Skip to main content
Log in

Democracies only: When do IMF agreements serve as a seal of approval?

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Conditional lending by the IMF is predicated, in part, on the belief that IMF programs are associated with increased capital inflows to participating countries. This belief is generally consistent with theoretical arguments in the academic literature (e.g., Bird and Rowlands 1997; Bordo et al. 2004) but the empirical literature often finds otherwise (e.g., Jensen 2004). This paper argues that the effect of IMF agreements on a country’s access to foreign direct investment (FDI) depends on its domestic institutions. Access to FDI depends on a country’s ability to credibly commit to implementation, and this ability varies systematically across regime type. The theory is empirically tested using a treatment effects model with a Markov transition in the treatment equation in a dataset covering 142 countries from 1976 to 2006. We find that in democracies IMF program participation has a strong positive effect on FDI inflows and in autocracies participation has a weak negative effect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Throughout the paper we refer to the IMF as “lending” and to countries as “borrowing,” however, technically the IMF does not “lend” money and countries do not “borrow” money. Officially, the countries can make purchases by exchanging their currency for the equivalent of another members’ currency or Special Drawing Rights (SDR), and then the country repurchases its own currency over time. The IMF places charges on these purchases and thus the purchase and repurchase is equivalent to making a loan with interest.

  2. The model we use is a treatment effects model with a built in first order Markov process in the treatment equation. Throughout the rest of the paper we refer to the model as a “treatment effects Markov transition model.”

  3. For example, according to the former Managing Director of the IMF, the Fund’s “prime objective is growth…there is no longer any ambiguity about this. It is towards growth that our programs and their conditionality are aimed” (Polak 1991, 19).

  4. In a review of IMF compliance Vreeland (2006) discusses how consensus has emerged that IMF agreements tend to have unfavorable macroeconomic effects, but it is unclear if this is the result of poor policy choices or policy compliance. We believe that it is a result of lack of compliance and not poor policy prescriptions, though the empirics here are difficult to untangle (see, for example, Mercer-Blackman and Unigovskaya 2004). Although some attempts have been made at disentangling implementation and participation (e.g., Arpac et al. 2008), we argue these attempts have been modest at best. Including a measure of implementation in the econometric analysis limits the dataset, and all of the measures of implementation are indirect and tangential to the concept.

  5. In practice, failure to comply with the conditions of IMF loans is not, in all cases, followed with a fall from good standing or the withholding of future tranches of funding (Vreeland 2006; Dreher 2002).

  6. There are anecdotal examples of countries requiring approval from other branches of government. For example, Brazil needs approval of the Parliament to get a new loan, but not to continue or rollover an existing one (http://www.brettonwoodsproject.org/art-27514). However, examples such as these are exceptions rather than the rule.

  7. This argument is not necessarily incompatible with that made by Fang and Owen (2011), who argue that non-democratic states have a greater need to employ IMF agreements as a means to make their promises of reform more credible. It is possible both for participation in an IMF agreement to be the only option available to autocracies to make their commitments to reform more credible, and for the effectiveness of this device to be weak.

  8. Pooling across different types of IMF agreements, as is standard in the literature, is potentially problematic, as conditionality varies by agreement type. Empirical differentiation by agreement type could potentially produce further insight into the causal mechanism behind the catalytic affect of IMF participation. However, this differentiation is beyond the scope of this paper.

  9. All independent variables are lagged 1 year unless otherwise noted. The dependent variables are measured in time t; so to obviate simultaneity, all the independent variables are measured at time t−1.

  10. The net measure of investment varies for each model, depending on which specification of the dependent variable is used.

  11. We do not include time dummies because WorldFDI captures the relevant time trends. However, the results are robust to the inclusion of time dummies. The Hausman test and the test statistic are significant, indicating that it is necessary to include country fixed effects.

  12. Beck and Katz suggest that LSDV is strictly preferable to alternative estimators when T is greater than 20, and that it likely remains preferable for values of T somewhat less than 20 as well (2004, p. 15). Our substantive results do not require direct interpretation of the coefficient on the lagged dependent variable, and results are robust to omission of the country fixed effects.

  13. The descriptive statistics for both the Democracy and LIEC measures can be found in the Appendix.

  14. Calculating the Durbin Watson statistic indicated the presence of correlated errors, and that Beck and Katz’s suggestions apply to the data used in this analysis.

  15. If there is reverse causality between an independent variable and a dependent variable, and the dependent variable is determined simultaneously with at least one of the regressors, endogeneity bias may also be a problem. For endogeneity bias, the dependent variable is observed for all observations of the data. In contrast, sample selection bias arises when the dependent variable is observed only for a restricted, nonrandom sample of observations.

  16. For a thorough discussion of this problem see Steinwand and Stone (2008). However, while most of the recent literature addresses selection into IMF agreements, it does so without addressing the dynamic nature of IMF lending, which the selection equation by itself does not correct for. For example, see Abouharb and Cingranelli (2009).

  17. The following discussion is heavily dependent on Angrist et al. (1996) and Jensen (2004).

  18. Including a lagged dependent variable corrects for serial correlation, but also soaks up much of the variation. This is well known in the literature (see Achen 2000). Running the models without the lagged dependent variable should produce results with asymptotically correct coefficients, but with larger statistical significance.

  19. Recidivism is common among participants in IMF arrangements. Countries which participate in an IMF agreement in time t−1 are far more likely to be under an agreement in time t than countries not under an agreement in time t−1.

  20. As Ai and Norton (2003) point out, the magnitude of the interaction effect in non-linear models does not equal the marginal effect of the interaction term. In the Appendix, we plot both the Stata-estimated (incorrect) marginal effect and the correct interaction effect for the interaction of LIEC and Under.

  21. The full tables are displayed in the Appendix.

References

  • Abouharb, R., & Cingranelli, D. L. (2009). IMF programs and human rights. The Review of International Organizations, 4, 47–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Achen, C. (2000). “Why lagged dependent variables can supress the explanatory power of other independent variables.” Presented at the annual meeting of the Society for Political Methodology, UCLA.

  • Adji, S. S., Ahn, Y. S., Holsey, C. M., & Willett, T. D. (1997). Political capacity, macroeconomic factors, and capital flows. In M. Arbetman & J. Kugler (Eds.), Political capacity and economic behavior (pp. 127–148). Boulder: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economic Letters, 80, 123–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist, J. D., Imbens, G. W., & Rubin, D. B. (1996). Identification of causal effects using instrumental variables. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 91(434), 444–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arpac, O., Bird, G., & Mandilaras, A. (2008). Stop interrupting: an empirical analysis of the implementation of IMF programs. World Development, 36(9), 1493–1513.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W. (2005). IMF programs: who is chosen and what are the effects? Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1245–1269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. (1995). What to do (and not to do) with time- series-cross-section data. American Political Science Review, 89, 634–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. (2004). Time-Series-Cross-Section Issues: Dynamics. Unpublished manuscript. http://www.nyu.edu/gsas/dept/politics/faculty/beck/beckkatz.pdf. Accessed 11/01/2009.

  • Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: the database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berlinschi, R. (2010). Reputation concerns in aid conditionality. Review of International Organizations, 5(4), 433–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird, G., & Rowlands, D. (1997). The catalytic effect of lending of the international financial institutions. The World Economy, 24(1), 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird, G., & Rowlands, D. (2001). The catalysis of direct borrowing: the role of the IMF in mobilising private capital markets. The World Economy, 45(1), 115–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, G., & Rowlands, D. (2009). The IMF's role in mobilizing private capital flows: are there grounds for catalytic conversion? Applied Economic Letters, 16(17), 1705–1708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo, M. D., Mody, A., & Oomes, N. (2004). Keeping capital flowing: the role of the IMF. International Finance, 7(3), 421–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2009). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice.

  • Collier, P. (1999). Learning from failure: the international financial institutions as agencies of restraint in Africa. In A. Schedler, L. J. Diamond & M. F. Plattner (Eds.), The self-restraining state: power and accountability in new democracies. Boulder: Lynn Rienner Publishers.

  • Dhonte, P. (1997). Conditionality as an instrument of borrower credibility, IMF Working Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment. 97/2. Washington, DC: IMF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2002). Conditionality and ownership in IMF lending: a political economy approach. IMF Staff Papers, 49, 36–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2002). The development and implementation of IMF and World Bank Conditionality. Hamburgisches Welt-Wirtschafts-Archiv Discussion Paper, No. 185. Hamburg Institute of International Economics, Hamburg, Germany. http://ideas.repec.org/p/ags/hiiedp/26352.html.

  • Dreher, A. (2006). IMF and economic growth: the effects of programs, loans, and compliance with conditionality. World Development, 34(5), 769–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, M. S. (2005). Investor responses to IMF program suspensions: is noncom-pliance costly? Social Science Quarterly, 86(4), 857–873.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, S., & Owen, E. (2011). International institutions and credible commitment of non-democracies. Review of International Organizations, Online First.

  • Ferree, K. E., & Singh, S. (1999). Institutional change and economic performance in Africa, 1970–1995. Paper presented at the 1999 meetings of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta Ga.

  • Fischer, S. (1999). On the Need for an International Lender of Last Resort. Prepared for delivery at the joint luncheon of the American Economic Association and the American Finance Association, New York, January 3, 1999. Available at www.imf.org.

  • Haggard, S. (1985). The politics of adjustment: lessons from the IMF’s Extended Fund Facility. International Organization, 39(3), 505–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hajivassiliou, V. (1987). The external debt repayment problem of LDCs: an econometric model based on panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 36, 205–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haque, N., & Khan, M. S. (1998). Do IMF-supported programs work? A survey of the cross-country empirical evidence. IMF Working Paper WP/98/169. International Monetary Fund.

  • Hellman, J. S. (1998). Winners take all: the politics of partial reform in postcommunist transitions. World Politics, 50, 203–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N. M. (2004). Crisis, conditions, and capital. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(2), 194–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N. M., Malesky, E. J., & Weymouth, S. (2010). Binding the Grabbing Hand: legislatures and expropriation risk in authoritarian regimes. Chicago: Midwest Political Science Association Conference.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahler, M. (1992). External influence, conditionality, and the politics of adjustment. In S. Haggard & R. R. Kaufman (Eds.), The politics of economic adjustment (pp. 89–136). Princeton University Press.

  • Kaufman, R., & Stallings, B. (Eds.). (1989). Debt and democracy in Latin America. Boulder: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P., & Khemani, S. (2005). Democracy, public expenditures, and the poor. World Bank Research Observer, 20, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P., & Stasavage, D. (2003). The limits of delegation: veto players, Central Bank independence and the credibility of monetary policy. American Political Science Review, 97(3), 407–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohler, H. (2001). Promoting stability and prosperity in a globalized world. Remarks by IMF Managing Director, Council of the Americas, Washington, DC, May 7. Available online at http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/050701.htm.

  • Knight, M., & Santaella, J. A. (1997). Economic determinants of IMF financial arrangements. Journal of Development Economics, 54(2), 405–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddala, G. S. (1983). Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Mercer-Blackman, V., & Unigovskaya, A. (2004). Compliance with IMF program indicators and growth in transition economies. Emerging Markets, Finance and Trade, 40(3), 55–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mody, A., & Saravia, D. (2002). Catalyzing capital flows: do IMF programs work as commitment devices? Washington, DC: IMF Working Paper.

  • Mody, A., & Saravia, D. (2006). Catalysing private capital flows: do IMF programmes work as commitment devices? The Economic Journal, 116, 843–867.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pepinsky, T. B. (2009). Economic crises and the breakdown of authoritarian regimes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Polak, J. J. (1991). The changing nature of IMF conditionality. Princeton Essays in International Finance no. 184. Princeton: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (1991). Democracy and the market: political and economic reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (1993). Democracy and the market: Political and economic reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1995). Why is there multilateral lending? DEPR Discussion Papers 1207.

  • Rowlands, D. (2001). The response of other lenders to the IMF. Review of International Economics, 9(3), 531–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schadler, S., Bennett, A., Carkovic, M., Dicks-Mireaux, L., Mecagni, M., Morsink, J. H. J., et al. (1995). IMF conditionality: experience under stand-by and extended fund arrangements: part I: key issues and findings, and part II: Background Papers. IMF Occasional Papers. No. 128 and No. 129. IMF, Washington, September.

  • Sheahan, J. (1987). Patterns of development in Latin America: Poverty, repression and economic strategy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slantchev, B. (2005). The political economy of simultaneous transitions: an empirical test of two models. Political Research Quarterly, 58(2), 279–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinwand, M. C., & Stone, R. W. (2008). The International monetary fund: a review of the recent evidence. The Review of International Organizations, 3, 123–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vreeland, J. R. (2001). The effect of IMF programs on labor. World Development, 30(1), 121–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vreeland, J. R. (2003). The IMF and economic development. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vreeland, J. R. (2006). IMF program compliance: aggregate index versus policy specific research strategies. Review of Intern ational Organizations, 1, 359–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Further Reading

  • Biglaiser, G., & DeRouen, K., Jr. (2010). The effects of IMF programs on U.S. foreign direct investment in the developing world. Review of International Organizations, 5, 73–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broome, A. (2008). The importance of being earnest: the IMF as a reputational intermediary. New Political Economy, 13(2), 125–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardoso, E., & Helwege, A. (1993). Latin America’s economy: diversity, trends, and conflicts. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connors, T. A. (1979). The apparent effects of recent IMF stabilization programs. International Finance Discussion Papers 135. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

  • Conway, P. (1994). IMF lending programs: participation and impact. Journal of Development Economics, 45, 365–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crisp, B. F., & Kelly, M. J. (1999). The socioeconomic impacts of structural adjustment. International Studies Quarterly, 43(3), 533–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dicks-Mireaux, L., Mecagni, M., & Schadler, S. (2000). Evaluating the e_ect of IMF lending to low-income countries. Journal of Development Economics, 61, 495–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. (1993). Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Wokingham: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garuda, G. (2000). The distributional effects of IMF programs: a cross-country analysis. World Development, 28(6), 1031–1051.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gylfason, T. (1987). Credit policy and economic activity in developing countries with IMF stabilization programs. Princeton: Studies in International Finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan, M. (1990). The macroeconomic effects of fund-supported adjustment programs. IMF Staff Papers, 37(2).

  • Killick, T. (1995). IMF programmes in developing countries: design and impact. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Killick, T., Malik, M., & Marcus, M. (1992). What can we know about the effects of IMF programmes? World Economy, 15, 575–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loxley, J. (1984). The IMF and the poorest countries: the performance of the least developed countries under IMF stand-by arrangements. Ottawa: The North-South Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marchesi, S., & Thomas, J. P. (1999). IMF conditionality as a screening device. The Economic Journal, 109(454), 111–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marchesi, S., Sabani, L., & Dreher, A. (2011). Read my lips: the role of information transmission in multilateral reform design. Journal of International Economics, 84(1), 86–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris, S., & Shin, H. S. (2006). Catalytic finance: when does it work? Journal of International Economics, 70, 161–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor, M., Jr. (1987). The effects of IMF participation in the third world: debate and evidence from Latin America. World Development, 15(2), 249–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A., & Vreeland, J. R. (2000). The effects of IMF programs on economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(2), 385–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R. (2008). The scope of IMF conditionality. International Organization, 62(Fall), 589–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, S. E., & Butler, D. M. (2007). A lot more to do: the sensitivity of time-series cross-section analyses to simple alternative specifications. Political Analysis, 15(2), 101–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Benjamin A. T. Graham.

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

bcg_data.dta (DTA 20664 kb)

bcg_ROIO2011_replication_5-1-11.do (DO 7 kb)

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Estimation of Interaction Effects

The following plots give both the simple probit-estimated (incorrect) marginal effect and the correct interaction effect for the interaction between LIEC and Under (Ai and Norton 2003). Despite the large differences in the estimated effects, the z-scores from both estimation techniques are nearly identical across all three models. We omit plots of the z-scores from this appendix, but these can be created from the replication do file available at the Review of International Organization’s webpage.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Pooled

Fig. 4
figure 4

Democracies only

Fig. 5
figure 5

Autocracies only

Table 8  
Table 9 Treatment effects model with a Markov transition

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bauer, M.E., Cruz, C. & Graham, B.A.T. Democracies only: When do IMF agreements serve as a seal of approval?. Rev Int Organ 7, 33–58 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-011-9122-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-011-9122-9

Keywords

Navigation