1 Introduction

Firms are widely considered the main driver of a country’s economic performance (e.g. Birch, 1981; Audretsch and Thurik, 2000; Reynolds et al., 2001; Audretsch and Fritsch, 2002). This literature has its origins in Schumpeter’s (1934) theory of endogenous growth, which argues that, to promote economic growth, it is essential to understand the determinants of entrepreneurial activity and to encourage it. The development of a country starts from the bottom, and “development-from-below” relies significantly on local resources, enterprises and actors (Helmsing, 2005).

It is also widely recognized that differences in performance between firms are due to their internal resources and to their behaviour (Jensen and McGuckjn, 1997; Bernard et al., 2012; Coad et al., 2018). However, firms do not exist in isolation; they are part of an entrepreneurial ecosystem (Stam, 2015; Stam and Spigel, 2018; Stam and Van de Ven, 2021), within a specific national context, whose elements may influence their creation, performance and even survival (Acs et al., 2014, 2016, 2018; Alvedalen and Boschma, 2017; Brown and Mason, 2017; Ndiaye et al., 2018). Therefore, for an in-depth understanding of firm performance, country-level factors should be considered together with firm-level factors (Commander et al., 2008; Commander and Svejnar, 2011; Goldszmidt et al., 2011).

In this paper, we investigate the relationship between transport infrastructure endowment at the country-level with firm performance in emerging economies. Grounding on the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship (KSTE) introduced by Audretsch (1995), we argue that transport infrastructures, by enabling connectivity, interactions and the exchange of knowledge and ideas, facilitate the access to entrepreneurial opportunities and capabilities to implement those opportunities. It follows that well-developed transport infrastructures have the potential to promote the economic performance of firms (Audretsch and Lehmann, 2005; Ghio et al., 2015; Audretsch et al., 2015).

The role of transport infrastructures in aggregate economic growth is proved to be relevant (Fromm, 1965; Aschauer, 1989; Calderón and Servén, 2004; Button, 2010; Bottasso and Conti, 2010; Calderón et al., 2015; Ferrari et al., 2018), especially in the context of emerging economies where the infrastructure endowment is lower compared to more developed economies, so its improvement is likely to have a greater impact on their economy (Baum-Snow et al., 2017; EBRD, 2018; Li and Li, 2013). Moreover, the role of physical infrastructures as an element of the systemic nature of the entrepreneurial ecosystem (Audretsch et al., 2015; Stam, 2015; Stam and Spigel, 2018; Stam and Van de Ven, 2021) and its national dimension (Acs et al., 2014; Urbano, et al., 2019) is recognized by scholars. Despite this, to the best of our knowledge, studies that investigate the linkage between the heterogeneity of firm performance in emerging economies and transport infrastructure endowment, as a key element of the entrepreneurial ecosystem, are absent. In this paper, we aim to fill this gap. For this purpose, we consider transport networks, such as roads and railways, and transport nodes, such as airports and ports. Moreover, we consider the logistics system and services, which has been largely overlooked by the literature on entrepreneurship.

Due to the coexistence in the analysis of factors that, at different levels, might be related to firm performance, we examine them in an integrated framework through the multilevel approach. This approach allows to define a two-level hierarchical structure, where firms are nested in countries and, at the same time, to separate the effect of firm-level factors from the effect of transport infrastructures and logistics on the heterogeneity of firm performance.

For the purpose of this research, we combine firm-level data on 32 countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia from the fifth round of the Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey (BEEPS V) conducted in 2012–2016, by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) and the World Bank (WB), with country-level data on transport infrastructures and logistics collected from institutional data sources.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses the theoretical background and develops the research hypotheses. Section 3 outlines the description of the data and the construction of the variables. Section 4 presents the methodology used to investigate the determinants of firm performance. Section 5 shows and discusses the empirical results. In Section 6, the robustness of the previous analysis is investigated. Finally, concluding remarks are summarized in Section 7.

2 Theoretical background and hypothesis development

2.1 Linking transport infrastructures and logistics to firm performance in emerging economies

The individual entrepreneur is not the sole locus of value creation. The entrepreneurial activity needs to be placed in a broader context which consists of all the elements that are required to sustain productive entrepreneurship, the so-called entrepreneurial ecosystem (Stam, 2015; Stam and Spigel, 2018; Stam and van de Ven, 2021). By commercializing innovations, entrepreneurs act as agents that trigger the mechanism of transferring knowledge advances into economic growth. Even where entrepreneurial initiative is present, this process of transmission can be either hindered or facilitated by the environment in which the businesses operate (Acs et al., 2018), which provides resources that agents can mobilize to exploit entrepreneurial opportunities (Acs et al., 2014; Alvedalen and Boschma, 2017; Brown and Mason, 2017). Indeed, the entrepreneurial context can influence how aggressively the firm will pursue growth and with what outcomes (Acs et al., 2016).

The literature on entrepreneurship unanimously recognized that knowledge is key in ecosystems (Acs et al., 2013; Cantner et al., 2021; Stam and van de Ven, 2021). In this regard, the KSTE sustains that entrepreneurial behaviour is a response to profitable opportunities from knowledge spillovers. An entrepreneurial context that is rich in knowledge encourages the development of new technologies, promotes the entrepreneurial activity and enhances the economic performance of firms (Audretsch and Lehmann 2005).

The spillover of knowledge from its source is not automatic but is hampered by the knowledge filter, a term that refers to the barriers that prevent knowledge from spilling over for innovation and commercialization (Acs et al., 2013). In this regard, transport infrastructure development improves connectivity and interactions, thus facilitating the exchange of knowledge and ideas that could fuel entrepreneurial ventures (Audretsch and Lehmann, 2005; Ghio et al., 2015; Audretsch et al., 2015). From this perspective, the mobility of economic agents serves as the conduit of knowledge spillovers (Audretsch and Keilbach, 2005). Locations with well-developed transport infrastructures, by attracting new firm establishment (Holl, 2004a; Arauzo-Carod and Viladecans-Marsal, 2009), promote agglomeration mechanisms that, in turn, enhance knowledge exchange and diffusion between firms — because geographic proximity is important for the transmission of knowledge spillovers (Audretsch, 1998) — labour market pooling and input sharing. Moreover, transport infrastructures can have a positive impact on firm-level productivity by reducing transport costs and facilitating the movement of goods and the labour force (Holl, 2016).

From the discussion above emerges that transport infrastructure endowment, among other elements of the entrepreneurial context, by enabling knowledge spillovers, has the potential to stimulate firm-level performance. Several studies show that transport infrastructures play a key role in economic processes, but, to the best of our knowledge, there is a lack of studies that place attention on transport infrastructures as a crucial element in the entrepreneurial ecosystem (see Wurth et al., 2022), with a few exceptions (Audretsch et al., 2015). Therefore, this paper contributes to the research on entrepreneurship and small business economics by analysing the economic performance of firms to assess whether the reason why some firms outperform others can be also traced to the unobserved heterogeneity due to country-level differences in the transport infrastructure endowment and, thus, in the transmission of knowledge spillovers and in the ability to foster entrepreneurial activity.

The concept of entrepreneurial ecosystem (Cao and Shi, 2021) and KSTE (Iftikhar et al., 2020) in the context of emerging economies and developing countries recently starts receiving attention. Firms in emerging economies are typically small and young and offer significant benefits in terms of job creation, innovation and, ultimately, economic growth. Among the others, Decker et al. (2015) demonstrate that the expansion of young firms, but also their creation, can be a significant driver of growth. In emerging economies, the endowment of transport infrastructures is lower and shows different bottlenecks compared to more developed economies. Its improvement, by fostering knowledge spillovers among firms, is expected to have a positive relationship with their economic performance and, thus, on the economy as a whole.

In this context, the difference between connectivity and accessibility needs to be considered. While connectivity is an attribute of a network and measures the minimum number of links needed to reach all nodes from all other nodes, accessibility is an attribute of a node and measures the minimum number of links needed to reach all or certain nodes from a specific node (ESCAP, 2007). We suggest that a clear distinction should be made in terms of networks and nodes, which can be defined as “connectivity” and “accessibility” characteristics of a transportation system. Therefore, we develop the research hypotheses on the role of transport infrastructures in firm performance by distinguishing transport infrastructures by their attributes, as networks, when considering roads and railways, and as nodes, when we refer to ports and airports. Finally, we also consider the role of logistic system and services in supporting firm performance

2.2 Empirical evidence and hypothesis development

The first paper to examine the link between infrastructures and entrepreneurship is that of Audretsch et al. (2015), who posit that, by enhancing connectivity and linkages that facilitate entrepreneurial opportunity recognition, infrastructures can promote the creation of start-ups. Audretsch et al. (2015) show that railways do promote the start-up of new firms in German regions, while highways yield limited or no impact on entrepreneurial activity because Germany has a very dense motorway network, extensively connecting even remote areas.

In the specific context of high-speed rail (HSR), Chen and Hall (2011) show that HSR reinforces the transition of local economies to knowledge economies, and Komikado et al. (2021) find that HSR development promotes knowledge productivity enhancements at an international scale. Some studies also point out that the impact of HSR on knowledge sharing is largely due to its uniqueness in offering inter-regional passenger transport (Inoue et al., 2017; Tamura, 2017).

Agrawal et al. (2017) and Bottasso et al. (2022) place their attention to road networks. Agrawal et al. (2017) explore the effect of highways on regional innovation in the USA and report evidence that an increase in regional highway stock leads to an increase in regional patenting. This happens because roads have a strong knowledge diffusion effect because facilitate the local knowledge flows and increase the likelihood that innovators access knowledge inputs even from more distant neighbours. Particularly, highways have a larger impact on innovation in low-density regions, where inventors are likely to be more spread out. Bergantino et al. (2013) investigate the R&D efficiency of Italian regions and find that disparities in rail and road network development reflect on regional performance. Also, Bottasso et al. (2022) focus on the innovative performance of Italian regions and show that highway stock has an innovation-enhancing effect because it fosters collaborations among inventors by reducing travel costs and it increases the centrality in the regional innovation network. Particularly, highways are found to increase innovation by spreading knowledge diffusion between regions and not only within regions.

The empirical evidence on emerging economies is mostly on China. Wang et al. (2018) investigate the relationship between city-level road density and firm-level innovation, showing that increasing road density spurs innovation by expanding market size and promoting knowledge spillovers. At a more aggregate level, Zhang et al. (2020) show that HSR increases regional proximity and, thus, stimulates information flows and corporate innovation. Moreover, Yang et al. (2021) show that HSR not only accelerates innovation growth at prefecture-level but also promotes innovation convergence. Consistently, Komikado et al. (2021) explain that the existence of HSR stations, a proxy of accessibility, is positively associated with knowledge productivity, and Tang et al. (2022) show that knowledge spillovers are important manifestations through which HSR promotes regional innovation and total factor productivity.

On this basis, we argue that the development of transport networks improves connectivity, reduces the cost of face-to-face communication, fosters collaborations and knowledge spillovers and, ultimately, can enhance the performance of firms in emerging economies. Therefore, we put forth the following research hypothesis:

  • Hypothesis 1: Transport networks are positively related to the performance of firms in emerging economies.

Zhang and Graham (2020) develop a conceptual framework showing that the impact of air transport on the economy mostly arises through its supply chain effects and spillover effects. The supply chain effects are related to the employment and the economic activity that air transport supports both directly and indirectly. The spillover effects are related to the substantial reduction of long-distance constraints that increases accessibility and enables enhanced economic interactions, thereby creating locational advantages. Bilotkach (2015) shows that air transport has a positive impact on key indicators of regional economic development in the USA, such as the employment, the number of business establishments and the average wage. Along the same lines are the findings of Bergantino et al. (2013), according to which air accessibility plays a positive role in increasing regional R&D output in Italy. The positive linkage of airport activities to regional economies more recently emerges also for New Zealand (Fu et al., 2021). Finally, evidence from Chinese cities shows that airports have a positive and significant effect on economic development, not limited to the economy of the city served, but extended to other connected cities (Chen et al., 2021).

Bottasso et al. (2014) explore the impact of port activities on local development by assessing the direct and indirect (i.e. spillover) effects of seaports in regions located in thirteen European countries. Their results reveal that ports tend to increase GDP in the area where they are located, but there are significant positive spillover effects on the GDP of nearby regions, suggesting that the economic relevance of ports spreads beyond the port regions. Additionally, the presence of a port is found to be an attractive factor for the location decisions of foreign direct investments (Belderbos and Carree, 2002; Deichmann et al., 2005).

The discussion above induces us to conjecture that transport nodes, by increasing the accessibility and the economic interactions, improve the performance of firms in emerging economies. Thus, we formulate the following research hypothesis:

  • Hypothesis 2: Transport nodes are positively related to the performance of firms in emerging economies.

Overall, well-developed transport infrastructures are expected to improve a country’s accessibility, which is crucial for firms also because a substantial part of their activities requires moving inputs and outputs. The organization of modern economies is built upon an efficient transport system, and an increasing role is played by the logistics sector in overcoming the constraints of time and distance in the supply chains.

Logistics is defined as the movement, handling and storage of goods from supply, through production and distribution to customers (Holl, 2006). In an increasingly globalized environment, logistics also become one of the main engines of competitiveness and economic development (Jiang et al., 2016). As demonstrated by the literature, there is a bidirectional link between logistics performance and economic development (Arvis et al., 2007; Lean et al., 2014), but this link has been less investigated at micro-level.

Considering all the above, we argue that a more efficient logistics system with more qualitative connectivity reduces time and distance constraints and provides better linkages between suppliers, firms and customers, thus supporting the economic performance of firms. Therefore, we formulate the following research hypothesis:

  • Hypothesis 3: The performance of the logistics system is positively related to the performance of firms in emerging economies.

Summing up, this paper is among the few in the literature that comprehensively explores the role of transport infrastructure endowment — transport networks, transport nodes and logistics system — in the performance of firms in emerging economies.

2.3 Measures of transport infrastructures

The empirical literature declines transport infrastructures differently based on measures used, which may influence the evidence provided.

The availability of data for transport is usually one of the key constraints to study the effect of the transport system on the creation, performance and survival of firms. It becomes more difficult for emerging economies, where previous analyses rely more on considering firms’ perceptions of transportation constraints (see, among others, Dollar et al., 2005; Carlin et al., 2006; Aterido et al., 2011) that may lead to methodological problems (Dethier et al., 2011). As a result, studies either use a crude measure of transport or have better measures of transport for fewer time periods (Melo et al., 2010).

Various studies use general measures for transport. For instance, Coughlin and Segev (2000) employ a dummy variable to account for the presence of interstate highways, which appears to be positively associated with the number of new firms in US counties. Fotopoulos and Spence (1999) consider the amount of per capita public investment in the public infrastructure provision, having a positive impact on new plant openings in Greece. Holl (2004a, 2004b, 2004c) uses distance to the motorway network to measure the availability of this transport infrastructure. She finds that improvements in the distance to the nearest motorway have an important role in the formation of new establishments in Portuguese and Spanish municipalities, where plant openings are higher in municipalities that have access to a motorway within 10 km and fall with increasing distance.

This issue appears relevant to be discussed, given that the literature provides different results related to entrepreneurship, innovation and, more generally, to firm economic performance depending also on how transport infrastructures are defined and measured in empirical analysis. Indeed, Audretsch et al. (2015) posit that research needs to take infrastructure more seriously by creating new measures of more specific types of infrastructures, pointing out another fundamental question, such as the role of infrastructure quality. The types of infrastructures can be either considered as measures of accessibility in the transport network (see Audretsch et al., 2015; Yang et al., 2021) or as connectivity measures when related to transport nodes, considering flows or number of destinations (see Bilotkach, 2015; Bottasso et al., 2014).

In Table 1, we provide a summary of the main empirical works that investigate the role of transport infrastructures from the KSTE perspective, namely, in promoting knowledge transmission between firms and, at a more aggregate level, between regions or countries. This table offers an overview of how transport measures are defined and how they contribute to the empirical evidence.

Table 1 Summary of empirical evidence, measures and definitions of transport infrastructures in the knowledge spillover theory literature

3 Data and variables

To test the hypotheses on the relationship between country-level transport endowment and firm performance in emerging economies, we combine firm-level data on 32 countries from East Europe and Central Asia, drawn by the fifth round of BEEPS V conducted in the period 2012–2016Footnote 1 by the EBRD and the WB, with country-level data, collected from institutional data sources. Based on face-to-face interviews with firms’ owners and managers, BEEPS V provides detailed performance information on about 16,000 firms from the main manufacturing and service sectors.

To analyse firm performance, we rely on the log-linear Cobb–Douglas production function with constant return to scale, where the dependent variable is the natural logarithm of firm productivity. Given the information gathered from BEEPS V, we define firm productivity as sales (in US dollars) per employee, the so-called labour productivity.Footnote 2 Moreover, we proxy the variable capital with the investments (in machinery, vehicles, equipment, land or buildings) per employee in US dollars, expressed in natural logarithm.Footnote 3

We augment the Cobb–Douglas production function by including a set of firm-level explanatory variables to control for internal factors that might influence the heterogeneity in performance among firms. Many empirical works investigate the relationship between firms’ growth and age (e.g. Coad et al., 2013). As age is closely related to competitive processes, as innovation activities (Mateut, 2018), the relationships with firm performance are expected to be positiveFootnote 4 (Jensen and McGuckjn, 1997). On this basis, we define the binary variable start-up equal to 1 if the firm starts operations in the last 5 years, 0 otherwise. Exporting firms are typically considered more productive than non-exporting firms (Bernard et al., 1995) with significant implications for international strategic decisions (Pongelli et al., 2016). Also, foreign participation in firms’ ownership seems to positively affect performance, especially in emerging economies (Asiedu and Esfahani, 2001; Douma et al., 2006; Gurbuz and Aybars, 2010; Hintošová and Kubíkovál, 2016). Thus, we include in the analysis the above-mentioned aspects by introducing the dummy variables: exporter, equal to 1 if the firm exports some of its outputs, 0 otherwise; and foreign, equal to 1 if 1% of assets or more are owned by private foreign individuals, companies or organizations, 0 otherwise. In a globalized and competitive marketplace, the endowment of a skilled workforce can explain why some firms outperform others (Barney et al., 2001; Acedo et al., 2006). The literature provides evidence of the positive association between human capital and overall firm performance (Crook et al. 2011), especially for small firms (Lepak and Snell, 2002; Coder et al., 2017). Therefore, we define the variable qualification as the share of permanent full-time employees holding a university degree. Finally, to control for sectoral patterns, we define a set of industry dummies, named SEC.Footnote 5 Due to missing values, we end up with 10,954 firms with complete observations.

To address our research hypotheses, firm-level productivity is associated with different measures of country-level transport endowment. Specifically, to test Hypothesis 1 on transport networks, we define two variables: road, the total roads in km per square km, including expressways and paved and unpaved urban roads, and rail, the total railways in km per square km, including public and non-public railways. To test Hypothesis 2 on transport nodes, we define the two variables: airport, the number of airports paved runways per 1000 square km, and port, the number of total ports.Footnote 6 Finally, to test Hypothesis 3, we employ the logistic performance index (LPI),Footnote 7 providing an assessment of the managerial and physical effectiveness of a country’s logistics. Overall, this measure indicates the relative ease and efficiency with which products can be moved and how the logistics system works as trade facilitator.

The sample of emerging economies considered consists of countries belonging to different income groups with disparities in terms of development. Therefore, we introduce as control variable gap, the ratio between the GDP per capita (expressed in PPP constant 2011 international USD) of the most developed economy in the sample and the observed country (Y*/Y, where Y* is the most developed country in the sample and Y the observed country), to account for different levels of development across countries that can affect firm performance.

Country-level data are collected from the European Commission, the World Bank and the Central Intelligence Agency for the reference year 2011. A table with a summary definition of variables and their sources is included in the Appendix (Tables 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12). General descriptive statistics are reported in Table 2.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics

Descriptive statistics show high heterogeneity levels. The mean of labour productivity is about 121,000 US dollars per employee displaying significant variation among countries. Around 15% of the firms in the sample are start-ups representing the age class from 0 to 5 years, while the average age of firms is around 15 years, and 86% are small and medium enterprises, suggesting that firms in emerging economies are quite young and relatively small. Overall, firms with the participation of foreign capital represent 7% of the sample, while only 22% of firms occur in export activities, with considerable variation both across firms and countries. Lastly, the share of permanent employees holding a university degree reported by firms is around 33% of the total permanent full-time employees. In the Appendix, we provide additional descriptive statistics regarding the between and within variability of firm-level variables due to country clusters (Tables 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12). There is a considerable variation in the mean of firms’ labour productivity among countries, from 22,000 US dollars per employee for Ukraine up to 498,000 US dollars for Cyprus. Figure 1 shows labour productivity for each country in the sample.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Mean of firms’ labour productivity by country clusters (sales in US dollars per employee). Source: Authors’ computation based on BEEPS V data. Firm-level data are collected over the period 2012–2016 and refer to the fiscal year previous to the period in which the survey was carried out

Additional descriptive statistics of transport infrastructures and logistics and control variables are reported in Table 3.

Table 3 Descriptive statistics of country-level variables by country for the year 2011.

The density of roads and rails shows considerable differences between countries. The average density is 0.63 and 0.03, respectively. The less endowed country is Mongolia for both kinds of infrastructures, while the most endowed countries are Hungary and Czech Republic. The number of airports paved per 1000 square km shows also high variation, where Mongolia is the last country with a density value of 0.01, while Czech Republic and Cyprus have the highest airport density of the group, with a value of 1.62. As far as ports are concerned, Turkey is the country with the highest number of ports. Clearly, the presence of port facilities is due to the geographical position of a country. Finally, the average score of LPI is 2.82. Poland has the best logistic performance of the sample countries, scoring 3.43 points, whereas Mongolia has the worst scoring, only 2.25 points. The correlation matrix among country-level variables is reported in the Appendix (Tables 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12).

4 Firm performance nested in countries: the multilevel modelling approach

The hierarchical structure of the micro-level data — firms (level 1) nested in countries (level 2) — implies a violation of the assumption of independence among observations within the second-level units. To deal with this issue, we refer to the class of multilevel models enabling us to explicitly model the hierarchical structure of the data and the unobserved heterogeneity (Raudenbush and Bryk, 2002; Goldstein, 2011; Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012).

First, the level-1 model corresponds to the following linear regression model:

$${\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{LABOUR\ PRODUCTIVITY}_{ij}={\beta}_{0j}+{\beta}_{1j}{CAPITAL}_{ij}+{\beta}_{2j}{STARTUP}_{ij}+{\beta}_{3j}{EXPORTER}_{ij}\\ {}+{\beta}_{4j}{QUALIFICATION}_{ij}+{\beta}_{5j}{FOREIGN}_{ij}+{\sum}_{k=1}{\delta}_{0k}{SEC}_{ik}+{e}_{ij}\end{array}}$$
(1)

where i indexes the firm and j the country, β0j is the standard intercept, β1j to β5j are the standard slope coefficients, and eij is the standard error term.

Second, the level-2 model assumes that the intercept (β0j) and the coefficients (β1j to β5j) are nested in countries:

$${\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{\beta}_{0j}={\gamma}_{00}+{\gamma}_{01}{GAP}_j+{\gamma}_{02}{ROADS}_j+{\gamma}_{03}{RAILS}_j+{\gamma}_{04}{AIRPORTS}_j+{\gamma}_{05}{PORTS}_j+{\gamma}_{06}{LPI}_j+{u}_{0j}\\ {}{\beta}_{1j}={\gamma}_{10}+{u}_{1j}\\ {}{\beta}_{2j}={\gamma}_{20}+{u}_{2j}\\ {}{\beta}_{3j}={\gamma}_{30}+{u}_{3j}\\ {}{\beta}_{4j}={\gamma}_{40}+{u}_{4j}\\ {}{\beta}_{5j}={\gamma}_{50}+{u}_{5j}\end{array}}$$
(2)

where γ00 is the estimated mean of sales across countries and the coefficients γ01 to γ06 are the fixed effects of each country-level predictor, while the coefficients γ10 to γ50 are the estimated mean of the firm-level slopes across countries, and u0j to u5j are the random-specific country effects that represent also the level-2 error term. The random effects can be considered as the effect of omitted country-specific variables, causing performance heterogeneity among firms within the same country (Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, 2012).

By combining the level-1 model and level-2 model, the reduced form of the random-coefficients model can be expressed as

$${\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{LABOUR\ PRODUCTIVITY}_{ij}={\gamma}_{00}+{\sum}_{m=1}^M{\gamma}_{0m}{Z}_{mj}+{\sum}_{n=1}^N{\gamma}_n{X}_{nj}+{\sum}_{n=0}^N{u}_{nj}\\ {}+{\sum}_{k=1}{\delta}_{0k}{SEC}_{ik}+{e}_{ij}\end{array}}$$
(3)

where n is the number of firm-level predictors (N=5), m is the number of country-level predictors (M=6), Xnj and Zmj are, respectively, the predictor vectors, and unj is the vector of random effects. The random effects \({\sum}_{n=0}^N{u}_{nj}\) represent all the factors at country-level that are not observed and are not explained by firm-level characteristics, thus providing useful information on cross-country differences.

We carry out the multilevel analysis by going through different steps. First, to detect the existence of the hierarchical structure in the data, we consider the variance-components model that includes only the intercept among covariates. Second, by adding level-1 variables, we estimate a random-intercept model, where only the intercept is allowed to vary across countries. Third, we consider the random-coefficient model, with only level-1 variables, allowing also the estimated coefficients of level-1 variables to vary across countries. Finally, we extend the latter model by introducing level-2 predictors to assess the effect of transport infrastructures and logistic services in reducing level-2 variability, thus explaining intra-country firm performance differences not already explained by firm-level characteristics.

Further, the Likelihood ratio test, which assumes under the null hypothesis that random effects are jointly equal to zero, is performed after each regression to test the goodness of our model decision. We also test for firm performance variability across countries by calculating the intra-class correlation (ICC) coefficients (ρ) across estimated models, which express the ratio between country-level variance and the total variance, showing the proportion of total variance in firm performance that is accounted for by countries. The intra-class correlation quantifies the degree to which firms with a fixed degree of relatedness resemble each other in terms of a quantitative trait — operating within the same country.

5 Results and discussion

5.1 Baseline regressions

In Table 4, we collect the empirical results of the variance-components model, reported in column (1) and the random-intercept model and the random-coefficient model with only firm-level variables, reported in Columns (2) and (3), respectively.Footnote 8 Fixed effects are reported for the intercept and the slopes in the upper part of the table, while the random effects are shown in the lower part of the table. All regressions include industry dummies. The LR test reported at the bottom of the table for each regression confirms that the multilevel model is preferred to the linear model.

Table 4 Results of variance-components model, random-intercept model and random-coefficient model

The estimated coefficients ρ of ICC for each model, reported in the last row of the table, are statistically significant with a value of about 26% across regression models. This is evidence of the existence of a hierarchical structure in the data that needs to be modelled through a multilevel approach.

The variance-components model provides evidence of the existence of random effects at country-level. Firm productivity differs in mean by countries of about 0.76 standard deviation, which captures the unobserved country-level heterogeneity that will be further investigated in the next section. The random intercept is statistically significant at 5% level.

The random-intercept model with firm-level variables shows a reduction of level-1 residuals. The intercept has a magnitude of about 0.75 standard deviation from the mean, and it is statistically significant at 5% level. This indicates that there are differences across countries, which are related to a different country’s context in which firms operate. At country-level, some firms have better performance, other worst. The measure is given by how widely the random-intercept is distributed around the estimated mean by country. The predicted country random-intercept lies for 44% of the countries in a range of [0.07, 1.36], meaning that, for these countries, there is a positive association between national context and labour productivity. Oppositely, for countries showing a negative predicted country random-intercept, the unobserved characteristics are related to lower labour productivity of firms with respect to the overall mean.

We start the discussion by looking first at fixed effects of firm-level variables as reported in column (3) for the random-coefficient. Particularly, capital has a positive and highly significant coefficient, suggesting that greater productivity is associated with higher investment intensity. start-up has a negative coefficient, suggesting that younger firms have lower labour productivity compared to more mature firms. Exporter has a positive and highly significant coefficient, providing evidence that greater labour productivity is associated with exporting firms. Qualification has a positive coefficient, suggesting that greater labour productivity is associated with higher qualified human capital. Finally, foreign has a positive coefficient, meaning that foreign participation in firm’s assets is positively related to firm performance.

Turning attention to the random-coefficients, they are statistically significant at 1% level and the random intercept at 5% level. The random effects indicate how widely the estimated intercept and coefficients are distributed around the mean, shown in the fixed effects part. The estimated random effects for variables capital, start-up, export, qualification and foreign are largely widespread around their mean, which indicates that firms, given these internal characteristics, perform differently in different countries.

Figure 2 shows the predicted random effects of the country random-intercept, namely, the standard deviations of each country from the overall mean of labour productivity.Footnote 9 Firms show different labour productivity due to unobserved country-level factors, implying that such differences can be associated with a better or worse country context.

Fig 2
figure 2

Ranking of country-predicted random effects (intercept of random-coefficients model)

After controlling for firm-specific characteristics, large differences emerge among countries. Most EU emerging economies lie in the upper right-hand of the rank. These countries appear to be characterized by better conditions that might determine better business environments, also reflected in their higher firm performance.

5.2 The role of transport infrastructures and logistics

We collect in Table 5 the results of the intercept-as-outcome model, by which we assess the relationship between transport infrastructures and logistics variables and firm performance. Given the quite high correlation of country-level variables (see Appendix Tables 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12), we include them once at a time in the model.

Table 5 Results of intercept-as-outcome models with infrastructures’ country-level predictors

The macro-control variable gap is negatively related to firm performance: it can be interpreted as the distance of the level of development of a given country from the most developed country in the sample, so that the larger the gap the worse the performance of firms in that country. Additionally, gap is negatively correlated with all the transport infrastructures and logistics variables, suggesting that less developed countries have also worse transport infrastructure endowment.

The variables road and rail show positive and statistically significant coefficients at levels 1% and 5% of confidence, respectively (see columns (1) and (2)). Therefore, Hypothesis 1 is fully supported. The extension of the road and rail networks explains firm performance heterogeneity across countries. Particularly, the road network significantly reduces the random intercept to about 0.38 standard deviation from the overall sales mean.

Our results are consistent with previous evidence on transport networks and firm performance in emerging economies, particularly with Wang et al. (2018) showing a positive relationship between city road density and firm-level innovation. From a more aggregate perspective, results are also in line with Bottasso et al. (2022), showing a positive relationship between road networks and knowledge spillovers in Italian regions, but partially differ from Audretsch et al. (2015). The latter find that road infrastructures have little or no effect on firm creation, possibly attributable to the high density of motorway networks in Germany, while, in emerging economies, road networks are remarkably less developed; thus, their improvement is likely to promote firms’ activities.

The variable airport has a positive and significant coefficient at 1% level of confidence, while the coefficient of the variable port is not statistically significant (see columns (3) and (4)). It follows that Hypothesis 2 is partially and weakly supported, only with respect to the positive role of airports. In this case, part of the variability at country-level remains unexplained, due to other national factors possibly associated with it. It should be noted that other papers, using different measures for airport activities, such as passenger flows or number of destinations (Bilotkach, 2015), obtain stronger positive evidence. Overall, we argue that the presence of airports is positively associated with firm performance also by favouring international knowledge spillovers (Simmie, 2002; Bascavusoglu-Moreau and Li (2013). The non-significant role of ports is not in line with Bottasso et al. (2014), probably because of the different measure used, namely, port throughput. Unfortunately, for the emerging economies considered, there is a lack of other indicators of port infrastructure (such as length of quays, berths capacity or occupational profile).

The variable LPI has a positive and significant coefficient at 1% level of confidence (see column (5)). Therefore, Hypothesis 3 is strongly confirmed. A more developed logistic system of a country, by giving to firms transaction cost advantages in organizing an appropriate distributive channel, can contribute to enhance the relationship-building process between business partners. In other words, the performance of a country’s logistic system is positively associated with the performance of firms by reducing time and distance in the supply chains and by generating knowledge spillover benefits between business partners, both domestically and internationally.

After country-level variables are introduced, the coefficient of the intercept decreases considerably. The estimated value of the random intercept remains significant meaning that other country factors matter for firm performance. The intra-class correlations confirm the role of national transport infrastructure variables in explaining part of the unexplained variability of firm performance among countries. The intra-class correlations decrease up to 0.081 compared to 0.256 for the random-coefficient model. This allows to argue that an important part of firm’s labour productivity is surely explained by firm-level characteristics, but part of country-level variance is explained by transport infrastructures and logistic system and services, with specific aspects, such as road, rail, airport and logistics, being associated with better economic performance at the firm-level.

6 Robustness check

6.1 Bayesian model based on MCMC approach

To investigate the robustness of the previous analysis, the Bayesian model based on Markov chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) approach is computed in alternative to the frequentist analysis.

A multilevel problem concerns a population with a hierarchical structure. In samples from such a population can be described, the individual observations are in general not independent. For example, firms in the same country tend to perform similarly to each other, because of selection processes and because of the environment they share. In general, it occurs in survey research if the sample is not taken at random, but cluster sampling from geographical areas is used instead. It is also called “design effect”. It depends on both intra-class correlation and cluster size. As a result, the average correlation among firms in the same country can be higher than the average correlations between firms operating in different countries. Standard statistical tests lean heavily in the assumption of independence of the observations. If this assumption is violated, and in multilevel data, this is almost always the case (Hox et al., 2017); the estimate of the standard errors of conventional statistical tests is much too small, resulting in many spuriously “significant” results. The biases that may be the effect of violation of the assumption of independent observation are still important assumptions to check (Hobert, 2000).

Our previous model is completely informed by the data: in this view, everything that we need to know for the model is encoded in the training data we have available, which gives a single point estimate for the output. This can be interpreted as the most likely estimate, given the data.

However, we might like to express our estimate as a distribution of possible values. The aim of the Bayesian approach is not to find the single “best” value of the model parameters, but rather to determine the posterior distribution for the model parameters.

A Bayesian model has two parts: a statistical model that describes the distribution of the response variable (y) given the unknown parameters (θ) of the model and a prior distribution that describes beliefs about the unknown parameters (θ) independent from the data, where the statistical model is the likelihood function L(θ; y). Therefore, not only the response is generated from a probability distribution, but the model parameters are assumed to come from a distribution as well. We have a posterior distribution for the model parameters that is proportional to the likelihood of the data multiplied by the prior probability of the parameters. The updating from the prior distribution to the posterior distribution is carried out using Bayes’ theorem:

$$p\left(\theta |\boldsymbol{y}\right)\propto f\left(\boldsymbol{y}|\theta \right)\bullet \pi \left(\theta \right)=L\left(\theta |\boldsymbol{y}\right)\bullet \pi \left(\theta \right)$$
(4)

where f(y| θ) is the sampling distribution of the response variable and π(θ) is the prior distribution of θ.

Bayesian methods explicitly use probability distributions to quantify uncertainties about the unknown parameters. Probability describes the degree of belief rather than long-run frequency. This is a considerable deviation from the classical statistics paradigm. As a result, Bayesian inference is carried out conditional on the observed data and does not rely on the assumption that a hypothetical infinite population of data exists.

We implement the Bayesian framework based on Markov chain Monte Carlo technique using Gibbs sampling algorithm. The analysis also compares the existence of the hierarchical structure of the data modelled through the multilevel approach with the linear regression model as reported in Table 6.

Table 6 Bayesian MCMC estimations of linear and multilevel model

Despite coefficient parameters’ estimates using the linear regression and the multilevel model being quite similar to the simulated posterior distribution of the parameters using the Bayesian approach, information about the fitted Bayesian model, as the average efficiency of the MCMC algorithm and marginal likelihood (ML),Footnote 10 the multilevel one results overwhelmingly more appropriate to describe the data. The efficiency summaries for any parameter using the Bayesian approach are reported in the Appendix (Tables 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12).

6.2 Alternative specification of the Cobb–Douglas production function

As mentioned in Section 3, due to the lack of information in the data on the cost of capital for the whole sample of firms, we proxy capital by investments. However, BEEPS V for a sub-sample of firms provides information on the capital stock as well as on the cost of material and intermediate inputs. Therefore, we re-estimate the multilevel model by measuring the variable capital by the natural logarithm of the replacement cost for machinery, land and buildings per employee, and we also add the variable inputs as the natural logarithm of the total cost of raw materials and intermediate goods used in production (Audretsch et al., 2020). However, the estimation of random effects with a highly reduced number of observations available for the sub-sample (20.4% of the initial sample) does not allow to control for further explanatory variables and their related random effects. Therefore, we need to specify a more parsimonious model, in which, besides capital, inputs and industry-specific dummies, we introduce only transport infrastructures and logistics variables. As shown in Table 7, the estimations are fully consistent with the first specification of the Cobb–Douglas production function shown in Section 5.

Table 7 Robustness check of Cobb–Douglas function with infrastructures’ country-level predictors

7 Conclusions

The literature on entrepreneurship has focused on the ecosystems to shed light on the elements that can impact entrepreneurial activity (Acs et al., 2014, 2016, 2018; Stam, 2015; Alvedalen and Boschma, 2017; Brown and Mason, 2017; Stam and Spigel, 2018; Stam and van de Ven, 2021). In this regard, we embed the role of transport endowment as a part of the physical infrastructure in the entrepreneurial ecosystem literature (Audretsch et al., 2015). Indeed, transport infrastructures, by enhancing connectivity and interactions, facilitate the exchange of knowledge and ideas that could support entrepreneurship (Audretsch and Lehmann, 2005; Ghio et al., 2015; Audretsch et al., 2015). Previous studies have been mostly conducted by adopting an aggregate perspective, while the channels through which transport endowment is related to firms’ activities at micro-level remain overlooked especially for less developed countries.

With this work, we commit to shedding light on the relationship between country-level transport infrastructures and logistics system and services with the performance of firms from a micro-analysis perspective, while controlling for firm-level factors. Some studies focus on China, due to investments in improving the transport infrastructure system in recent years, while Eastern Europe and Central Asia countries miss this perspective of analysis. We consider different types of transport infrastructures, such as roads, railways, airports and ports, along with the overall performance of the country’s logistics services.

In doing so, we adopt the appropriate approach to study a hierarchically structured phenomenon such as performance. The multilevel approach allows us to model the unobserved country-level heterogeneity in firms’ labour productivity and to test whether it is related to different types of transport infrastructure in each country. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to examine whether a country’s transport infrastructure is directly associated with the performance of enterprises in less developed economies.

Our results show that although most of the variability in firms’ labour productivity is related to their internal characteristics, transport endowment also plays a role in their economic performance. More specifically, we find evidence that the extent of the road and rail transport networks has a strong positive relationship with firms’ productivity. Moreover, the presence of airports and the performance of the logistics system of a country are also able to capture differences in performances across countries, while ports seem to have no influence on them.

This paper contributes to the literature on firm performance and transport economics by showing that the positive role of transport infrastructures on economic growth and development is also due to the positive relationship it has at firm-level. We argue that this process is particularly favoured by transport networks, promoting knowledge spillovers that, in turn, create business opportunities for entrepreneurs. It also highlights the role of transport infrastructure investments in emerging economies as a pathway to drive growth and accelerate the catch-up process. While in higher-income countries, investments in transport infrastructures mostly address the need for replacement and maintenance; in low-income countries, investments are needed to improve transport infrastructures and to bring them up to the level of those in more advanced economies (EBRD, 2018). A limitation of this study is that it does not take into account spillover effects among nearby areas, which might be relevant for a network industry. However, this can be seen as an avenue for future research.

Finally, this paper creates a paradigm for future studies to improve the understanding of the interdependence between different levels of analysis to design more complex and comprehensive transport investment strategies and logistics system and servicesdevelopment policies. We are aware, however, of the relevance that the availability of panel data over longer periods could have for determining the effect of changes in transport infrastructures on firm performance. In addition, the availability in the future of higher quality data for transport infrastructures, allowing a more detailed analysis of different types of networks and nodes, would improve research insights.