Skip to main content
Log in

Information flows and crashes in dynamic social networks

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a dynamic model of information transmission and aggregation in social networks in which continued membership in the network is contingent on the accuracy of opinions. Agents have opinions about a state of the world and form links to others in a directed fashion probabilistically. Agents update their opinions by averaging those of their connections, weighted by how long their connections have been in the system. Agents survive or die based on how far their opinions are from the true state. In contrast to the results in the extant literature on DeGroot learning, we show through simulations that for some parameterizations the model cycles stochastically between periods of high connectivity, in which agents arrive at a consensus opinion close to the state, and periods of low connectivity, in which agents’ opinions are widely dispersed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Absent detailed information about the network topology, such as the links among analysts, we use the number of agents in the network as a proxy for the relative magnitudes of the numbers of connections.

  2. This condition on \(k^*\) ensures that the probability of death in (3) is bounded by zero and one.

  3. The model is written in the Python programming language (Python xxx) using the NetworkX (Hagberg et al. 2008) and Pandas (McKinney 2012) packages. Seed values for runs are randomly chosen but are stored for potential later use. We establish a “burn-in” period at the beginning of a run of the model. At the beginning of the burn-in period, all agents have uniformly drawn k-values and zero connections. The burn-in period ends when all agents have died at least once, after which the model run is considered to begin and time is reset to \(t=0\).

  4. Using the terminology in Golub and Jackson (2010), the singleton set containing the last agent is the only “closed group,” and thus the only minimal closed group, relative to \({\mathbf {W}}\) in (9). Then, (10) follows from Theorem 3 in Golub and Jackson (2010).

  5. Other cutoff values for state classification produce similar results.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A (2011) Opinion dynamics and learning in social networks. Dyn Games Appl 1(1):3–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bala V, Goyal S (2000) A noncooperative model of network formation. Econometrica 68(5):1181–1229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandrasekhar AG, Larreguy H, Xandri JP (2015) Testing models of social learning on networks: evidence from a lab experiment in the field. NBER Working Paper No. 21468, National Bureau of Economic Research, August 2015

  • DeGroot MH (1974) Reaching a consensus. J Am Stat Assoc 69(345):118–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeMarzo PM, Vayanos D, Zwiebel J (2003) Persuasion bias, social influence, and unidimensional opinions. Quart J Econ 118(3):909–968

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golub B, Jackson MO (2010) Naive learning in social networks and the wisdom of crowds. Am Econ J Microecon 2(1):112–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimm V, Mengel F (2020) An experiment on belief formation in networks. J Euro Econ Assoc 18(1):49–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagberg AA, Schult DA, Swart PJ (2008) Exploring network structure, dynamics, and function using NetworkX. In: Proceedings of the 7th python in science conference (SciPy2008) pp 11–15, Pasadena, CA, USA, 2008

  • Hegselmann R, Krause U (2002) Opinion dynamics and bounded confidence, models, analysis and simulation. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 5(3). http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/5/3/2.html

  • Hegselmann R, Krause U (2005) Opinion dynamics driven by various ways of averaging. Comput Econ 25(4):381–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson MO, Rogers BW (2007) Meeting strangers and friends of friends: how random are social networks? Am Econ Rev 97(3):890–915

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson MO, Watts A (2002) The evolution of social and economic networks. J Econ Theory 106:265–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz J (2005) A stabilization theorem for dynamics of continuous opinions. Phys A 355(1):217–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz J (2006a) Convergence of products of stochastic matrices with positive diagonals and the opinion dynamics background. In: Positive systems, pp 209–216

  • Lorenz J (2006b) Consensus strikes back in the Hegselmann-Krause model of continuous opinion dynamics under bounded confidence. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 9(1). http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/9/1/8.html

  • McKinney W (2012) Python for data analysis: data wrangling with pandas, numPy, and IPython. O’Reilly, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirtabatabaei A, Bullo F (2012) Opinion dynamics in heterogeneous networks: convergence conjectures and theorems. SIAM J Control Opt 50(5):2763–2785

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreau L (2005) Stability of multiagent systems with time-dependent communication links. IEEE Trans Autom Control 50(2):169–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller-Frank M, Neri C (2020) A general analysis of boundedly rational learning in social networks. Forthcoming in Theoret Econ. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2933411

  • Pardoux E (2008) Markov processes and applications: algorithms, networks, genome and finance. Wiley, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Python Software Foundation. Python language reference, version 2.7. Available at http://www.python.org

  • Sidhu B, Tan HC (2011) The performance of equity analysts during the global financial crisis. Australian Account Rev 21(56):32–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skyrms B, Pemantle R (2009) A dynamic model of social network formation. In: Adaptive networks, pp. 231–251. Springer, Berlin

  • Staudigl M (2013) Co-evolutionary dynamics and Bayesian interaction games. Int J Game Theory 42(1):179–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2020) Employed full time: wage and salary workers: financial analysts occupations: 16 years and over. Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/LEU0254476000A

  • Watts A (2001) A dynamic model of network formation. Games Econ Behav 34(2):331–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisbuch G, Deffuant G, Amblard F, Nadal J (2002) Meet, discuss, and segregate!. Complexity 7(3):55–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Phillip J. Monin.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Monin, P.J., Bookstaber, R. Information flows and crashes in dynamic social networks. J Econ Interact Coord 16, 471–495 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-020-00310-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-020-00310-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation