Skip to main content
Log in

Adhere to the rules or be discretionary? Empirical evidence from the euro area

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper constructs a framework for modelling the interaction between monetary and fiscal policies before and after the formation of the euro area with a view to determining how and why member states’ fiscal policies become more discretionary after the adoption of the euro. Two hypotheses are theoretically derived and empirically tested, developing results with predictions in a robust manner based on various checks. The paper concludes that prior to joining the euro area, the fiscal policies of the member states only respond to demand shocks. However, after joining the euro area, states follow a more discretionary approach that suits both demand and supply shocks, whether domestically or abroad and regardless of the strict rules of the Stability and Growth Pact and other treaties, particularly in response to adverse shocks. This change in fiscal policies in response to economic shocks originates from the asymmetric policy structure: a common monetary policy outlined by the European Central Bank in the euro area, which contrasts with the fiscal policies determined individually by national governments. Although the European Union has been consolidating its governance structure since the recent global financial crisis and the ensuing European sovereign-debt crisis, substantial efforts continue to be required to transform the euro area into a thorough and genuine economic and monetary union.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although member states could implement individual monetary policies prior to joining the euro area, they are not independent in their monetary policies as a result of the spillover effects from other countries’ policy decisions. For example, as Eichengreen (2008) points out, other countries had to adapt to the monetary policy decisions of Germany in Europe as a result of the leading role of the Deutsche Mark.

  2. It should be mentioned here that experience has shown that countries can “get away with” violating the SGP (at least in the past), as the experiences of big countries such as Germany and France in the early 2000s showed (De Haan et al. 2004).

  3. The EU has been collecting data on discretionary current expenditure since 2010, providing insufficient observations to study fiscal policy changes. Therefore, to capture the discretionary orientation of fiscal policy, this paper uses the ratio of the cyclical component of expenditure of the general government to the potential GDP (GEXP) as the dependent variable.

  4. Reed (2015) argues that the common practice of using lagged variables—a widespread practice in the economics and finance literature that even appears in leading journals, including but not limited to the American Economic Review and the Journal of Finance—does not solve the problem of simultaneity bias. An alternative solution is to use lagged values of the endogenous variable as instruments for estimation. Reed warns that “this is only an effective estimation strategy if the lagged values do not themselves belong in the respective estimating equation, and if they are sufficiently correlated with the simultaneously-determined explanatory variable”. However, Bellemare et al. (2017) emphasise that “this argument does not imply that lagged explanatory variables are always and everywhere inappropriate”, and “there are several kinds of data generating processes (DGPs) in which lagged explanatory variables are appropriate in the context of no unobserved confounding, in which case one of the following DGPs must be assumed”:

    (a) There is no reverse causality, and the causal effect operates with a one-period lag only.

    (b) There is reverse causality, but reverse causality is contemporaneous only, and the causal effect of X on Y operates with a one-period lag only.

    (c) There is reverse causality, and the causal effect of X on Y is contemporaneous; there are no dynamics in Y, but there are dynamics in X.

    Bellemare et al. (2017) observe that “Scenarios (a), (b), and (c) are valid justification for lagging explanatory variables”. In specification (11), the dependent variable—GEXP, the ratio of the cyclical component of expenditure of the general government to the potential GDP of the member states—primarily responds to economic shocks, as economic theory and policy practice suggest. It is also constrained by the debt level and the annual budgetary balance. Therefore, there is supposed to be no unobserved confounding in (11). Further, the core variables—SS, DS, SSF, and DSF—are obtained as, or calculated from, structural residues of PVAR models. Therefore, the reverse causality of GEXP on economic shocks is very weak. Even if there is a degree of reverse causality, specification (11) still satisfies scenario (b). Therefore, specification (11) operating with a one-period lag only is appropriate for estimation.

  5. Germany, France, Italy, Spain, Portugal, Finland, Holland, Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Greece, Estonia, Ireland, Luxemburg, Malta, Slovenia and Slovakia. Since Latvia and Lithuania joined the euro area after 2014, we excluded these two countries from our study.

  6. The Stata command of the GLS regression for panel data with correlated disturbances is “XTGLS”.

  7. Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxemburg, Holland, Portugal, and Spain.

References

  • Afonso A, Sousa RM (2012) The macroeconomic effects of fiscal policy. Appl Econ 44(34):4439–4454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agell J, Calmfors L, Jonsson G (1996) Fiscal policy when monetary policy is tied to the mast. Eur Econ Rev 40(7):1413–1440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agnello L, Furceri D, Sousa RM (2013) How best to measure discretionary fiscal policy? Assessing its impact on private spending. Econ Model 34:15–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma R, Giuliodori M (2011) The effects of government purchases shocks: review and estimates for the EU. Econ J 121(550):F4–F32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma RMWJ, Jensen H (2005) Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in a micro-founded model of a monetary union. J Int Econ 67(2):320–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellemare MF, Masaki T, Pepinsky TB (2017) Lagged explanatory variables and the estimation of causal effect. J Polit 79(3):949–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benigno P (2004) Optimal monetary policy in a currency area. J Int Econ 63(2):293–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Quah D (1989) The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. Am Econ Rev 79(4):655–673

    Google Scholar 

  • Bofinger P, Mayer E (2007) Monetary and fiscal policy interaction in the euro area with different assumptions on the Phillips curve. Open Econ Rev 18(3):291–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral R, Díaz RG (2015) Is fiscal policy coordination desirable for a monetary union? An assessment from the perspective of a small open economy. Invest Econ-Mex 74(294):3–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. J Monet Econ 12(3):383–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canofari P, Di Bartolomeo G, Messori M (2017) EMU stability: direct and indirect risk sharing. Open Econ Rev 28(5):847–862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi I (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. J Int Money Financ 20(2):249–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano LJ, Eichenbaum M, Evans CL (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J Polit Econ 113(1):1–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Gali J, Gertler M (2000) Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory. Q J Econ 115(1):147–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cover JP, Enders W, Hueng CJ (2006) Using the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model to identify structural demand-side and supply-side shocks: results using a bivariate VAR. J Money Credit Bank 38(3):777–790

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P (2012) The governance of a fragile Eurozone. Aust Econ Rev 45(3):255–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P, Ji Y (2013) Self-fulfilling crises in the Eurozone: an empirical test. J Int Money Financ 34:15–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P, Ji Y (2014) How much fiscal discipline in a monetary union? J Macroecon 39:348–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P, Ji Y (2017) Governing a sustainable Eurozone. Riv Int Sci Sociali 125(2):173–194

    Google Scholar 

  • De Haan J, Berger H, Jansen D (2004) Why has the stability and growth pact failed? Int Financ 7(2):235–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2001) Monetary-fiscal policy interactions and commitment versus discretion in a monetary union. Eur Econ Rev 45(4–6):977–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2003) Symbiosis of monetary and fiscal policies in a monetary union. J Int Econ 60(2):235–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B (2008) Globalizing capital: a history of the International Monetary System. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B, Ghironi F (2002) Transatlantic trade-offs in the age of balanced budgets and European monetary union. Open Econ Rev 13(4):381–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engwerda JC, Van Aarle B, Plasmans JEJ (2002) Cooperative and non-cooperative fiscal stabilization policies in the EMU. J Econ Dyn Control 26(3):451–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engwerda J, Van Aarle B, Plasmans J, Weeren A (2013) Debt stabilization games in the presence of risk premia. J Econ Dyn Control 37(12):2525–2546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ernst E, Semmler W, Haider A (2017) Debt-deflation, financial market stress and regime change—evidence from Europe using MRVAR. J Econ Dyn Control 81:115–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2017) Reflection paper on the deepening of the economic and monetary union. Technical Report, European Commission

  • Evers MP (2015) Fiscal federalism and monetary unions: a quantitative assessment. J Int Econ 97(1):59–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferré M (2008) Fiscal policy coordination in the EMU. J Policy Model 30(2):221–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, Monacelli T (2008) Optimal monetary and fiscal policy in a currency union. J Int Econ 76(1):116–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghironi F, Giavazzi F (1998) Currency areas, international monetary regimes, and the employment-inflation tradeoff. J Int Econ 45(2):259–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2012) Econometric analysis, 7th edn. Prentice Hall, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Gros D, Mayer T (2010) Towards a European Monetary Fund. Policy brief, CEPS

    Google Scholar 

  • Im KS, Pesaran MH, Shin Y (2003) Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J Econom 115(1):53–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jarociński M, Maćkowiak B (2018) Monetary-fiscal interactions and the euro area’s malaise. J Int Econ 112:251–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jawadi F, Mallick SK, Sousa RM (2016) Fiscal and monetary policies in the BRICS: a panel VAR approach. Econ Model 58:535–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones J (2012) Discretionary fiscal policy and the European monetary union. Modern Ec 3:742–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Juncker J-C, Tusk D, Dijsselbloem J, Draghi M, Schulz M (2015). Completing Europe’s economic and monetary union: the five presidents’ report. Technical Report, European Council

  • Lof M, Malinen T (2014) Does sovereign debt weaken economic growth?A panel VAR analysis. Econ Lett 122(3):403–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Love I, Zicchino L (2006) Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: evidence from panel VAR. Q Rev Econ Finance 46(2):190–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magazzino C (2016) Economic growth, CO2 emissions and energy use in the South Caucasus and Turkey: a PVAR analyses. Int Energy J 16(4):153–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Reis R (2002) Sticky information versus sticky prices: a proposal to replace the new Keynesian Phillips curve. Q J Econ 117(4):1295–1328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni P (2013) Structural panel VARs. Econometrics 1(2):180–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pizzati L (2000) Monetary policy coordination and the level of national debt. Empirica 27(4):389–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravn MO, Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2012) Consumption, government spending, and the real exchange rate. J Monet Econ 59(3):215–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed WR (2015) On the practice of lagging variables to avoid simultaneity. Oxford B Econ Stat 77(6):897–905

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts JM (1995) New Keynesian economics and the Phillips curve. J Money Credit Bank 27(4):975–984

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer CD, Romer DH (2004) A new measure of monetary shocks: derivation and implications. Am Econ Rev 94(4):1055–1084

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudd J, Whelan K (2005) New tests of the new-Keynesian Phillips curve. J Monet Econ 52(6):1167–1181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Semmler W, Haider A (2018) Cooperative monetary and fiscal policies in the euro area. South Econ J 85(1):217–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Semmler W, Young B (2017). Re-booting Europe: what kind of fiscal union–what kind of social union? Working Paper 13/2017, The New School for Social Research

  • Sun J (2011) The sovereign debt crisis and asymmetries within the euro area. Chin J Eur S 1:30–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini G (1986) Money, debt and deficits in a dynamic game. J Econ Dyn Control 10(4):427–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uhlig H (2002) One money, but many fiscal policies in Europe: what are the consequences? CEPR Discussion Papers No. 3296

  • Van Aarle B, Garretsen H, Huart F (2004) Monetary and fiscal policy rules in the EMU. Ger Econ Rev 5(4):407–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Rompuy H, Barroso J M, Juncker J-C, Draghi M (2012) Towards a genuine economic and monetary union. Technical report, European Council

  • Von Hagen J, Mundschenk S (2003) Fiscal and monetary policy coordination in EMU. Int J Finance Econ 8(4):279–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zou Z, Yuan L (2014) An empirical analysis on asymmetric shocks to the euro area based on SVAR methods. Stud Int Finance 10:32–42

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the two referees for their very helpful and constructive comments.

Funding

This work was funded by the National Social Science Fund of China (Grant Number 16BJL087).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zongsen Zou.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zou, Z., Wang, X. & Feng, D. Adhere to the rules or be discretionary? Empirical evidence from the euro area. J Econ Interact Coord 15, 501–525 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-019-00239-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-019-00239-4

Keywords

Navigation