Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Competition and coordination strategies of shared electric vehicles and public transportation considering customer travel utility

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Science and Pollution Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

With the rise of the sharing economy and the concept of “green environmental protection and low-carbon travel,” the emerging project of shared electric vehicles is booming. However, the accompanying coordination problem between shared electric vehicles and public transportation system needs to be urgently solved. In reality, customers’ choice of travel mode is influenced by their own travel perceived utility. Thus, this paper will discuss the competition and coordination problem between shared electric vehicles and public transportation system from the perspective of customer travel utility. Considering the travel cost and comfort in the customer travel utility, the game models of shared electric vehicle and public transportation system in different scenarios are established by using competitive game and cooperative game. Then, the equilibrium solutions under different scenarios are obtained by solving the models. The analysis results show that shared electric vehicles would bring some beneficial improvements to the transportation system under certain circumstances. Furthermore, public transportation system should adopt a coordinative strategy with the shared electric vehicles to promote the total customer travel utility for the entire system. It is worth considering the improvement of the service quality of shared electric vehicle and public transportation, which would affect the rate of increasing in the total customer travel utility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Data sharing is not applicable to this article as no dataset were generated or analyzed during the current study.

References

  • Ahmadreza FI, Anowar S, Mille EJ et al (2017) Hail a cab or ride a bike? A travel time comparison of taxi and bicycle-sharing systems in New York City. Transportation Research Part A: Policy & Practice 101:11–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Ang M, Lim YF, Sim M (2012) Robust storage assignment in unit-load warehouses. Manag Sci 58(11):2114–2130

    Google Scholar 

  • Avci B, Girotra K, Netessine S (2014) Electric vehicles with a battery switching station: adoption and environmental impact. Manag Sci 61:772–794

    Google Scholar 

  • Banister D (2008) The sustainable mobility paradigm. Transp Policy 15(2):73–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Akiva, Moshe E, Lerman S R (1985) Discrete choice analysis: Theory and application to travel demand. MIT Press. 1985: 4-25.

  • Brandstätter G, Kahr M, Leitner M (2017) Determining optimal locations for charging stations of electric car-sharing systems under stochastic demand. Transp Res B Methodol 104:17–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruglieri M, Colorni A, Luè A (2014) The vehicle relocation problem for the one-way electric vehicle sharing: an application to the Milan case. Procedia Soc Behav Sci 111:18–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantarella GE, De LS (2005) Multilayer feed forward networks for transportation mode choice analysis: an analysis and a comparison with random utility models. Transportation Research Part C: Emerging Technologies 13(2):121–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Casals L, Martinez-Laserna E, Amante García B, Nieto N (2016) Sustainability analysis of the electric vehicle use in Europe for CO2 emissions reduction. J Clean Prod 127:425–437

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen P, Zhang Z, Hu XF (2016) Analysis of passenger behaviors impacting on subway station security test. Urban Mass Transit 19(5):5–9

    Google Scholar 

  • Chorus CG (2012) Logsums for utility-maximizers and regret-minimizers, and their relation with desirability and satisfaction. Transp Res A Policy Pract 46(7):1003–1012

    Google Scholar 

  • Ci YS, Zhao JF, Wu LN (2017) Lotka-Volterra-based competition mode of transportation in urban passenger corridor. Journal of Transportation Systems Engineering and Information Technology 17(3):39–45,52

    Google Scholar 

  • Correia G, Antunes A (2017) Optimization approach to depot location and trip selection in one-way car sharing systems. Transport Research Part E 48:233–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Dong J, Liu C, Lin Z (2014) Charging infrastructure planning for promoting battery electric vehicles: an activity-based approach using multiday travel data. Transport Res Part C: Emerg Technol 38:44–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Ettema D, Gärling T, Olsson LE, Friman M, Moerdijk S (2013) The road to happiness: measuring Dutch car drivers’ satisfaction with travel. Transp Policy 27:171–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Galatoulas N, Genikomsakis KN, Ioakimidis CS (2018) Analysis of potential demand and costs for the business development of an electric vehicle sharing service. Sustain Cities Soc 42:148–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo XC, Wang W, Lv S (2000) Study on URT’s forecast model on cooperate and competitive OD matrix. J Highway Transport Res Dev 17(4):57–59 63

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Hao ZN, He YH (2013) Pros and cons of regular traffic and transportation and innovative improvement in new metro age. Shanghai Urban Manag 22(2):59–62

    Google Scholar 

  • He L, Mak HY, Rong Y, Shen Z (2017) Service region design for urban electric vehicle sharing systems. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 19:309–327

    Google Scholar 

  • Jin FL, An K, Yao EJ (2020) Mode choice analysis in urban transport with shared battery electric vehicles: a stated-preference case study in Beijing, China. Transp Res A Policy Pract 133:95–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaspi M, Raviv T, Tzur M, Galili H (2016) Regulating vehicle sharing systems through parking reservation policies: analysis and performance bounds. Eur J Oper Res 251:969–987

    Google Scholar 

  • Kevin A, MelendezTapas K, DasChanghyun K (2020) Optimal operation of a system of charging hubs and a fleet of shared autonomous electric vehicles. Appl Energy 279:115861. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2020.115861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Ma J, Cui J, Ghiasi A, Zhou F (2016a) Design framework of large-scale one-way electric vehicle sharing systems: a continuum approximation model. Transport Res Part B: Methodol 88:21–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Li XP, Ma JQ, Cui JX, Amir G, Zhou F (2016b) Design framework of large-scale one-way electric vehicle sharing systems: a continuum approximation model. Transp Res B Methodol 88:21–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu XT (2012) An Analysis on the competitive tension of travel modes and the heuristic thoughts from ecology. Urban Plan Forum 5:66–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu R, Ding ZH, Jiang X, Sun J, Jiang YL, Qiang W (2020) How does experience impact the adoption willingness of battery electric vehicles? The role of psychological factors. Environ Sci Pollut Res 27:25230–25247

    Google Scholar 

  • Ma CQ, Wang YP, Chen KM (2007) Competition model between urban rail and bus transit. J Transport Sys Eng Info Technol 7(3):140–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Mak HY, Shen Z-JM (2014) Pooling and dependence of demand and yield in multiple-location inventory systems. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 16(2):263–269

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D (1980) Econometric models for probabilistic choice among products. J Bus 53(3):13–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokhtarian PL, Salomon I (2001) How derived is the demand for travel? Some conceptual and measurement considerations. Transp Res A Policy Pract 35(8):695–719

    Google Scholar 

  • Neubauer J, Wood E (2014) The impact of range anxiety and home, workplace, and public charging infrastructure on simulated battery electric vehicle lifetime utility. Power Sources 257:12–20

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Páez A, Whalen K (2010) Enjoyment of commute: a comparison of different transportation modes. Transp Res A Policy Pract 44(7):537–549

    Google Scholar 

  • Paula BM, Elías HP, Ángel PN, David AS (2020) Light electric vehicle charging strategy for low impact on the grid. Environ Sci Pollut Res 28:18790–18806. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-020-08901-2

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Redmond LS, Mokhtarian PL (2001) The positive utility of the commute: modeling ideal commute time and relative desired commute amount. Transportation 28(2):179–205

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell M, Mokhtarian P (2014) How real is a reported desire to travel for its own sake? Exploring the ‘teleportation’ concept in travel behaviour research. Transportation 42(2):333–345

    Google Scholar 

  • Sprumont F, Viti F, Caruso G, König A (2014) Workplace relocation and mobility changes in a transnational metropolitan area: the case of the University of Luxembourg. Transport Res Procedia 4:286–299

    Google Scholar 

  • Sprumont F, Paola A, Francesco V (2017) Analyzing the correlation between commuting satisfaction and travelling utility. Transport Res Procedia 25:2639–2648

    Google Scholar 

  • St-Louis E, Manaugh K, Lierop D, El-Geneidy A (2014) The happy commuter: a comparison of commuter satisfaction across modes. Transportation Research Part F: Traffic Psychology and Behaviour 26, Part A: 160-170.

  • The Foresight Industry Research Institute (2019) In-depth analysis report on China’s shared car business model innovation and investment opportunities. https://bg.qianzhan.com/trends/detail/506/190517-5da8cc05.html. Accessed May

  • Weikl S, Bogenberger K (2015) A practice-ready relocation model for free-floating carsharing systems with electric vehicles-mesoscopic approach and field trial results. Transport Res Part C: Emerg Technol 57:206–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Whalen KE, Páez A, Carrasco JA (2013) Mode choice of university students commuting to school and the role of active travel. J Transp Geogr 31:132–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu P (2019) Which battery-charging technology and insurance contract is preferred in the electric vehicle sharing business? Transp Res A Policy Pract 124:537–548

    Google Scholar 

  • Xu GW, Wang SY, Li J, Zhao DT (2020) Moving towards sustainable purchase behavior: examining the determinants of consumers’ intentions to adopt electric vehicles. Environ Sci Pollut Res 27:22535–22546

    Google Scholar 

  • Yong G, Huang HJ (2016) Modal split in a competitive system of transit and highway with heterogeneous users. Syst Eng Theory Pract 36(9):2320–2327

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang F, Chen K (2018) Transportation cost, scale effect and regional economic disparity: taking Liaoning as an example. J Northeastern University: Nat Sci Ed 39(2):293–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang JL, Li TZ (2014) Urban rail transit and bus collinear analysis based on competition model. J Transport Info Safety 32(4):108–112,118

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Y, Yu YF, Zou B (2011) Analyzing public awareness and acceptance of alternative fuel vehicles in China: the case of EV. Energy Policy 39:7015–7024

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Y, Liu XM, Zhang H (2014) Dilemmas and strategies for the development of urban non-notorized travel. Urban Dev Studies 21(6):113–116

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang HC, Colin JRS, Timothy EL, Zeng T, Scott JM (2020) Charging infrastructure demands of shared-use autonomous electric vehicles in urban areas. Transp Res Part D: Transp Environ 78:78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.trd.2019.102210

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

This study is partially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Program No. 71974154), the Natural Science Foundation of Shaanxi Province (Program No. 2019JM-110), and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (Project No. JB210605).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Zhiyong Zhang analyzed the research problem, wrote the original draft based on the formal analysis, and finished the revision. He was also responsible for the drawing part of the paper and for some calculation with software. Xiao Zhang had provided the methodology support and reviewed and edited the writing, and also funded this manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiao Zhang.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable

Consent for publication

Not applicable

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible Editor: Philippe Garrigues

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

The proof of Proposition 1 .

Comparing the optimal number of customers using PT in Scenario 2 with Scenario 1, it can be found that \( \frac{a-k}{2b}<\frac{a}{2b} \) owing to a > 0, b > 0, and k > 0. And the number of customers reduced is \( \Delta {Q}_P=\frac{k}{2b} \).

The proof of Proposition 2 .

The change in the total utility is \( \Delta U=U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right)-U\left({Q_P}^{\ast}\right)=\frac{k\left(k+4{bQ}_{all}-2a\right)}{4b} \). When k + 4bQall − 2a > 0, it can be obtained ΔU > 0. Therefore, when \( {Q}_{all}>\frac{a}{2b}-\frac{k}{4b} \), \( U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right)>U\left({Q_P}^{\ast}\right) \). In other words, after SEV enters the system and only competes with PT and \( {Q}_{all}>\frac{a}{2b}-\frac{k}{4b} \), the total customer travel utility increases. Similarly, when \( {Q}_{all}=\frac{a}{2b}-\frac{k}{4b} \), \( U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right)={U}_{all}\left({Q}_P^{\ast}\right) \). When \( {Q}_{all}<\frac{a}{2b}-\frac{k}{4b} \), \( U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right)<{U}_{all}\left({Q}_P^{\ast}\right) \). In summary, the magnitude of the total utility of Scenario 1 and Scenario 2 depends on the relationship between Qall and \( \frac{a}{2b}-\frac{k}{4b} \) in the transport system.

The proof of Proposition 3 .

In Scenario 2, it can be known that the optimal numbers of customers using PT and SEV are \( {Q}_P^{\ast }=\frac{a-k}{2b} \) and \( {Q}_S^{\ast }={Q}_{all}-\frac{a-k}{2b} \), respectively. In addition, the maximum total utility of the system is \( U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right)=\frac{a^2}{4b}+\frac{k\left(k+4{bQ}_{all}-2a\right)}{4b} \).

Since Qall is a determined value in the transport system, when the number of customers taking SEV does not reach the equilibrium result, i.e., \( {Q}_S<{Q}_{all}-\frac{a-k}{2b} \), it could be obtained that \( {Q}_P>\frac{a-k}{2b} \). In this case, the total utility is less than that in the equilibrium, \( U\left({Q}_P,{Q}_S\right)<U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right)=\frac{a^2}{4b}+\frac{k\left(k+4{bQ}_{all}-2a\right)}{4b} \). Thus, SEV needs to be subsidized to lower the price of taking SEV to attract more customers and ultimately promote the total customer travel utility of the whole system. Similarly, when \( {Q}_S={Q}_{all}-\frac{a-k}{2b} \), it could be obtained \( {Q}_P=\frac{a-k}{2b} \) and \( U\left({Q}_P,{Q}_S\right)=U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right) \). SEV does not need to be subsidized to upset the optimal equilibrium of the whole system. When \( {Q}_S>{Q}_{all}-\frac{a-k}{2b} \), it can have\( {Q}_P<\frac{a-k}{2b} \) and \( U\left({Q}_P,{Q}_S\right)<U\left({Q}_P^{\ast },{Q}_S^{\ast}\right) \). Therefore, SEV does not need to be subsidized, but PT needs to be subsidized to improve the service quality to attract more customers and ultimately promote the total customer travel utility of the whole system.

In summary, the total customer travel utility of the system varies with the relationship between QS and \( {Q}_{all}-\frac{a-k}{2b} \). When \( {Q}_S<{Q}_{all}-\frac{a-k}{2b} \), the total customer travel utility of the whole system is decreasing. Therefore, it is recommended to subsidize SEV to promote the total customer travel utility of the whole system in this case. On the contrary, the result is reversed.

The proof of Proposition 4 .

As the travel utility function coefficients are determined in Scenario 3, it can be easily found that the size relationship is affected by u and η. For example, when μ < η, \( {Q}_P^{\ast }-{Q^{\prime}}_P^{\ast }=\frac{k\left(\eta -\mu \right)}{2b\left(1+\mu \right)}>0 \) and \( {p}_S-{p}_A=\frac{\left(1+\mu +\eta \right)k-\left(1+2\mu \right)a}{2 bc}>0 \). Therefore, it could be obtained that the optimal number of customers served by PT is reduced and the optimal price of using SEV at station A is reduced compared to that in Scenario 2. Meanwhile, the amount of change in the optimal number of customers taking PT is \( \frac{k\left(\eta -\mu \right)}{2b\left(1+\mu \right)} \). Similarly, when μ = η, \( {Q}_P^{\ast }={Q^{\prime}}_P^{\ast } \), and pS = pA. When μ > η, \( {Q}_P^{\ast }<{Q^{\prime}}_P^{\ast } \), and pS < pA.

Further conclusions can be drawn from the above. The values of μ and η are influenced by the distance from station A to station B and the service quality of the travel modes (Zhang and Li 2014; Ma et al. 2007; Páez and Whalen 2010). Therefore, when station B in the transport system is settled, the values of μ and η are influenced only by the service quality. As μ < η, PT should promptly improve its service quality to get more customers. In addition, the price of taking SEV from station A in Scenario 3 is lower than that in Scenario 2, pA < pS, and the reduction is \( \frac{\left(1+2\mu \right)a-\left(1+\mu +\eta \right)k}{2 bc} \). Based on the demand function of SEV, when the price of taking SEV decreases, it could result in the increasing number of customer taking SEV and the decreasing number of customer taking PT at station A. It explains why the optimal number of customers traveling by PT decreases in Scenario 3.

The proof of Proposition 5 .

The difference between \( {U}_{all}\left({Q}_P,{Q}_S,{Q}_P^{\prime },{Q}_S^{\prime}\right) \) and Uall(QP, QS) is \( \Delta U={U}_{all}\left({Q}_P,{Q}_S,{Q}_P^{\prime },{Q}_S^{\prime}\right)-{U}_{all}\left({Q}_P,{Q}_S\right)=\eta {kQ}_{all}+\frac{{\left[a\left(1+\mu \right)-k\left(1+\eta \right)\right]}^2}{4b\left(1+\mu \right)} \). Due to the positive parameter values, ΔU > 0 and it is always increasing regardless of the size relationship between μ and η.

The proof of Proposition 6 .

Taking the derivations of ΔU, it can be obtained that \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \eta }=k\left[Q-\frac{a}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{2b\left(1+\mu \right)}\right]=k\left(Q-{Q}_3\right) \) and \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \mu }=\frac{2a\left[a\left(1+\mu \right)-k\left(1+\eta \right)\right]-4b{\left[a\left(1+\mu \right)-k\left(1+\eta \right)\right]}^2}{16{b}^2{\left(1+\mu \right)}^2} \). Owing to k > 0 and Q > Q3 > 0, then\( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \eta }>0 \). Therefore, ΔU is strictly monotonically increasing as the value of η increases. Let \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \mu }=0 \), we can get the following result, 2a[a(1 + μ) − k(1 + η)] − 4b[a(1 + μ) − k(1 + η)]2 = 0. Thus, it can be found that there are two different cases between μ and \( \frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) as follows.

Case 1. If a(1 + μ) − k(1 + η) = 0, \( \mu =\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \).

Since \( \mu =\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), it can be obtained that \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \mu}\equiv 0 \). Therefore, ΔU is not changed as the value of μ changes. At this time, ΔU is a constant value, and this constant value is ΔU = ηkQ.

Case 2. If a(1 + μ) − k(1 + η) ≠ 0, \( \mu \ne \frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \).

Let \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \mu }=0 \), we can get \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), and the following conclusions can be drawn. When \( \mu >\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \mu }<0 \), ΔU decreases as the value of μ increases at this time. When \( \mu <\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), \( \frac{\mathrm{\partial \Delta }U}{\partial \mu }>0 \), ΔU increases as the value of μ increases at this time. Thus, \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) is the only maximum point of ΔU. Therefore, \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) is the maximum point of ΔU.

For μ > 0, we need to discuss the above calculations by different situations.

  1. (1)

    When \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1\le 0 \), it means that μ = 0 is the only maximum point of ΔU, and \( \Delta {U}_{\mathrm{max}}<\eta kQ+\frac{{\left[a-k\left(1+\eta \right)\right]}^2}{4b} \). ΔU increases as the value of μ increases at this time.

  2. (2)

    When \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1>0 \), ΔU decreases as the value of μ increases. It means that \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) is the only maximum point of ΔU, and \( \Delta {U}_{\mathrm{max}}=\eta kQ+\frac{a^3}{8b\left[a+2 bk\left(1+\eta \right)\right]} \). At this time, when \( 0<\mu <\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), ΔU increases as the value of μ increases. Thus, it means that \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) is the only maximum point of ΔU, and \( \Delta {U}_{\mathrm{max}}=\eta kQ+\frac{a^3}{8b\left[a+2 bk\left(1+\eta \right)\right]} \).

Therefore, the increase or decrease of ΔU is different depending on the value of μ. There are three different relationships between ΔU and μ. When \( \mu =\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), ΔU is a fixed value and the fixed value is ηkQ. When \( \mu \ne \frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \), \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) is the only maximum point of ΔU. If \( \frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1\le 0 \), ΔU is strictly increased as μ increases at this time and \( \Delta {U}_{\mathrm{max}}<\underset{\mu \to 0}{\lim}\Delta U=\eta kQ+\frac{{\left[a-k\left(1+\eta \right)\right]}^2}{4b} \). If \( \frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1>0 \), \( \mu =\frac{1}{2b}+\frac{k\left(1+\eta \right)}{a}-1 \) is the maximum point of ΔU at this time and \( \Delta {U}_{\mathrm{max}}=\eta kQ+\frac{a^3}{8b\left[a+2 bk\left(1+\eta \right)\right]} \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhang, Zy., Zhang, X. Competition and coordination strategies of shared electric vehicles and public transportation considering customer travel utility. Environ Sci Pollut Res 28, 62142–62154 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-15040-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-15040-9

Keywords

Navigation