Skip to main content
Log in

A Note on Allen’s Arc Elasticity with Arithmetic, Geometric and Harmonic Means

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Discussion and debate on the application of Allen’s arc elasticity has continued into the 21st century. This note demonstrates three points. First, perceived differences between Allen’s geometric mean elasticity and a constant demand elasticity based on an assumed isoelastic demand curve are negligible for small changes in price and quantity, which comprise the vast majority of such changes. Second, in some cases of rapid security or commodity price movements, the harmonic mean may provide the most accurate elasticity estimates across measures of central tendency. Third, because the arithmetic and harmonic means serve as bounds for the geometric mean, an elasticity based on the geometric mean may be considered a prudent choice among these three on this basis alone.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Phillips (1994, Daellenbach 319) notes the similarity in the results between the two approaches for small changes in price, but asserts that an argument for isoelastic demand curves “is referenced here only for comparison purposes.” Apart from the debate, Vázquez (1995) formulates a measure of arc elasticity that is in line with the characteristics of point elasticity and Haque (2005) shows the potential of using arithmetic means to approximate harmonic means in the computation of elasticity.

  2. When p U diverges toward infinity, we can divide both numerator and denominator by p U and take the limit. We find that the \( \lim \left[ {{{{2{p_U}{p_L}}} \left/ {{\left( {{p_U} + {p_L}} \right)}} \right.}} \right] = \lim \left[ {{{{2{p_L}}} \left/ {{(1 + {{{{p_L}}} \left/ {{{p_U}}} \right.})}} \right.}} \right] = 2{p_L} \). In contrast, both the arithmetic and geometric means are undefined in this situation.

  3. The result is \( {\left( {{{{dq}} \left/ {{dp}} \right.}} \right)^2}\left( {{{{\overline{p}_G^2}} \left/ {{\overline{q}_G^2}} \right.}} \right) = \left( {{{{dq}} \left/ {{dp}} \right.}} \right)\left( {{{{{{\overline{p}}_A}{{\overline{p}}_H}}} \left/ {{{{\overline{q}}_A}{{\overline{q}}_H}}} \right.}} \right)\left( {{{{dq}} \left/ {{dp}} \right.}} \right) \). However, the fact that \( \eta_G^2 = {\eta_A} \cdot {\eta_H} \) does not imply that the absolute values of the elasticity measures follow the order of \( {\eta_A} > {\eta_G} > {\eta_H} \). That is, although the geometric mean price and quantity values are bounded by the arithmetic and harmonic means, their respective ratios (e.g.,\( {{{{{\overline{p}}_A}}} \left/ {{{{\overline{q}}_A}}} \right.} \)) need not follow this order.

  4. We are greatly indebted to the referee for kindly supplying the simulation results shown in Table 2. The use of constant price elasticity demand functions enables us to compare the accuracy of the approximation. We expand the simulations to include other elasticity values in Tables 3 and 4.

References

  • Daellenbach, L. A., Khandker, A. W., Knowles, G. J., & Sherony, K. R. (1991). Restrictions of Allen’s arc elasticity of demand: Time to consider the alternative? The American Economist, 35(1), 56–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daellenbach, L. A., Khandker, A. W., Knowles, G. J., & Sherony, K. R. (1993). Elasticity of demand: Pedagogy and reality: Reply. The American Economist, 37(1), 80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daskin, A. J. (1992). Two propositions on the application of point elasticities to finite price changes. The Journal of Economic Education, 23(1), 17–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallego-Diaz, J. (1944–1945). A note on the arc elasticity of demand. Review of Economic Studies, 12(2), 114–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenblatt, J. B., Succar, S., Denkenberger, D. C., Williams, R. H., & Socolow, R. H. (2007). Baseload wind energy: modeling the competition between gas turbines and compressed air energy storage for supplemental generation. Energy Policy, 35, 1474–1492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haque, M. O. (2005). Income elasticity and economic development: methods and applications (pp. 47–60). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C. C., & Samuelson, P. A. (1946). The graphic depiction of elasticity of demand. Journal of Political Economy, 54(4), 354–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, W. (1973). Advanced calculus (2nd ed.). Boston, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ketenci, N., & Uz, I. (2011). Bilateral and regional trade elasticities of the EU. Empirical Economics, 40(3), 839–854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, J. F., & Yurova, Y. (2007). Property taxation and selling prices of industrial real estate. Review of Accounting & Finance, 6(3), 273–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, S. M., & Platen, E. (2010). Real-world pricing for a modified constant elasticity of variance model. Applied Mathematical Finance, 17(2), 147–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panagariya, A., Shah, S., & Mishra, D. (2001). Demand elasticities in international trade: Are they really low? Journal of Development Economics, 64(2), 313–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, R. (2003). Traveler response to transportation system changes: an interim introduction to the handbook. Washington DC: Transportation Research Board/National Academy, 12, 1–23.

  • Phillips, W. A. (1993). Allen’s arc vs. assumed isoelasticity, pedagogical efficacy vs. artificial accuracy: A comment. The American Economist, 37(1), 72–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, W. A. (1994). Rejuvenating Allen’s arc with the geometric mean. The Journal of Economic Education, 25(4), 309–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vázquez, A. (1985). Geometrical analysis of the arc price elasticity of demand and the change in total revenue. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 33(3), 387–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vázquez, A. (1995). A note on the arc elasticity of demand. Estudios Economicos, 10(2), 221–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vázquez, A. (2008). A note on the two-input arc elasticity of substitution. Estudios Económicos, 23(2), 313–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Villas-Boas, S. B. (2009). An empirical investigation of the welfare effects of banning wholesale price discrimination. The Rand Journal of Economics, 40(1), 20–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, C. W., & Stitt, K. R. (1995). The Ramsey rule revisited. Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 767–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, R. M. (1992). Excursions in calculus: An interplay of the continuous and the discrete. Mathematical Association of America: Washington D.C.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hui Wen Cheng.

Appendix

Appendix

To expand Eq. (3), first note that:

$$ \ln \left( {1 + r} \right) = \sum\limits_{{i = 1}}^{\infty } {{{\left( { - 1} \right)}^{{n + 1}}}} {{{{{\left( {1 + r - 1} \right)}^n}}} \left/ {n} \right.}. $$

This reduces to the following:

$$ \ln \left( {1 + r} \right) = r\left[ {1 - \left( {{{r} \left/ {2} \right.}} \right) + \left( {{{{{r^2}}} \left/ {3} \right.}} \right) - \left( {{{{{r^3}}} \left/ {4} \right.}} \right) + ...} \right],\,\,{\text{for}}\,\,\left| r \right| < 1. $$
(1A)

Expanding \( {\left( {1 + r} \right)^{{ - 0.5}}} \) of Eq. (4) around \( \overline{r} = 0 \) readily yields:

$$ \matrix{{*{20}{c}} {{{r} \left/ {{{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}^{{0.5}}}}} \right.} = r\left[ {1 - 0.5{{\left( {1 + \overline{r}} \right)}^{{ - 1.5}}}r + {{{0.75{{\left( {1 + \overline{r}} \right)}^{{ - 2.5}}}{r^2}}} \left/ {{2!}} \right.} - 1.875{{{{{\left( {1 + \overline{r}} \right)}^{{ - 3.5}}}{r^3}}} \left/ {{3!}} \right.} + ...} \right]} \\ { = r\left[ {1 - {{r} \left/ {2} \right.} + 0.375{r^2} - 0.3125{r^3} + ...} \right]} \\ } $$
(2A)

Subtracting (2A) from (lA) gives rise to the difference in the percent change in quantity, or the numerators of \( {\eta_G} \)and \( {\eta_{{iso}}} \) , as follows:

$$ {\Delta_q} = r\left( {{{{ - {r^2}}} \left/ {{24}} \right.} + {{{{r^3}}} \left/ {{16}} \right.}...} \right). $$
(3A)

By exactly the same procedure, the difference in the percent change in price, or the numerators of \( {\eta_G} \) and \( {\eta_{{iso}}} \) , is as follows (where s is a small percent):

$$ {\Delta_p} = s\left( {{{{ - {s^2}}} \left/ {{24}} \right.} + {{{{s^3}}} \left/ {{16}} \right.}...} \right). $$
(4A)

Eqs. (3A) and (4A) represent alternating series for small r and s values which are of negligible magnitudes.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Yang, C.W., Loviscek, A.L., Cheng, H.W. et al. A Note on Allen’s Arc Elasticity with Arithmetic, Geometric and Harmonic Means. Atl Econ J 40, 161–171 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-012-9315-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-012-9315-5

Keywords

Navigation