Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The demand for transparency: An empirical note

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

By encouraging socially wasteful rent seeking and corruption, natural resources abundance might not be a blessing but a country’s curse. A recent attempt to impede these practices of corruption with theft is the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI). The purpose of this organization is to verify and fully publish company payments and government revenues from oil, gas, and mining. Using a probit estimation technique the paper analyses empirically the political and socio-economic factors which determine a country’s participation in EITI, which can be interpreted as revealed willingness to reform.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Kolstad and Wiig (2009) for a comprehensive survey of reasons why low transparency might lead to high corruption, many of which are not relevant here, however, as we only deal with transparency of resource revenues.

  2. Alternatively, IMF (2007), Appendix I, lists 31 resource-rich non-OECD countries that were not participants in the EITI process in January 2008.

  3. These initiating countries were: Chad, Democratic Republic of Congo, Equatorial Guinea, Madagascar, Republic of Congo, Sao Tome and Principe, Sierra Leone, Trinidad and Tobago, and Timor-Leste. Candidate countries as of November 2007 were Azerbaijan, Cameroon, Gabon, Ghana, Guinea, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Liberia, Mali, Mauritania, Mongolia, Niger, Nigeria, Peru, and Yemen. In February 2008, 7 “initiating countries” actually became “candidates”.

  4. This does not mean that they have been found guilty of window dressing at the time when EITI was joined or later; slow progress might be due to other factors (like the general election held in Trinidad and Tobago in fall 2007, but this is speculative). Chad was dropped from our regressions anyway due to missing data.

  5. On the other hand, transparency should complement accountability, as it facilitates relating misconduct to a certain individual (Boehm and Olaya, 2006, p.440).

  6. As far as EITI membership is a means of window dressing, there is no reason why this hypothesis should hold. This is one mechanism how window dressing, unobservable to us, might increase the error term.

  7. In ancillary regressions, available upon request, we also tried EITIcandidate (1 if the country is a candidate country, and 0 otherwise), EITIearly (1 if the country attended the EITI Lancaster House Conference in June 2003), and EITIsteps (2 for candidate countries, 1 for initiating countries and 0 otherwise for ordered probit), with qualitative results being no different from our current ones, though EITIearly led to a markedly worse fit.

  8. Data are not available for Equatorial Guinea, Liberia, Chad, Democratic Republic of Congo and Timor-Leste.

  9. We excluded all OECD members and EU member countries, as well as oversea territories of France (DOM-TOM).

  10. As one referee suggested, a further caveat might be that more corrupt countries are EITI target countries, and hence it should not come as a surprise that higher levels of (political) corruption increase the probability of participation. We cannot rule out that argument completely, although the EITI is formally not exclusively designed to address the most corrupt countries, but resource-rich countries instead. Resource-abundance and corruption indices are not correlated, however. Moreover, it seems unlikely that ‘corrupt countries’ be more likely to join the EITI simply because they are targeted countries.

  11. No data are available for years closer to 2006.

  12. Postscript: In 2009, it did.

  13. But see a recent pessimistic assessment of the progress to be expected from EITI by Kolstad and Wiig (2009, section 6–7).

References

  • Alesina, A., et al. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Ardagna, S., & Trebbi, F. (2006). Who adjusts and when? On the political economy of reforms. IMF Staff Papers, 53, 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amin, M., & Djankov, S. (2009). Natural resources and reforms, CEPR DP 7229.

  • Andvig, J. C. (1991). The economics of corruption: a survey. Studi economici, 43, 57–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andvig, J. C., & Moene, K. O. (1990). How corruption may corrupt. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 13, 63–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard, H., Fischbacher, U., & Fehr, E. (2006). Parochial altruism in humans. Nature, 442, 912–915.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, D. A., Kuh, E., & Welsch, R. E. (1980). Regression diagnostics: Identifying influential data and sources of collinearity. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boehm, F., & Olaya, J. (2006). Corruption and public contracting auctions: the role of transparency in bidding processes. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 77, 431–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P. (2000). Ethnicity, politics and economic performance. Economics and Politics, 12, 225–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2009). Disclosure by Politicians, Tuck School of Business Working Paper No. 2009–60.

  • Drazen, A., & Grilli, V. (1993). The benefit of crises for economic reforms. American Economic Review, 83, 598–607.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., & Voigt, S. (2008). Does membership in international organizations increase governments’ credibility? Testing the effects of delegating powers, CESifo Working Paper 2285, www.cesifo-group.de/~DocCIDL/cesifo1_wp2285.pdf.

  • Easterly, W. (2001). Can institutions resolve ethnic conflict? Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49, 687–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freedom House (2006). Freedom in the world country ratings, New York.

  • Griffin, J. M., & Neilson, W. S. (1994). The 1985–1986 oil price collapse and afterwards: what does game theory add? Economic Enquiry, 32, 543–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2006). Penn World Table Version 6.2, Center for international comparisons of production, income and prices at the University of Pennsylvania, September 2006.

  • Hodler, R. (2006). The curse of natural resources in fractionalized countries. European Economic Review, 50, 1376–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2007). Guide on resource revenue transparency, Washington: http://imf.org/external/np/pp/2007/eng/101907g.pdf.

  • Isham, J., et al. (2004). The varieties of resource experience: natural resource export structures and the political economy of growth. World Bank Economic Review, 19, 141–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2007). Governance matters VI: Aggregate and individual governance indicators 1996–2006, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4280.

  • Kolstad, I., & Wiig, A. (2009). Is transparency the key to reducing corruption in resource-rich countries? World Development, 37, 521–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad, I., & Søreide, T. (2009). Corruption in natural resource management: Implications for policymakers, to be published in: Resources Policy, doi:10.1016/j.resourpol.2009.05.001.

  • Lambsdorff, J. G. (2006). Causes and consequences of corruption: What do we know from a cross-section of countries? In S. Rose-Ackerman (Ed.), International handbook on the economics of corruption (pp. 3–51). Cheltenham: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15, 222–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leite, C., & Weidmann, J. (2002). Does mother nature corrupt? Natural resources, corruption, and economic growth. In G. T. Abed & S. Gupta (Eds.), Governance, corruption, & economic performance (pp. 159–196). Washington: IMF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindstedt, C., & Naurin, D. (2006). Transparency against corruption. A cross-country analysis, mimeo: www.qog.pol.gu.se/research/reports/Lindstedt_Naurin.pdf.

  • Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D. L. (1974). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In P. Zarembka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics (pp. 105–142). Academic: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? American Economic Review, 83(2), 409–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (2008). Perspectives on mechanism design in economic theory. American Economic Review, 98, 586–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naurin, D. (2006). Transparency, publicity, accountability—the missing links. Swiss Political Science Review, 12, 90–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ölcer, D. (2009). Extracting the maximum from the EITI, OECD Development Centre Working Paper No. 276, Paris.

  • Olken, B. A. (2005). Corruption and the costs of redistribution: Micro evidence from Indonesia, mimeo: NBER.

  • Pitlik, H. (2007). A race to liberalization? Diffusion of economic policy reforms among OECD-economies. Public Choice, 132, 159–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitlik, H. (2008). The impact of growth performance and political regime type on economic policy liberalization. Kyklos, 61, 258–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitlik, H., & Wirth, S. (2003). Do crises promote the extent of economic liberalization? An empirical test. European Journal of Political Economy, 19, 565–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (2007). E Pluribus Unum: diversity and community in the twenty-first century. Scandinavian Political Studies, 30, 137–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (1999). The big rush, natural resource booms and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 59(1), 43–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin, X., & Subramanian, A. (2003). Addressing the natural resource curse: An illustration from Nigeria, NBER Working Paper 9804, Cambridge/Mass.

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staehr, K. (2007). Linkages between political and economic reforms in the post-communist countries, mimeo.

  • Tang, M.-K., & Wei, S.-J. (2009). The value of making commitments externally: evidence from WTO accessions. Journal of International Economics, 78, 216–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations Development Program UNDP (2008). A user’s guide to measuring corruption, Oslo.

  • World Bank (2001). Global development network growth database, http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/0,,contentMDK:20701055~pagePK:64214825~piPK:64214943~theSitePK:469382,00.html.

  • World Bank (2006). Where is the wealth of nations? Measuring capital for the 21st century, Washington.

  • World Trade Organization (2008). International Trade Statistics 2007, http://stat.wto.org/StatisticalProgram/WSDBStatProgramSeries.aspx?Language=E.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Björn Frank.

Additional information

We are indebted to the editor, two anonymous referees, Martin Gassebner, Johann Graf Lambsdorff, Roland Menges, Martin Paldam, Friedrich Schneider, Stanley Winer, conference participants at the Public Choice Society 2008 Meetings in San Antonio and Jena, as well as seminar participants at Clausthal and Dresden, especially Mathias Erlei and M. Reza Farzanegan, for very helpful comments, and to Beverley Locke for polishing the style.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(DO 6 kb)

ESM 2

(DTA 41 kb)

ESM 3

Variables in data set “The Demand for Transparency” by Firchow, Frank and Pitlik (PDF 29 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Pitlik, H., Frank, B. & Firchow, M. The demand for transparency: An empirical note. Rev Int Organ 5, 177–195 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-009-9073-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-009-9073-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation