Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Relationship Between EU Indicators of Persistent and Current Poverty

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The current poverty rate and the persistent poverty rate are both included in the European Union’s (EU's) portfolio of primary indicators of social inclusion. We show that there is a near-linear relationship between these two indicators across EU countries drawing on empirical analysis of EU-SILC and ECHP data. Using a prototypical model of poverty dynamics, we explain how the near-linear relationship arises and show how the model can be used to predict persistent poverty rates from current poverty information. In the light of the results, we discuss whether the EU's persistent poverty measure and the design of EU-SILC longitudinal data collection require modification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The European Commision’s explanation of the Social OMC is available at http://ec.europa.eu/social/main.jsp?catId=753&langId=en.

  2. See also the book-length discussions of poverty dynamics that appeared during the 1990s, e.g. Leisering and Leibfried (1999), Leisering and Walker (1999), and Walker and Ashworth (1994).

  3. See e.g. Jenkins (2011) who used 16 waves of British Household Panel Survey data.

  4. For an overview of EU-SILC, see Wolff et al. (2010). To access further information about EU’s regulations concerning the SILC, data documentation provided by Eurostat, and SILC variable lists, we recommend the EU-SILC web portal provided by the GESIS research institute at http://www.gesis.org/dienstleistungen/daten/amtliche-mikrodaten/european-microdata/eu-silc/eu-silc-further-information/.

  5. Member states have quite a lot of discretion about the data collection instruments used to derive the data: for instance, the cross-sectional and longitudinal components may come from separate sources (and the longitudinal dataset does not have to be linkable with the cross-sectional dataset even if, in practice, it is often the same source that is used for both data sets). There is also the issue of the extent to which cross-sectional and longitudinal components yield statistics for a given country and year that are consistent with one another. We return to these data issues below.

  6. See Marlier et al. (2007) for more discussion of the development of and refinements to the EU’s social indicators framework over time.

  7. This is apparent if one uses the variance of the logarithms as the measure of dispersion. Observe that log(θ c ) = 2log(R c ) + log(1 + Z) where Z = 2E c (1 − R c )/R c , and log(P c ) = log(E c ) − log[1 + (E c  − R c )] ≈ log(E c ) + R c  − E c , since E c  − R c is small. The variance of the first expression is dominated by the variance of log(R c ), and the variance of the second expression is dominated by the variance of log(E c ). We provide estimates of these variances later in the paper.

  8. The cross-sectional files contain data for all EU member states plus Norway and Iceland.

  9. In principle, use of a current income definition rather than an annual income definition would be expected to lead to greater poverty turnover and income mobility, other things being equal. In practice, Böheim and Jenkins (2006) argue using British Household Panel Survey data that the two income definitions lead to similar estimates of income distribution statistics.

  10. For more extensive discussion of EU-SILC register and survey data collection methods, see Lohmann (2011).

  11. We use the four-year longitudinal weights for all countries except Finland, Luxembourg, and Portugal. For these three countries, we use the Eurostat-supplied base weights since no longitudinal weights are provided in the data release.

  12. Except for Ireland and the UK: see earlier.

  13. Subgroup membership can be allocated for all individuals in the longitudinal files (except for six individuals in the data for Slovenia). We considered an alternative subgroup in which ‘children’ were defined to also include individuals older than 18 who were still in education. In this case, a small fraction of individuals (up to 1% in Norway and Sweden, and 2.9 % in the UK) could not be allocated to a subgroup, primarily because of missing information on activity status.

  14. Eurostat includes a derived variable summarising current poverty status in the cross-sectional files but not in the longitudinal files.

  15. All comparisons refer to survey year 2008. Detailed comparisons are available from the authors on request.

  16. The Pearson correlation summarises the strength of a linear relationship. It ranges between −1 (when there is a perfect negative linear relationship and 1 (when there is a perfect positive linear relationship). It equals 0 when there is no linear relationship.

  17. The close association between a longitudinal measure of poverty and the current poverty rate is also found when other measures besides the EU’s persistent poverty rate are considered. For example, the 21-country Pearson correlation between current poverty rates and persistent poverty rates calculated using a UK definition is 0.87 (0.91 if Latvia is excluded). Persistent poverty on the UK measure is defined as being poor at least 3 years out of four, i.e. the same as the EU measure except that there is no conditioning on current poverty status in the fourth year (see Department for Work and Pensions 2010). The cross-country Pearson correlation between the current poverty rate and the proportion of individuals poor in all 4 years is 0.76 (0.82 if Latvia is excluded).

  18. The least squares regression line for the old member states sample is S c  = −1.392 (1.14) + 0.698 (0.078) * P c  + ε, and S c  = 1.385 (1.49) + 0.479 (0.089) * P c  + η for the new member states sample, where the numbers in parentheses are estimated standard errors. The slope terms are the estimates of (average) θ. One cannot reject the hypothesis that the intercept terms are zero, at the 95% level, consistent with Eq. (2).

  19. We observe that the estimates for the UK are to the ‘southeast’ of the implied linear regression line in Figs. 1 and 2 as well.

  20. For example, for Sweden, the ratio of retention rate and entry rate sample sizes is around 6 %. For the high current poverty rate countries, the ratio is around 25 %.

  21. Data from the Eurostat portal at http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/eurostat/home (accessed 12 July 2012).

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stephen P. Jenkins.

Appendix: Derivation of Poverty Rate Expressions from the Prototypical and Mover–Stayer Models

Appendix: Derivation of Poverty Rate Expressions from the Prototypical and Mover–Stayer Models

1.1 The Prototypical Model

The derivation of the expression for the current poverty rate (Eq. 1) begins with the identity stating that the total number of poor people this year equals the total number of people poor last year plus the number of people entering poverty between the 2 years minus the number of people exiting poverty over the same period. The poverty entry rate is the number of persons entering poverty divided by the number of people who were non-poor last year; the poverty exit rate (one minus the poverty retention rate) is the number of persons leaving poverty divided by the number of persons who were poor last year. Equation (1) is derived by rewriting the identity in terms of the rates of current poverty, poverty entry, and poverty retention, imposing the steady-state and first-order Markov assumptions, and then rearranging the equation.

The derivation of the expression for the persistent poverty rate (Eq. 2) utilises the EU’s persistent poverty rate definition combined with the expression for the current poverty rate shown in Eq. (1). The probability of being persistently poor according to the EU definition is the probability of experiencing one of four possible 4-year sequences of poverty or non-poverty. For example, the probability of being poor for four consecutive years is the probability of being poor in year 1, P c , multiplied by the probability of remaining poor in the following three years, i.e. P c  × (R c )3, where P c is evaluated using Eq. (1). The probability of being non-poor in Year 1 and poor in Years 2, 3, and 4 is (1–P c ) × E c  × (R c )2, which is equal to P c  × (1–R c ) × (R c )2 in the steady-state case. The probabilities for the other two sequences can be derived similarly, and are each equal to P c  × E c  × R c  × (1 − R c ). The expression for S c in Eq. (2) is the sum of the four probabilities. With a sufficiently large sample size, the probabilities correspond to population proportions (rates).

1.2 A Mover–Stayer Model

In our mover–stayer model, the poverty dynamics identity cited above has to be revised: the total number of poor people this year is equal to the number of people from the movers group who are poor plus the number of stayers (who are always poor). This total is equal to the number of stayers plus the number of movers from non-poverty to poverty minus the number of movers from poverty to non-poverty. The poverty retention rate for the population as a whole reflects the combination of the poverty retention rate among the movers who happened to be poor last year and the poverty retention rate among the stayers (100 %). Poverty entry rates refer to the number of poverty entries among movers who were non-poor. (Stayers are not at risk of entering poverty as they are never non-poor.) We could have also supposed the existence of a third class of people—those who are never poor—but this complicates the model without adding insights regarding persistent poverty.

The expression for the current poverty rate, \( P_{c}^{*} \), is derived by rewriting the revised identity in terms of rates of current poverty, poverty entry, and poverty retention, imposing the steady-state and first-order Markov assumptions, and then rearranging the equation:

$$ P_{c}^{*} = P_{c} + W_{c} /(1 + D_{c} ) $$
(3)

where P c , E c , and R c are as defined as in Eqs. (1) and (2), and now refer to rates for movers only. D c is the ratio of the entry rate to the exit rate, E c /(1 − R c ) > 0, and W c is the proportion of stayers in the population. We argue shortly that W c is a small number and the second term in (3) must be smaller still since D c  > 0.

The persistent poverty rate in the mover–stayer model, \( S_{c}^{*} \), is equal to a weighted average of the persistent poverty rate among the movers and the persistent poverty rate among the stayers (100 %), where the weights are equal to proportions of movers and stayers in the population, respectively. Thus

$$ S_{c}^{*} = (1 -W_{c} )\theta_{c} P_{c} + W_{c} . $$

This expression can be re-written in terms of \( P_{c}^{*} \) using Eq. (3):

$$ S_{c}^{*} = \theta_{c} P_{c}^{*} + \delta_{c} ,\quad {\text{where}}\quad \delta_{c} = W_{c} (1 - \theta_{c} ) $$
(4)

Allowing for heterogeneity in poverty dynamics in this way leads to prediction of a near-linear relationship as before, except that there is now a country-specific intercept term, δ c , that was not present in Eq. (2). Since this intercept is positive, one would expect predictions of persistent poverty rates on the basis of Eq. (2) rather than Eq. (4) to produce under-estimates, other things being equal. The intuition is that reliance on current information does not take sufficient account of high poverty persistence propensities among some groups within a country. The empirical issue, and one we consider in the paper, is whether the degree of under-estimation is large or small. Our prior expectation is that the degree is small because W c is likely to be quite small in all countries, and the other term, (1 − θ c ), will not play a significant role if there is little cross-country variation in θ c (the hypothesis discussed in the main text). Estimates of ‘permanent poverty’ rates are rare because there are few very long-running household panel surveys (Sect. 2). However there is some UK evidence that supports our claim. Drawing on British Household Panel Survey data, the Department for Work and Pensions (2010: Table 3.1) reports that the proportion of persons with an income placing them in the poorest fifth of the population in every year between 1991 and 2008 was 3 %, which suggests an upper bound to W c of around 0.03. Greater chances of under-estimation may occur if one looks at subgroups such as elderly people more likely to contain individuals who are permanently poor. More generally, cross-national heterogeneity in W c is another factor that potentially loosens the tightness of the near-linear relationship (Fig. 8).

Fig. 8
figure 8

Predicted and observed current poverty rates (%), 2006 and 2005, old and new member states. Notes Authors’ calculations from EU-SILC longitudinal files. Predicted rates are derived using Eq. (1) in the main text. Year refers to income year. The estimates for 2007 are shown in the top panel of Fig. 5

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jenkins, S.P., Van Kerm, P. The Relationship Between EU Indicators of Persistent and Current Poverty. Soc Indic Res 116, 611–638 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-013-0282-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-013-0282-2

Keywords

Navigation