Skip to main content
Log in

Autonomy or Privilege? Lobbying Intensity of Local Business Associations in China

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Journal of Chinese Political Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article examines the relationship between the state and society in contemporary China by analyzing the lobbying behavior of business associations. Particularly, it asks whether and how autonomy and/or privileged access exert/s influence on their lobbying frequency. A formal model is developed that focuses on the trade-off between lobbying intensity and the private provision of collective goods. The hypotheses are tested against the original survey data from Zhejiang and Jiangsu Provinces. The research finds that self-established associations lobby less, and those with consultant status assigned by the government lobby the government more often. In contrast, the impact of “autonomy” in a narrow sense is weaker than is commonly claimed in the Chinese lobbying literature.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For another recent example that applies formal modeling to an area-oriented question of village elections in China, see Takeuchi [40].

  2. Deng and Kennedy [6] confirm that the Chinese usage of the term “youshui” is consistent with the general definition of lobbying in political science.

  3. Scholars often propose labels that they claim adequately capture the relevant characteristics: fragmented authoritarianism [34], authoritarian communitarianism [15], consultative authoritarianism [41], crony communism [8], guanxi capitalism [33], and fragmented corporatism [16], among others.

  4. He also quips that “associations are like ‘pedestrian overpasses’. Some people use the overpasses, but in China most cross the road at street level” ([22], 173).

  5. However, it is unclear which statistical method (linear or non-linear, for instance) they have applied.

  6. In fact, privileged access is a central trait of the concept of corporatism [4]. Although corporatism has also been a key concept in China studies, scholars have mostly focused on the relationship between the government and the group, not between groups.

  7. After all, it was the government initiative that facilitated institutional separation between business associations and governmental departments in the first place [16, 50].

  8. It is different from the distinction between inside and outside lobbying [30], which refers to two main methods of influencing public policy, or between private and collective lobbying [12, 20].

  9. Formally, it is assumed that \( \overline{x}\kern0.5em < ar<{x}_1^{*}+{x}_2^{*} \), where \( \overline{x}\kern0.8em \equiv \frac{\beta_2-{\beta}_1}{k_2} \), \( {x}_1^{*}\equiv \frac{\beta_1}{k_1} \), and \( {x}_2^{*}\equiv \frac{\beta_2}{k_2} \).

  10. It might be the case that self-establishment is also related to a larger value of k 2; that is, the marginal return decreases more rapidly as a result of the larger initial return. However, under a relatively conservative assumption that self-establishment does not decrease x 2 , it can be shown that \( {\widehat{x}}_1 \) is always decreasing in β 2. The proof is as follows: substituting \( {k}_2=\frac{\beta_2}{x_2^{*}} \) into the formula for \( {\widehat{x}}_1 \) and differentiating with regard to β 2 yield \( \frac{d{\widehat{x}}_1}{d{\beta}_2}=\frac{x_2^{*}\left\{\left( ar-{x}_2^{*}\right){k}_1-{\beta}_1\right\}}{{\left({\beta}_2+{x}_2^{*}{k}_1\right)}^2} \). The “moderate scarcity” constraint, ar < x *1  + x 2 , can also be rewritten as (ar − x 2 )k 1 < β 1 by substitution, which implies that the numerator is always negative. Since the denominator is always positive, the first derivative is always negative.

  11. It is because the total benefit from lobbying might remain constant regardless of the initial responsiveness (β 1). Formally, if the total benefit is fixed (denoted by \( \frac{c}{2} \)), then \( {k}_1=\frac{{\beta_1}^2}{c} \). Substituting and differentiating with regard to β 1 yield \( \frac{d{\widehat{x}}_1}{d{\beta}_1}=\frac{-c\left({\beta_1}^2+2\left({k}_2 ar-{\beta}_2\right){\beta}_1-c{k}_2\right)}{{\left({\beta}_1+c{k}_2\right)}^2} \), whose sign depends on the value of β 1. In this case, a prediction cannot be derived without knowing the actual value of β 1.

  12. It can be shown by a similar process as appears in the footnote for Hypothesis 2 - b.

  13. It can be shown by a similar process as appears in the footnote for Hypothesis 1.

  14. Here, it is assumed that the ratio is exogenous. Relaxing this assumption is an agenda for future research.

  15. In this case, it is more reasonable to think the government responsiveness (k 1) is fixed.

  16. Differentiating with regard to β 1 yields \( \frac{\partial {\widehat{x}}_1}{\partial {\beta}_1}=\frac{1}{k_1+{k}_2} \). It suggests potential interaction effects with the indicators. For example, if self-establishment affects both β 2 and k 2 (larger), it may be predicted that the impact of the ratio (income from the government) would be smaller if an association is self-established.

  17. Alternatively, a larger total benefit may be represented by constant β 1 and smaller k 1. It does not affect the prediction regarding the main effect.

  18. The majority of business associations are affiliated with FIC in Wenzhou and Wuxi, as two trial cities of reform in business associations. A couple of associations in these cities are still affiliated with policy departments, since the government could not force them. Meanwhile, in Zhejiang Province level and Ningbo City level, business associations are affiliated with EIC, FIC, and other government departments. However, all business associations in the four places also must be separately registered in the Public Affairs Bureau. This is called the System of Dual Control for all associations in China. However, the System of Dural Control may be repealed after 2013 since the Proposal of the State Council Restructuring and Functional Transformation Plan was delivered at the First Session of the Twelfth National People’s Congress on March 5, 2013.

  19. The possibility cannot be entirely excluded that some threats to internal validity, such as self-selection, existed in the data-generating process.

  20. We replaced lobbying with “proposing policies” (zhengce jianyi) in the questionnaire, because the term “lobbying (youshui)” is commonly associated with the corporate behavior in contemporary China [6]. In contrast, “proposing policies” is more encompassing, politically neutral, and preserves the original conceptualization of lobbying.

  21. Eising [9] also utilizes MI. Although Victor [47] advocates mean substitution, it is not recommended by the statistical community because it underestimates the variance and thus biases the inference.

References

  1. Baron, David P. 1994. Electoral competition with informed and uniformed voters. The American Political Science Review 88(1): 33–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Baumgartner, Frank R., and Beth L. Leech. 1998. Basic interests. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Binderkrantz, Anne. 2005. Interest group strategies. Political Studies 53(4): 694–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Binderkrantz, Anne. 2008. Different groups, different strategies. Scandinavian Political Studies 31(2): 173–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Cai, Yongshun. 2004. Managed participation in China. Political Science Quarterly 119(3): 425–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Deng, G., and S. Kennedy. 2010. Big business and industry association lobbying in China: The Paradox of Contrasting Styles. The China Journal 63: 101–125.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Dickson, Bruce J. 2003. Red capitalists in China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Dickson, Bruce J. 2008. Wealth into power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  9. Eising, Rainer. 2007. Institutional context, organizational resources and strategic choices. European Union Politics 8(3): 329–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Fewsmith, Joseph. 2005. Chambers of commerce in Wenzhou Show Potential and Limits of ‘Civil Society’ in China. China Leadership Monitor 16: 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Fewsmith, Joseph. 2013. The logic and limits of political reform in China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Godwin, R. Kenneth, Edward J. López, and Barry J. Seldon. 2008. Allocating lobbying resources between collective and private rents. Political Research Quarterly 61(2): 345–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Godwin, R. Kenneth, Scott H. Ainsworth, and Erik Godwin. 2013. Lobbying and policymaking. Thousand Oaks: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Grant, Wyn. 2004. Pressure politics: The changing world of pressure groups. Parliamentary Affairs 57(2): 408–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Heberer, Thomas. 2009. Evolvement of citizenship in Urban China or authoritarian communitarianism? Journal of Contemporary China 18(61): 491–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Holbig, Heike. 2010. Fragmented corporatism? The case of Chinese Trade Associations. Paper presented at Annual Meeting of the Association of Asian Studies, March 25–29, at Philadelphia.

  17. Honaker, James, Gary King, and Matthew Blackwell. 2013. AMELIA II: A program for missing data 1.7.2, Cambridge.

  18. Hsu, Jennifer Y.J., and Reza Hasmath (eds.). 2013. The Chinese corporatist state. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Huang, Mei. 2010. Chuugoku no riekidantai to ‘tsuyoi shihon, yowai roudou’ no genjou. [Chinese interest groups and the current situation of ‘strong capital, weak labor’] Ajiakenkyuu [Asian Studies] 56(1):1–16.

  20. Hula, Kevin W. 1999. Lobbying together. Washington, D.C.: Georgetown University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Kennedy, Scott. 2005. Business of lobbying in China. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Kennedy, Scott. 2008. The price of competition. In Associations and the Chinese State, ed. Jonathan Unger, 149–174. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Kennedy, Scott. 2009. Comparing formal and informal lobbying practicies in China. China Information 23(2): 195–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Kennedy, Scott (ed.). 2011. Beyond the middle Kingdom. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Kennedy, Scott, and Guosheng Deng. 2012. Hangye xiehui de youshuo xingwei jiqi yingxiang yinsu fenxi. [An analysis of factors that shape the lobbying behavior of industry associations] Jingji shehui tizhi bijiao [Comparative Economic and Social Systems] 162(4):147–156.

  26. King, Gary, James Honaker, Anne Joseph, and Kenneth F. Scheve. 2001. Analyzing incomplete political science data. American Political Science Review 95(1): 49–69.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Kojima, Kazuko, Jae-Young Choe, Takafumi Ohtomo, and Yutaka Tsujinaka. 2012. The corporatist system and social organizations in China. Management and Organization Review 8(3): 609–628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Kojima, Kazuko, Jae-Young Choe, Takafumi Ohtomo, and Yutaka Tsujinaka. 2013. Are social organizations in China free and happy?. Chinese Management Insights 2: 1–3.

  29. Kojima, Kazuko, and Yutaka Tsujinaka. 2013. Chuugoku no Shakaidanntai no Seijitekikinou ni Kansuru Ichikousatsu [A study on the political function of Chinese social ogranizations]. Paper presented at Annual Conference of Japanese Political Science Association, September 16, at Sapporo.

  30. Kollman, Ken. 1998. Outside lobbying. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Lowery, David. 2013. Lobbying influence. Interest Groups & Advocacy 2(1): 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Ma, Jun, and Muhua Lin. 2012. Policymaking in China. China Review 12(1): 95–121.

    Google Scholar 

  33. McNally, C.A. 2011. China’s changing Guanxi capitalism. Business and Politics 13(2), Article 5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Mertha, Andrew C. 2009. Fragmented authoritarianism 2.0. The China Quarterly 200: 995–1012.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Pei, Minxin. 1998. Chinese civic associations. Modern China 24(3): 285–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Pyle, William. 2006. Collective action and post-communist enterprise. Europe-Asia Studies 58(4): 491–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Schafer, Joseph L. 1999. Multiple imputation: A primer. Statistical Methods in Medical Research 8: 3–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Schneider, Ben Ross. 2004. Business politics and the state in twentieth-century Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  39. Steinberg, David A., and Victor C. Shih. 2012. Interest group influence in Authoritarian States. Comparative Political Studies 45(11): 1405–1434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Takeuchi, Hiroki. 2013. Vote buying, village elections, and authoritarian rule in Rural China. Journal of East Asian Studies 13(1): 69–105.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Teets, Jessica C. 2013. Let many civil societies bloom: The rise of consultative authoritarianism in China. The China Quarterly 213: 19–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. ten Brink, Tobias. 2012. Perspectives on the development of the private business sector in China. China: An International Journal 10(3): 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Tsai, Kellee S. 2007. Capitalism without democracy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Tsai, Kellee S. 2013. China’s political economy and political science. Perspectives on Politics 11(3): 860–871.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Unger, Jonathan. 1996. ‘Bridges’: Private business, the chinese government and the rise of new associations. The China Quarterly 147: 795–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Unger, Jonathan (ed.). 2008. Associations and the Chinese State. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Victor, Jennifer Nicoll. 2007. Strategic lobbying: Demonstrating how legislative context affects interest groups’ lobbying tactics. American Politics Research 35(6): 826–845.

  48. White, Gordon. 1993. Prospects for Civil Society in China. The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 29: 63–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. White, Gordon, Jude A. Howell, and Xiaoyuan Shang. 1996. In search of civil society. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  50. Yang, Keming. 2013. Keep business for business: Associations of private enterprises in China. In The Chinese corporatist state, ed. Jennifer Y.J. Hsu and Reza Hasmath, 66–82. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Yu, Hui. ed. 2002. Hangye Xiehui Ji Qi Zai Zhongguo De Fazhan [Industry associations and their development in China: Theory and cases]. Beijing: Economy Management Press.

  52. Yu, Jianxing, and Sujian Guo (eds.). 2012. Civil society and governance in China. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Yu, Jianxing, and Jun Zhou. 2012. Chinese civil society research in recent years. China Review 12(2): 111–139.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Zang, Xiaowei. 2006. Elites, social change and policy-making in China: An introduction. Policy and Society 25(1): 1–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yongdong Shen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yu, J., Yashima, K. & Shen, Y. Autonomy or Privilege? Lobbying Intensity of Local Business Associations in China. J OF CHIN POLIT SCI 19, 315–333 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11366-014-9301-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11366-014-9301-7

Keywords

Navigation