Skip to main content
Log in

Estimating Residential Water Demand Using the Stone-Geary Functional Form: The Case of Sri Lanka

  • Published:
Water Resources Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper formulates a demand model for residential water in Sri Lanka using the Stone-Geary functional form. This functional form considers water consumption to be composed of two parts—a fixed and a residual component. The presence of these two components means it is possible to estimate a threshold below which water consumption is non-responsive to price changes. In turn, this can provide policy makers with a better understanding of the degree to which price changes will affect water consumption and the extent to which price instruments can be utilised to raise additional revenues. These revenues could then be used to extend pipe-borne water infrastructure to a greater proportion of the population than is currently the case. The findings presented here show the portion of water use that is insensitive to price changes in Sri Lanka is between 0.64 and 1.06 m3 per capita per month. The results indicate that price elasticity ranges from -0.11 to -0.14 while income elasticity varies from 0.11 to 0.14. Combined, these findings suggest water authorities could raise revenue via price increases to fund critical infrastructure extension.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 2005, 95 % of the urban and 75 % of the rural population had access to safe drinking water while 75 % of the urban and 14 % of the rural population had access to pipe-borne water (queryImbulana et al. 2006).

  2. In 2005 1 USD was equal to 102 SLRS (Central Bank of Sri Lanka 2005).

  3. Refer to Appendix 1 for further details of the instrumental marginal price.

  4. Refer to Appendix 1 for details of the procedure adopted to obtain both MP* and D*.

  5. A panel regression for the Cobb-Douglas demand function was estimated using OLS, instrumental variable, and two-stage least square methods and the results are available on request from the authors.

  6. This is based on the average household monthly consumption of 20 m3 at 2005 prices which equals 117.50 SLRS. As noted, in 2005 the exchange rate announced by the Central Bank of Sri Lanka was 1 USD equals 102 SLRS.

  7. The test assumes that the OLS will be consistent and asymptotically efficient under the null hypothesis that the price variables are exogenous but will be inconsistent under the alternative hypothesis. The calculated Hausman test statistic is 181.9 which greatly exceed the critical value of chi-square at 1 % level of significance with 6° of freedom.

  8. For the Cobb-Douglas form, estimated price elasticity of water demand ranged from -0.11 to -0.58 while income elasticity ranged from 0.03 to 0.13.

  9. The coefficient of the number of household varies from 0.21 to 0.86 for the Cobb-Douglas functional form.

References

  • ADB (2007) Sri Lanka country assistance program evaluation: water supply and sanitation sector assistance evaluation. Operations Evaluation Department, Asian Development Bank

  • Agthe D, Billings B, Dobra J, Raffiee K (1986) A simultaneous equation model for block rates. Water Resources Research (January):1–4

  • Al-Quanibet M, Johnston R (1985) Municipal demand for water in Kuwait: methodological Issues and Empirical results. Water Resour Res 21(4):433–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arbues F, Garcia-Valinas M, Martinez-Espineira R (2003) Estimation of residential water demand: a state-of-the-art-review. J Socio-Econ 32:81–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babel M, Gupta A, Pradhan P (2007) A multivariate econometric approach for domestic water demand modeling: an application to Kathmandu, Nepal. Water Resour Manag 21(3):573–589. doi:10.1007/s11269-006-9030-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH, Kao C (2000) Nonstationary panels, cointegration in panels and dynamic panels: a survey. Adv Econ 15:7–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barkatullah N (1999) Pricing, demand analysis and simulation: an application to a water utility. Dissertation.com

  • Beattie B, Foster H (1979) Urban residential demand for water in the United States. Land Econ 55:43–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beattie B, Foster H (1981) On the specification of price in studies of consumer demand under block price scheduling. Land Econ 57(4):624–629

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billings B (1982) Specification of block rate price variables in demand models. Land Econ 58(3):386–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billings B, Agthe D (1980) Price elasticity for water: a case of increasing block rates. Land Econ 56:73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breitung J (2000) The local power of some unit root tests for panel data. Adv Econ 15:161–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavanagh SM, Hanemann WM, Stavins RN (2002) Muffled price signals: household water demand under increasing block prices. FEEM Working Paper No. 40.2002

  • Central Bank of Sri Lanka (2005) Annual Report 2005. Central Bank, Colombo

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bank of Sri Lanka (2006) Annual Report 2006. Central Bank of Sri Lanka, Colombo

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen H, Yang ZF (2009) Residential water demand model under block rate pricing: a case study of Beijing, China. Commun Nonlinear Sci Numer Simul 14(5):2462–2468. doi:10.1016/j.cnsns.2007.12.013

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chicoine D, Ramamurthy G (1986) Evidence in the specification of price in the study of domestic water demand. Land Econ 62(1):26–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chu J, Wang C, Chen J, Wang H (2009) Agent-based residential water use behavior simulation and policy implications: a case-study in Beijing City. Water Resour Manag 23(15):3267–3295. doi:10.1007/s11269-009-9433-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalhuisen JM, Florax RJ, De-Groot H, Nijkamp P (2003a) Price and income elasticities of residential water demand: a meta analysis. Land Econ 79(2):292–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalhuisen JM, Florax RJGM, Groot HLFD, Nijkamp P (2003b) Price and income elasticities of residential water demand: a meta-analysis. Land Econ 79(2):292–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David CC, Inocencio AB (1998) Understanding household demand for water: the Metro Manila case. EEPSEA

  • Deaton A, Muellbauer J (1980) Economics and consumer behaviour. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Deller S, Chicooine D, Ramamurthy G (1986) Instrumental variables approach to rural water service demand. South Econ J 53(2):333–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Cosmo V (2011) Are the consumers always ready to pay? a quasi-almost ideal demand system for the Italian water sector. Water Resour Manag 25(2):465–481. doi:10.1007/s11269-010-9709-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espey M, Espey J, Shaw WD (1997) Price elasticity of residential demand for water: a meta-analysis. Water Resour Res 33(6):1369–1374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia S, Reynaud A (2004) Estimating benefits of efficient water pricing in France. Resour Energy Econ 26:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudin S (2006) Effect of price information on residential water demand. Appl Econ 38:383–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaudin S, Griffin R, Sickles R (2001) Demand specification for municipal water management: evaluation of the stone-geary form. Land Econ 77(3):399–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann WM (1997) Price Rate and Structures. In: Baumann DD, Boland JJ, Hanemann WM (eds) Urban water demand management and planning. McGraw-Hill, New York, pp 137–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Hensen S (1984) Electricity demand estimates under increasing block rates. Southern Economic Journal (July):147–156

  • Hensher D, Shore N, Train K (2005) Households’ willingness to pay for water service attributes. Environ Resour Econ 32(4):509–531. doi:10.1007/s10640-005-7686-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hewitt JA, Hanemann WM (1995) A discrete/continuous choice approach to residential water demand under block rate pricing. Land Econ 71(2):173–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoglund L (1999) Household demand for water in Sweden with implications of potential tax on water use. Water Resour Res 35(12):3853–3863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hussain I, Thrikawala S, Barker R (2002) Economic analysis of residential, commercial and industrial uses of water in Sri Lanka. Water Int 27(2):183–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Im KS, Pesaran MH (2003) On the panel unit root tests using nonlinear instrumental variables. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics. University of Cambridge

  • Levin A, Lin CF, Chu J (2002) Unit root test in panel data: asymptotic and finite sample properties. J Econ 108:1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Livingston ML (1995) Designing water institutions: market failure and institutional response. Water Resour Manag 9:203–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Espeneira (2003) Price specification issues under block tariffs: a Spanish case study. Water Policy 5:237–256

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire MC (1979) The analysis of federal grants into price and income components. In: Mieszkowski P, Oakland WH (eds) Fiscal federalism and grants in aid. Urban Institute, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Moeltner K, Stoddard S (2004) A panel data analysis of commercial customers’ water price responsiveness under block rates. Water Resour Res 40(W01401):1–9

    Google Scholar 

  • National Water Supply and Drainage Board (2005) Annual report 2005. National Water Supply and Drainage Board, Colombo

    Google Scholar 

  • Nauges C, Thomas A (2000) Privately operated water utilities municipal price negotiation, and estimation of residential water demand: the case of France. Land Econ 76(1):68–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nauges C, Martinez-Espineira (2004) Is all domestic water consumption sensitive to price control? Appl Econ 36:1697–1703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nieswiadomy M, Molina D (1988) Urban water demand estimates under increasing block rates. Growth Chang 19(1):1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nieswiadomy M, Molina D (1989) Comparing residential water estimates under decreasing and increasing block rates using household data. Land Econ 65(3):280–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordin JA (1976) A proposed modification on Taylor’s demand supply analysis: comment. Bell J Econ 7(2):719–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Núñez M, Oliver-Solà J, Rieradevall J, Gabarrell X (2010) Water management in integrated service systems: accounting for water flows in urban areas. Water Resources Management 24(8):1583–1604. doi:10.1007/s11269-009-9515-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Og AJ, Schulz CE (2006) Water demand and the urban poor: A study of the factors influencing water consumption among households in Cape Town. University of Tromso, Norway, South Africa

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohsfeldt RL (1983) Specification of block rate price variables in demand models. Land Economics August: 365–369

  • Pint EM (1999) Household responses to increased water rates during the California drought. Land Econ 75(2):246–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renwick M, Archibald S (1998) Demand side management policies for residential water use: who bears the conservation burden. Land Econ 74(3):343–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rietveld P, Rouwendal J, Zwart B (2000) Block rate pricing of water in Indonesia: an analysis of welfare effects. Bull Indones Econ Stud 36(3):73–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruijs A (2007) Welfare and distribution effects of water pricing policies. Natural resources management. Wageningen University, Wageningen

    Google Scholar 

  • Schleich J, Hillenbrand T (2009) Determinants of residential water demand in Germany. Ecol Econ 68(6):1756–1769. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.11.012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens TH, Miller J, Willis C (1992) Effect of price structure on residential water demand. Water Resour Bull 28(4):681–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor LD (1975) The demand for electricity: a survey. Bell J Econ 6(1):74–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wentz E, Gober P (2007) Determinants of small-area water consumption for the City of Phoenix, Arizona. Water Resour Manag 21(11):1849–1863. doi:10.1007/s11269-006-9133-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Worthington AC, Hoffmann M (2006) A state of the art review of residential water demand modelling. Faculty of Commerce—Papers. University of Woolongong, Woollongong

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Edwyna Harris.

Additional information

This paper has benefitted from the valuable suggestions of Yew-Kwang Ng, Robert Brooks, and Jaai Parasnis. We also thank seminar participants at the HDR colloquium at Deakin University, Asia Pacific Week 2008 at Australian National University, the 2008 Australian Conference of Economists, and PhD conference of Business and Economics at Australian National University for comments on earlier drafts.

Appendices

Appendix 1: A Model to Estimate Residential Water Demand

A residential water demand model to estimate marginal price and the difference variable can be expressed as follows:

$$ {Q_w} = \left( {MP,D,W,Y} \right) $$
(1a)
$$ MP = f\left( {{Q_w},ratestructure} \right) $$
(1b)
$$ D = f\left( {{Q_w},ratestructure} \right) $$
(1c)

Where, Q w is monthly water consumption for an average household; MP is marginal price for the last unit purchased; D is the difference between the actual water bill and what would be paid if all units were purchased at the MP; W is a vector of weather variables (temperature and rainfall) and; Y is a vector of socio-economic variables (household income and number of household members). The marginal price model includes three structural equations because quantity, marginal price, and the difference variable are simultaneously determined. Equation (1a) utilizes observed quantity values and is then solved for MP and D. The values of MP and D are then utilised in the demand equation.

Simultaneity arises because the quantity of water determines the price under the pricing schedule. With block-rate pricing, causality goes in both directions, from price to quantity and from quantity to price. Consumers choose the amount of water depending on some measure of price, and the price paid depends on the amount consumed. As a result, the OLS assumption that independence between the error term and the explanatory variables exists is violated. This will yield biased and inconsistent estimates (Hensen 1984).

To overcome this and produce more consistent parameters the IV approach has been used in studies similar to the one undertaken here (Billings 1982; Nieswiadomy and Molina 1989). The objective of the instruments is to provide a proxy for the endogenous price variables in water studies. The instruments should fulfil the requirement of being uncorrelated with the error structure while being correlated with the stochastic regressor (Deller et al. 1986).

The Stone-Geary model uses an artificial linearization of the tariff structure to derive instruments for the marginal price and difference variable. This assumes that, instead of taking the effort to learn how the tariff works and which block they are consuming in at each moment in time, households will roughly estimate the whole tariff as a ray line given by an intercept and a constant marginal price (Martinez-Espeneira 2003).

$$ TR = \alpha + \beta {Q_w} $$
(2)

The total revenue (TR) function is computed using the range of quantity (Q w) values (10–33 m3) encountered in the entire data set. These values of the total revenue are then regressed against the corresponding quantity values. The first derivative of the estimated function gives

$$ \hat{\beta } = \frac{{\partial TR}}{{\partial {Q_w}}} = MP* $$
(3)

MP* is the instrumental marginal price variable to the consumer and marginal revenue to the water utility. Estimating the parameter α in Eq. (2) gives the difference between what consumers actually pay and what consumers would pay if all units were sold at the MP*, that is D*. This procedure results in the representation of each rate schedule by MP* and D*, which are constant for all observations under each specific rate structure.

Appendix 2: The Stone-Geary Functional Form

Let Q w and Q z be the demand for water and all other goods respectively; P w and P z are unit prices for water and other goods respectively; γ w and γ z are minimum amounts (subsistence level) for water and other goods; β w and β z are preference parameters (marginal budget shares) for water and other goods; U is the total utility and; I is income (Nauges and Martinez-Espineira 2004).

The Stone Geary utility function is expressed as follows:

$$ U = {\beta_w}1{\text{n}}\left( {{Q_w} - {\gamma_w}} \right) + {\beta_z}1{\text{n}}\left( {{Q_z} - {\gamma_z}} \right) $$
(4)

Where \( {\beta_w} > 0,{\beta_z} > 0{\beta_w} + {\beta_z} = 1,\left( {{Q_z} - {\gamma_z}} \right) > 0\,and\,\left( {{Q_w} - {\gamma_w}} \right) > 0 \)

Normalizing the price of the aggregate goods to one result we use the following budget constraint:

$$ l = {Q_w}{P_w} + {Q_z} $$
(5)

Maximizing utility subject to the budget constraint yields the following demand function

$$ \matrix{{*{20}{c}} {L = {\beta_w}1{\text{n}}\left( {{Q_w} - {\gamma_w}} \right) + {\beta_z}1{\text{n}}\left( {{Q_z} - {\gamma_z}} \right) + \lambda \left( {I - {Q_w}{P_w} - {Q_z}} \right)} \hfill \\ {\frac{{\partial L}}{{\partial {Q_w}}} \to \frac{{{\beta_w}}}{{\left( {{Q_w} - {\gamma_w}} \right)}} = \lambda {P_w}} \hfill \\ {\frac{{\partial L}}{{\partial {Q_z}}} \to \frac{{{\beta_z}}}{{\left( {{Q_z} - {\gamma_z}} \right)}} = \lambda } \hfill \\ {\frac{{\partial L}}{{\partial \lambda }} \to I = {Q_w}{P_w} + {Q_z}} \hfill \\ {Assuming\,{\beta_w} + {\beta_z} = 1\quad {Q_z} = \frac{{{\beta_z}{P_w}\left( {{Q_w} - {\gamma_w}} \right) + {\gamma_z}{\beta_w}}}{{{\beta_w}}}} \hfill \\ {substituting\,in\,I = {Q_w}{P_w} + {Q_z}} \hfill \\ } $$
(6)
$$ {Q_w}\frac{{I{\beta_w} - {\gamma_z}{\beta_w} + {P_w}{\gamma_w}{\beta_w} - {P_w}{\gamma_w}}}{{{P_w}}}\,or\,{Q_w} = {\beta_w}\frac{{I - {P_w}{\gamma_w} - {\gamma_z}}}{{{P_w}}} + {\gamma_w} $$
(7)

The preference parameter for water can be given as;

$$ {\beta_w} = \frac{{{P_w}{Q_w} - {P_w}{\gamma_W}}}{{I - {P_w}{\gamma_w} - {\gamma_z}}} $$
(8)

It is assumed that γz = 0, so the demand function for water is given as;

$$ {Q_w} = \left( {1 - {\beta_w}} \right){\gamma_w} + {\beta_w}\frac{I}{{{P_w}}} $$
(9)

After assuming γ z  = 0, γ w can be renamed as the conditional water use threshold (Gaudin et al. 2001) and is a threshold below which consumption is not responsive to prices. The term conditional emphasizes that this threshold is dependent on the available technology, pricing structure, and price of durable goods during the period of estimation. The marginal budget share allocated to water is represented by β w .

The income variable in this model is the virtual income that is, the difference between household income and the difference variable. Price and income elasticities can be derived from these estimates. In this particular case, the two elasticities have the same magnitude.

$$ {\xi_p} = - {\beta_w}\frac{{I - {\gamma_z}}}{{{P_w}{Q_w}}} = - {\xi_I} $$
(10)

In accordance with the approach used in the relevant literature (for example: McGuire (1979); Gaudin et al. (2001); Nauges and Martinez-Espineira (2004)) γ z is abstracted from the equation and the price elasticity of water demand simplifies to:

$$ {\xi_P} = {\beta_w}\frac{I}{{P{Q_w}}} = - {\xi_I} $$
(11)

This simple specification is preferred because γ z does not provide any relevant information to the study.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dharmaratna, D., Harris, E. Estimating Residential Water Demand Using the Stone-Geary Functional Form: The Case of Sri Lanka. Water Resour Manage 26, 2283–2299 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-012-0017-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-012-0017-1

Keywords

Navigation