Skip to main content
Log in

Information Disclosure Policies: When Do They Bring Environmental Improvements?

  • Published:
International Advances in Economic Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There has been a growing interest among policy makers on the use of information disclosure policies for pollution control. This paper theoretically assesses the consequences of information disclosure policies and identifies the conditions under which such policies are likely to bring environmental improvements. Based on a dynamic game framework, the paper shows that both eco-labeling and more general full information disclosure policies may not always result in pollution reduction. Full information disclosure policies are likely to be effective if the product is not heavily polluting and if the minimum quality standard is set quite low. The paper also identifies the conditions under which all consumers are strictly better off with information disclosure policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As is standard in the quality differentiation literature, I do not address how the roles of high and low quality producing firms are determined.

  2. Individual consumers are assumed not to have an incentive to acquire the information by themselves because their individual gains are so small in comparison to the costs of acquiring such information.

  3. In the case of eco-labeling analyzed in the next section, firms simultaneously decide whether or not to apply for the eco-label and environmental quality in the first stage. For simplicity, I assume that the application fee is sufficiently small and exclude it from the analysis.

  4. This paper does not analyze the case where the quality of the product certified by the label is not perfectly credible. See Kirchhoff (2000) for such analyses.

  5. In this example, consumers may take emissions as the quality of a firm’s product. Again, this paper does not analyze the case where the disclosed information is not perfectly credible.

  6. In the case of corner solution, \( e^{ * }_{{\text{L}}} = \underline{e} \). Otherwise, \( e^{ * }_{{\text{L}}} = \underline{e} \).

  7. Producer’s surplus in this model is equivalent to profits.

  8. The effect of information disclosure on producer’s surplus is ambiguous because it is likely that firm H is better off but firm L is worse off. For example, if e L * = \( \underline{e} \), it is easy to show that firm H’s profit is larger but firm L’s profit is smaller under full information disclosure policies compared to under the absence of disclosure policies.

  9. For example, if there are hundreds of potentially harmful (but not highly toxic) chemicals, the monitoring and enforcement costs may be prohibitively costly with minimum quality standards.

References

  • Andreoni, J. (1989). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm glow. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1447–1458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, S., & Gangopadhyay, S. (1995). Toward a theoretical model of voluntary overcompliance. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28, 289–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bansal, S., & Gangopadhyay, S. (2003). Tax/subsidy policies in the presence of environmentally aware consumers. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45, 333–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjorner, T. B., Hansen, L. G., & Russell, C. S. (2004). Environmental labeling and consumers’ choice: An empirical analysis of the effect of the Nordic Swan. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47, 411–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cairncross, F. (1992). Costing the earth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., & Gangadharan, L. (2002). Environmental labeling and incomplete consumers information in laboratory markets. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 113–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, R. (1999). Questions about a gift horse: Voluntary corporate initiatives for environmental improvement are attractive, worrisome, and significant. In R. Gibson (Ed.), Voluntary initiatives: The new politics of corporate greening (pp. 3–12). Ontario: Broadview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchhoff, S. (2000). Green business and blue angels. Environmental and Resource Economics, 15, 403–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lamarre, L. (1997). Utility customers go for the green. ERPI Journal, 22, 6–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, K. J. (1956). The general theory of second best. Review of Economic Studies, 24, 11–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattoo, A., & Singh, H. V. (1994). Eco-labelling: Policy considerations. Kyklos, 47, 53–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moscovitz, D. (1993). Green pricing: Why not customer choice? The Electricity Journal, 6, 42–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motta, M. (1993). Endogenous quality choice: Price vs. quantity competition. Journal of Industrial Economics, 41, 113–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W., Markandya, A., & Barbier, E. B. (1989). Blueprint for a green economy. London: Earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ronnen, U. (1991). Minimum quality standards, fixed costs, and competition. RAND Journal of Economics, 22, 490–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1982). Relaxing price competition through product differentiation. Review of Economic Studies, 49, 3–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swallow, S. K., & Sedjo, R. A. (2000). Eco-labeling consequences in general equilibrium: A graphical assessment. Land Economics, 76, 28–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tietenberg, T., & Wheeler, D. (2001). Empowering the community: Information strategies for pollution control. In H. Folmer, H. L. Gabel, S. Gerking, & A. Rose (Eds.), Frontiers of environmental economics (pp. 85–120). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wasik, J. F. (1996). Green marketing and management: A global perspective. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Toshihiro Uchida.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

Consider how firm L’s profit changes when the threshold \( \widetilde{e} \) is incrementally increased from \( \underline{e} \). By assumption, firm H applies for the eco-label when \( \widetilde{e} \) is set sufficiently low and therefore \( e_{{\text{H}}} = \widetilde{e} \). I compare firm L’s profit when it chooses to apply for the label and when it chooses not to apply.

If L chooses to apply, the profit is given by (substituting \( e_{{\text{L}}} = \widetilde{e} \) into Eq. 5′),

$$ \pi _{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\overline{\theta } ^{2} }} {9}\widetilde{e} - c{\left( {\widetilde{e}} \right)} $$

If the threshold is increased, the change in the profit is characterized by

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\partial \pi _{{\text{L}}} }}{{\partial \widetilde{e}}} = \frac{{\overline{\theta } ^{2} }}{9} - c\prime {\left( {\widetilde{e}} \right)}} \\ {\frac{{\partial ^{2} \pi _{{\text{L}}} }}{{\partial \widetilde{e}^{2} }} = - c\prime \prime {\left( {\widetilde{e}} \right)} < 0.} \\ \end{array} $$

The first derivative of the profit function is positive as long as the slope of the cost function is not too steep. As a special case, firm L may never choose to apply for the label if the minimum quality standard is set high so that the slope of the cost function at the minimum standard is sufficiently steep. Otherwise, firm L has an incentive to apply for the label and the profit increases initially as the threshold is increased from the minimum required level \( \underline{e} \). However, with a convex cost function, the profit ultimately decreases at an increasing rate as the second derivative shows.

If L chooses not to apply for the label, from Eq. 5′,

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\partial \pi _{{\text{L}}} }}{{\partial \widetilde{e}}} = \frac{{ - 2\widetilde{e}\underline{e} ^{2} \overline{\theta } ^{2} }}{{{\left( {4\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}^{3} }} < 0} \\ {\frac{{\partial ^{2} \pi _{{\text{L}}} }}{{\partial \widetilde{e}^{2} }} = \frac{{{\left( {16\widetilde{e} + 2\underline{e} } \right)}\underline{e} ^{2} \overline{\theta } ^{2} }}{{{\left( {4\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}^{4} }} > 0} \\ \end{array} $$

Thus, the profit decreases but at a decreasing rate. Therefore, if \( \widetilde{e} \) is sufficiently high, L’s profit without applying for the eco-label becomes larger than that with the label. Therefore, there is a quality level such that firm L applies for the label if the threshold is set below that quality level and does not apply if the threshold is set above that quality level.

If firm L switches from applying for the label to not applying for the label, firm H’s profit increases and therefore firm H continues to apply for the label even if firm L chooses not to apply. This can be seen as follows. Suppose when the threshold is set at \( \underline{e} \), firm L is indifferent between applying and not applying for the label. Firm H’s profit when firm L applies for the label is given by

$$ \pi _{{\text{H}}} = \frac{{\overline{\theta } ^{2} }} {9}\widetilde{e} - c{\left( {\widetilde{e}} \right)}. $$

and the profit when firm L does not apply is given by Eq. 9. The difference between Eq. 9 and this equation is given by

$$ {\left[ {\frac{{\widetilde{e} + {\left( {\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}}} {{3\widetilde{e} + {\left( {\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}}}} \right]}^{2} \overline{\theta } ^{2} \widetilde{e} - \frac{{\overline{\theta } ^{2} }} {9}\widetilde{e}, $$

and this is positive since \( {\left[ {\frac{{\widetilde{e} + {\left( {\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}}} {{3\widetilde{e} + {\left( {\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}}}} \right]}^{2} > \frac{1} {9} \). Thus, firm H continues to apply for the eco-label even if firm L switches from applying to not applying for the label. Therefore, there is a quality level such that both firms apply for the label if the threshold is set below that quality level and only firm H applies if the threshold is set above that quality level.

To see that firm H does not apply for the label if the threshold is set sufficiently high, note that firm H’s profit given by Eq. 9 is also expressed as

$$ \pi _{{\text{H}}} = \frac{{\overline{\theta } ^{2} }} {4}\widetilde{e} - \frac{{\widetilde{e}\underline{e} {\left( {2\widetilde{e} - \frac{3} {4}\underline{e} } \right)}\overline{\theta } ^{2} }} {{{\left( {4\widetilde{e} - \underline{e} } \right)}^{2} }} - c{\left( {\widetilde{e}} \right)}. $$

The first term is positive but the second and the third terms are negative. Since cost function is convex, the third term dominates the first term as \( \widetilde{e} \) increases. Thus, if \( \widetilde{e} \) is sufficiently high, the profit becomes lower than that without applying for the label and therefore firm H chooses not to apply for the label. ▪

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Uchida, T. Information Disclosure Policies: When Do They Bring Environmental Improvements?. Int Adv Econ Res 13, 47–64 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11294-006-9062-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11294-006-9062-y

Keywords

JEL

Navigation