Skip to main content
Log in

Has punishment played a role in the evolution of cooperation? A critical review

  • Published:
Mind & Society Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the past decade, experiments on altruistic punishment have played a central role in the study of the evolution of cooperation. By showing that people are ready to incur a cost to punish cheaters and that punishment help to stabilise cooperation, these experiments have greatly contributed to the rise of group selection theory. However, despite its experimental robustness, it is not clear whether altruistic punishment really exists. Here, I review the anthropological literature and show that hunter-gatherers rarely punish cheaters. Instead, they avoid dealing with them and switch to other partners. I suggest that these data are better explained by individual selection, and in particular by partner choice models, in which individuals are in competition to be recruited by cooperative partners. I discuss two apparent problems for partner choice theories: large-scale cooperation and punishments in economic games. I suggest that rather than favouring group selection theory, these two phenomena provide evidence in favour of individual selection: (1) people produce large-scale cooperation through institutions in which punishment is not altruistic but rewarded on an individual basis; (2) punishment in experimental games can be explained without altruism and is indeed often better explained by individual interests.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This theory raises the problem of second-order punishment (some individuals may free-ride the cost of punishment by contributing to the common good but refusing to punish those who do not cooperate). Boyd et al. have proposed a solution (Boyd et al. 2003). We will see in Sect. 2.2 that this solution is empirically implausible.

  2. Among the Inuits, as a double safeguard against blood revenge on the executioner, close kinsmen may themselves be called upon to carry out the community will (Hoebel, 1954).

  3. These associations are widespread in countries where access to credit is difficult. They are made up of individuals who agree to make regular contribution to a fund that is given, in whole or in part, to each contributor in rotation.

  4. Group selection supporters also claim that group selection is necessary to explain the emergence of large-scale institutions (and not only their stabilization through punishment). Good institutions would flourish and out-compete bad institutions. However, common pool resources are just the cases that contradict this point. Indeed, as Ostrom shows, each institution with its rules, its symbols, its participants, is precisely adapted to its environment. It cannot travel easily and replace another institution. Moreover, empirical studies clearly show that institutions do not evolve by mutation and selection but rather by adjustment and conflict resolution.

    When appropriators design at least some of their own rules (design principle 3), they can learn from experience to craft enforceable rather than unenforceable rules. This means paying attention to the costs of monitoring and enforcing, as well as the benefits that accrue to those who monitor and enforce the rules. (p. 96).

  5. The same analysis can be used for the Prisoners’ Dilemma (Dreber et al. 2008; Wu et al. 2009). In each round, participants chose between cooperating, defecting, or punishing the other participant. Here punishment is not altruistic, since individuals are directly involved in the interactions and may benefit considerably from threatening their partners. By punishing, they show their partner that they are not going to allow themselves to be exploited in the following rounds. Again, this behaviour may have been adaptive in the ancestral environment, where it was not uncommon to interact again and again with the same individuals.

References

  • Aktipis C (2004) Know when to walk away: contingent movement and the evolution of cooperation. J Theor Biol 231(2):249–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ardener S (1964) The comparative study of rotating credit associations. J Anthropol Inst Great Britain Irel 94(2):201–229

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1984) The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R, Hamilton W (1981) The evolution of cooperation. Science 211(4489):1390–1396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balikci A, American Museum of Natural History (1970) The Netsilik Eskimo, 1st edn. Natural History Press, Garden City

    Google Scholar 

  • Barclay P (2004) Trustworthiness and competitive altruism can also solve the “tragedy of the commons”. Evol Hum Behav 25(4):209–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay P (2006) Reputational benefits for altruistic punishment. Evol Hum Behav 27:325–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay P, Willer R (2007) Partner choice creates competitive altruism in humans. Proc Biol Sci 274(1610):749–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron J, Ritov I (2008) The role of probability of detection in judgments of punishment. Unpublished manuscript

  • Baron J, Gowda R, Kunreuther H (1993) Attitudes toward managing hazardous waste: what should be cleaned up and who should pay for it? Risk Anal 13(2):183–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumard N (2008) A naturalist and mutualist theory of morality. Ecole Normale Supérieure, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumard N (2010a) L’origine de la morale Une histoire naturelle du bien et du mal. Odile Jacob, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumard N (2010b) Punishment is a group adaptation. Mind Soc. doi:10.1007/s11299-010-0080-3

  • Baumard N, Boyer P, Sperber D (2010) Evolution of fairness: cultural variability. Science 329(5990):388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard H, Fischbacher U, Fehr E (2006) Parochial altruism in humans. Nature 442(7105):912–915

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein L (1992) Opting out of the legal system: extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry. J Legal Stud 21(1):115–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black D (2000) On the origin of morality. In: Katz L (ed) Evolutionary origins of morality: cross-disciplinary perspectives (pp. xvi, 352 p.). Imprint Academic, Thorverton

  • Boehm C (1999) Hierarchy in the forest: the evolution of egalitarian behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton G, Zwick R (1995) Anonymity versus punishment in ultimatum bargaining. Games Econ Behav 10(1):95–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson P (1988) The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups. Theor Biol 132(3):337–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson P (2002) Group beneficial norms can spread rapidly in a structured population. J Theor Biol 215(3):287–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Gintis H, Bowles S, Richerson P (2003) The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 100(6):3531–3535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Gintis H, Bowles S (2010) Coordinated punishment of defectors sustains cooperation and can proliferate when rare. Science 328(5978):617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briggs JL (1970) Never in anger: portrait of an Eskimo family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brosig J (2002) Identifying cooperative behavior: some experimental results in a prisoner’s dilemma game. J Econ Behav Organ 47(3):275–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bshary R, Noë R (2003) The ubiquitous influence of partner choice on the dynamics of cleaner fish–client reef fish interactions. In: Hammmerstein P (ed) Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation. MIT, Cambridge, pp 167–184

    Google Scholar 

  • Bull J, Rice W (1991) Distinguishing mechanisms for the evolution of co-operation. J Theor Biol 149(1):63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsmith K, Darley J, Robinson P (2002) Why do we punish? Deterrence and just deserts as motives for punishment. J Pers Soc Psychol 83(2):284–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cashdan E (1980) Egalitarianism among hunters and gatherers. Am Anthropol 82(1):116–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang Y (2010) Self-interested partner selection can lead to the emergence of fairness. Evol Hum Behav 31(4):265–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cinyabuguma M, Page T, Putterman L (2004) On perverse and second-order punishment in public goods experiments with decentralized sanctioning. Working paper, Department of Economics, Brown University

  • Clastres P (1972) Chronique des Indiens Guayaki; ce que savent les Aché, chasseurs nomades du Paraguay. Plon, Paris

  • Clutton-Brock T, Parker G (1995) Punishment in animal societies. Nature 373(6511):209–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coricelli G, Fehr D, Fellner G (2004) Partner selection in public goods experiments. J Conflict Resolut 48(3):356–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darley J, Carlsmith K, Robinson P (2000) Incapacitation and just deserts as motives for punishment. Law Hum Behav 24(6):659–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawes CT, Fowler JH, Johnson T, McElreath R, Smirnov O (2007) Egalitarian motives in humans. Nature 446(7137):794–796

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Quervain DJ, Fischbacher U, Treyer V, Schellhammer M, Schnyder U, Buck A et al (2004) The neural basis of altruistic punishment. Science 305(5688):1254–1258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denant-Boemont L, Masclet D, Noussair C (2007) Punishment, counterpunishment and sanction enforcement in a social dilemma experiment. J Econ Theory 33(1):145–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreber A, Rand D, Fudenberg D, Nowak M (2008) Winners don’t punish. Nature 452(7185):348–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durkheim É (1893) De la division du travail social. F. Alcan, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrhart K-M, Keser C (1999) Mobility and cooperation: on the run. Série scientifique (CIRANO);99s-24

  • Evans-Pritchard EE (1940) The Nuer, a description of the modes of livelihood and political institutions of a Nilotic people. The Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Fehr E, Fischbacher U (2005) Driving forces behind informal sanctions. Econometrica 73:2017–2030

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U (2003) The nature of human altruism. Nature 425(6960):785–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U (2004) Social norms and human cooperation. Trends Cogn Sci 8(4):185–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415:137–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank R, Gilovich T, Regan D (1993) The evolution of one-shot cooperation: an experiment. Ethol Sociobiol 14:247–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fürer-Haimendorf Cv (1967) Morals and merit: a study of values and social controls in South Asian societies. Weidenfeld & Nicolson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis H (2009) The bounds of reason: game theory and the unification of the behavioral sciences. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis H, Bowles S, Boyd R, Fehr E (2003) Explaining altruistic behavior in humans. Evol Hum Behav 24(3):153–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis H, Bowles S, Boyd R, Fehr E (2005) Moral sentiments and material interests: origins, evidence, and consequences. In: Moral sentiments and material interests: the foundations of cooperation in economic life, pp 3–39

  • Glaeser EL, Sacerdote B (2000) The determinants of punishment: deterrence, incapacitation and vengeance. SSRN

  • Greif A (1993) Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: the maghribi traders’ coalition. Am Econ Rev 83(3):525–548

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurven M (2004) To give and to give not: the behavioral ecology of human food transfers. Behav Brain Sci 27:543–559

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardy CL, Van Vugt M (2006) Nice guys finish first: the competitive altruism hypothesis. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 32(10):1402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hechter M (1987) Principles of group solidarity. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Hechter M, Kanazawa S (1993) Group solidarity and social order in Japan. J Theor Polit 5(4):455–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Boyd R (2001) Why people punish defectors: weak conformist transmission can stabilize costly enforcement of norms in cooperative dilemmas. J Theor Biol 208:79–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, McElreath R, Barr A, Ensminger J, Barrett C, Bolyanatz A et al (2006) Costly punishment across human societies. Science 312(5781):1767–1770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Ensminger J, McElreath R, Barr A, Barrett C, Bolyanatz A et al (2010) Markets, religion, community size, and the evolution of fairness and punishment. Science 327(5972):1480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann B, Gächter S, Thöni C (2008) Antisocial punishment across societies. Science 319: 1362

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoebel EA (1954) The law of primitive man: a study in comparative legal dynamics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson T, Dawes C, Fowler J, McElreath R, Smirnov O (2009) The role of egalitarian motives in altruistic punishment. Econ Lett 102(3):192–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan H, Gurven M (2001) The natural history of human food sharing and cooperation: a review and a new multi-individual approach to the negotiation of norms paper presented at the conference on the structure and evolution of strong reciprocity, Santa Fe Institute

  • Knauft B (1987) Reconsidering violence in simple human societies: homicide among the Gebusi of New Guinea. Curr Anthropol 28(4):457–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurzban R, DeScioli P (2008) Reciprocity in groups: information-seeking in a public goods game. Eur J Soc Psychol 38(1):139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurzban R, DeScioli P (2009) Adaptationist punishment in humans. Context

  • Kurzban R, DeScioli P, O’Brien E (2006) Audience effects on moralistic punishment. Working paper

  • Landa JT (1981) A theory of the ethnically homogeneous middleman group: an institutional alternative to contract law. J Legal Stud 10(2):349–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee RB (1979) The !Kung San: men, women, and work in a foraging society. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibbrandt A, López-Pérez R (2008) The envious punisher. Working paper, University of Zurich

  • Malinowski B (1926/1985) Crime and custom in savage society. Rowman & Littlefield, New York

  • McFatter RM (1982) Purposes of punishment: effects of utilities of criminal sanctions on perceived appropriateness. J Appl Psychol 67(3):255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nikiforakis N (2008) Punishment and counter-punishment in public good games: can we really govern ourselves? J Public Econ 92(1–2):91–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noë R, van Schaik C, Van Hooff J (1991) The market effect: an explanation for pay-off asymmetries among collaborating animals. Ethology 87(1–2):97–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohtsubo Y, Watanabe E (2008) Do sincere apologies need to be costly? Test of a costly signaling model of apology. Evol Hum Behav 30(2):114–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action; public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Page T, Putterman L, Unel B (2005) Voluntary association in public goods experiments: reciprocity, mimicry and efficiency. Econ J 115(506):1032–1053

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky AM, Shavell S (2000) The economic theory of public enforcement of law. J Econ Lit 38(1):45–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner R (1983) The economics of justice. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pradel J, Euler HA, Fetchenhauer D (2008) Spotting altruistic dictator game players and mingling with them: the elective assortation of classmates. Evol Hum Behav 30(2):103–113

    Google Scholar 

  • Price ME (2005) Punitive sentiment among the Shuar and in industrialized societies: cross-cultural similarities. Evol Hum Behav 26:279–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radcliffe-Brown AR (1922) The Andaman islanders: a study in social anthropology. The University press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rand D, Dreber A, Ellingson T, Fudenberg D, Nowak M (2009) Positive interactions promote public cooperation. Science 325(5945):1272–1275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts G (1998) Competitive altruism: from reciprocity to the handicap principle. Proc R Soc Lond B 265:427–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts J, Gebotys R (1989) The purposes of sentencing: public support for competing aims. Behav Sci Law 7(3):387–402

    Google Scholar 

  • Rouland N (1976) La Sanction du droit chez certaines populations esquimaudes: problèmes théoriques et modes d’intervention de la communauté dans les procédures de règlement des conflit. Centre d’Etude Arctique, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Saijo T, Nakamura H (1995) The “spite” dilemma in voluntary contribution mechanism experiments. J Conflict Resolut 39(3):535–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheldon KM, Sheldon MS, Osbaldiston R (2000) Prosocial values and group assortation. Hum Nat 11(4):387–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sober E, Wilson D (1998) Unto others: the evolution and psychology of unselfish behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sripada C (2005) Punishment and the strategic structure of moral systems. Biol Philos 20(4):767–789

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein C, Schkade D, Kahneman D (2000) Do people want optimal deterrence? J Legal Stud 29(1):237–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sylwester K, RobertsG (2010) Cooperators benefit through reputation-based partner choice in economic games. Biol Lett 6:659–662

    Google Scholar 

  • Tooby J, Cosmides L, Price ME (2006) Cognitive adaptations for n-person exchange: the evolutionary roots of organizational behavior. Manag Decis Econ 27:103–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trivers R (1971) Evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q Rev Biol 46:35–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull CM (1965) The Mbuti pygmies: an ethnographic survey. American Museum of Natural History, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Verplaetse J, Vanneste S, Braeckman J (2007) You can judge a book by its cover: the sequel. A kernel of truth in predictive cheating detection. Evol Hum Behav 28(4):260–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiessner P (2005) Norm enforcement among the Ju/’hoansi Bushmen: a case of strong reciprocity? Hum Nat 16(2):115–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodburn J (1982) Egalitarian societies. Man 17(3):431–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu J, Zhang B, Zhou Z, He Q, Zheng X, Cressman R et al (2009) Costly punishment does not always increase cooperation. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 106(41):17448–17451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamagishi T (1986) The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. J Pers Soc Psychol 51(1):110–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nicolas Baumard.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Baumard, N. Has punishment played a role in the evolution of cooperation? A critical review. Mind Soc 9, 171–192 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11299-010-0079-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11299-010-0079-9

Keywords

Navigation