

  • George, A. (1980). Presidential decisionmaking in foreign policy: The effective use of information and advice. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, D., Lake, D., Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (Eds.). (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Huber, J., & Shipan, C. (2002). Deliberate discretion? The institutional foundations of bureaucratic autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, D., & McCubbins, M. (1991). The logic of delegation: Congressional parties and the appropriations process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lake, D., & McCubbins, M. (2006). The logic of delegation to international organizations. In D. Hawkins et al. (Eds.), Delegation and agency in international organizations (pp. 341–68). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lipson, M. (2010). Performance under ambiguity: international organization performance in UN peacekeeping. The Review of International Organizations, 5(3), 249–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A., & McCubbins, M. (1994). Who controls? information and the structure of legislative decision making. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 19(3), 361–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. (2006). Distribution, information, and delegation to international organizations: the case of IMF conditionality. In D. Hawkins et al. (Eds.), Delegation and agency in international organizations (pp. 140–164). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: police patrols versus fire alarms. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 165–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: agency theory and World Bank environmental reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2013). South Sudan – Disbursements of bilateral ODA by donor and sector (2011). Aid statistics by recipient and sector. http://www.oecd.org/dac/stats/documentupload/DataDonorRecipientSectorChart.zip. Accessed on 18 November 2013.

  • Panke, D. (2012). Lobbying institutional key players: how states seek to influence the European commission, the council presidency and the European parliament. Journal of Common Market Studies, 50(1), 129–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollack, M. (1997). Delegation, agency, and agenda setting in the European community. International Organization, 51(1), 99–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollack, M. (2003). The engines of European integration: delegation, agency, and agenda setting in the EU. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Raiffa, H. (1968). Decision analysis: Introductory lectures on choices under uncertainty. Reading: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Secretary of State (2014). Congressional Budget Justification: Appendix 1, Fiscal Year 2015. http://www.state.gov/documents/organization/223495.pdf. Accessed 17 July 2014.

  • Security Council Report (2011). Resolution on a UN mission in South Sudan. 6 July. http://www.whatsinblue.org/2011/07/rsolution-on-a-new-mission-in-sudan.php. Accessed 26 November 2013.

  • Sridhar, D., & Woods, N. (2013). Trojan multilateralism: global cooperation in health. Global Policy, 4(4), 325–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Swigert, J. (2004). Challenges of Peacekeeping in Africa. Statement before the Africa Subcommittee of the House International Relations Committee, 8 October. http://2001-2009.state.gov/p/io/rls/rm/2004/39154.htm. Accessed 27 August 2014.

  • Thatcher, M., & Stone Sweet, A. (2002). Theory and practice of delegation to non-majoritarian institutions. West European Politics, 25(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, E. (2009). Against the gathering storm securing Sudan’s comprehensive peace agreement. London: Chatham House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • UN (1945). Charter of the United Nations. http://treaties.un.org/doc/Publication/CTC/uncharter.pdf. Accessed 18 November 2013.

  • UN (2000). Report of the Panel on United Nations Peace Operations [Brahimi Report]. A/55/305 – S/2000/809, 21 August.

  • UN (2008). United Nations Peacekeeping Operations: Principles and Guidelines [Capstone Doctrine]. New York: Department of Peacekeeping Operations and Department of Field Support, 18 January.

  • UN (2009a). A New Partnership Agenda: Charting A New Horizon for UN Peacekeeping. New York: Department of Peacekeeping Operations and Department of Field Support, July.

  • UN (2009b). IMPP Guidelines: Role of the Headquarters. Internal document approved by the UN Secretary-General, May.

  • UN (2011a). Report of the Secretary-General on the Sudan. S/2011/239, 14 April.

  • UN (2011b). Special report of the Secretary-General on the Sudan. S/2011/314, 17 May.

  • UN (2011c). Permanent Missions to the United Nations. ST/SG/SER.A/301, New York: United Nations, Executive Office of the Secretary-General, Protocol and Liaison Service, March.

  • UN (2014). Report of the Office of Internal Oversight Services on Evaluation of the implementation and results of protection of civilians mandates in United Nations peacekeeping operations. A/68/787, 7 March.

  • UN (n.d.[a]). UNMIS Background. http://www.un.org/en/peacekeeping/missions/unmis/background.shtml. Accessed 28 May 2013.

  • UN (n.d.[b]). Financing Peacekeeping. http://www.un.org/en/peacekeeping/operations/financing.shtml. Accessed 17 July 2014.

  • UNSC (2011). Press Statement by Mr Gérard Araud, President of the Security Council. 22 May. http://www.franceonu.org/france-at-the-united-nations/press-room/speaking-to-the-media/remarks-to-the-press/article/22-may-2011-abyei-sudan-press. Accessed 4 July 2013.

  • Urpelainen, J. (2012). Unilateral influence on international bureaucrats: an international delegation problem. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56(4), 704–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • US General Accounting Office (2001). U.N. Peacekeeping: Executive Branch Consultations With Congress Did Not Fully Meet Expectations in 1999-2000. Report to Congressional Requesters. GAO-01-917, September.

  • Vaubel, R. (1986). A public choice approach to international organization. Public Choice, 51(1), 39–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaubel, R., Dreher, A., & Soylu, U. (2007). Staff growth in international organizations: a principal-agent problem? an empirical analysis. Public Choice, 133(3–4), 275–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waterman, R., & Meier, K. (1998). Principal-agent models: an expansion? Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 8(2), 173–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinlich, S. (2014). The UN secretariat’s influence on the evolution of peacekeeping. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • White House (2013). Government Assessment of the Syrian Government’s Use of Chemical Weapons on August 21, 2013. Washington, DC: White House, Office of the Press Secretary, 30 August. http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2013/08/30/government-assessment-syrian-government-s-use-chemical-weapons-august-21. Accessed 28 January 2014.

Download references

Acknowledgments

This article was previously presented at workshops in Oxford and Maastricht in December 2013, and at the ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops in Salamanca in April 2014. The author wishes to thank Michael W. Bauer, Derek Beach, Mareike Kleine, Duncan Snidal, all other participants at these workshops as well as the two anonymous reviewers and editor for their helpful comments.

The research leading to these results has received funding from the People Programme (Marie Curie Actions) of the European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007-2013) under REA grant agreement n° [298081].

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hylke Dijkstra.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dijkstra, H. Shadow bureaucracies and the unilateral control of international secretariats: Insights from UN peacekeeping. Rev Int Organ 10, 23–41 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-014-9203-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-014-9203-7

Keywords

Navigation