1 Introduction

Joseph Schumpeter (1934) was the first to defend that financial intermediaries in the capital market are essential for innovation and economic growth. However, due to asymmetric information between entrepreneurs and investors, several firms are faced with financing constraints. Usually, innovative firms are more financially constrained than non-innovative ones (Belin et al. 2011; Bah and Dumontier 2001; Aghion et al. 2004). Indeed, in addition to the problem of asymmetric information, innovative firms have fewer collateralizable assets (Hall and Lerner 2010) because “the capital created by R&D is largely intangibleFootnote 1 and firm-specific, limiting its resale market value” (Hall 2009:11). This situation could be associated with a higher risk for lenders if the firm has not enough valuable collateral since, in the case of non-payment of the debt by the borrower, the investor’s loss is also higher. For this reason, lenders generally request higher collateral, in order to reduce their loss and considering the observed-risk hypothesis (Blazy and Weill 2013). So due to uncertainty and risk, financial institutions are reluctant to invest in R&D projects compared to more traditional business projects (Mazzucato 2013).

Financing constraints have been highlighted by many authors (Canepa and Stoneman 2008; Iammarino et al. 2009) as a significant obstacle to innovation, but the degree of exposure to this problem is not homogeneous among firms. The identification of constrained firms is particularly important for policymakers in order to design effective policy orientation and to give public support to firms most in need (Hottenrott and Peters 2012).

The present paper focuses on direct assessment of financing constraints through the anonymous survey on SMEs’ access to finance in the euro area (SAFE), undertaken together by the European Commission and the European Central Bank (ECB).

Using a recursive bivariate model, where the first equation is to demonstrate an innovative behavior and the second to be a financially constrained firm, the paper aims to (i) identify which factors, both internal and external to the firm, have a higher impact on hindering access to finance; and (ii) assess how far innovative behavior (strategy and typology) can induce financing constraints. On the other hand, the present study also aims to assess differences between innovative firms and non-innovate ones, as regards firms’ perception about the characteristics of the supply side of the financial market. The study centers on European SMEs that have growth ambitions and therefore need external finance since information about obstacles is only available for this group of firms.

The contribution and originality of the paper are based on the inclusion in the model of variables related to firms’ external factors and linked with financial market characteristics, considered limiting as regards obtaining finance for growth ambitions. Indeed, most studies carried out have focused more on firms’ characteristics or countries’ institutional factors as the main determinants of firms’ financing constraints. However, the paper intends to go further and assess which constraints on the supply side lead to financing constraints. Difficulties in access to finance have been highlighted as an important obstacle to innovative activities, but the reverse relationship remains little explored. Finally, we use a data source (SAFE) that, as far as we are aware, has not previously been used to this end.

The paper is structured as follows. “Section 2” presents the theoretical framework of the study. “Section 3” describes the database. “Section 4” defines the conceptual framework and methodology. “Section 5” presents the results. “Section 6” concludes and provides some policy recommendations.

2 Background theory and literature review

From the corporate finance perspective, the decision to invest depends on the price or cost of such an investment and the required rate of return. The neo-classical long-run model of Jorgenson (1963) explains that the investment demand or the desired amount of capital stock is a function of a firm’s output and of user capital cost, where the output takes into account the price and quantity of goods and services, and the user capital cost is estimated taking in the rate of taxation, interest rate, and rate of investment replacement. Furthermore, the cost of capital is also determined by a firm’s capital structure, i.e., a mix between internal and external (debt and equity) financing. According to the Modigliani and Miller (1958) theorem, internal and external sources of financing are perfect substitutes. However, the main limitations of this hypothesis lie in the authors’ assumptions regarding perfect markets (without asymmetric information, risk, uncertainty, taxes, and bankruptcy costs) and the same cost of capital irrespective of financing sources and investment type (Damodaran 2006; Hall and Lerner 2010). Indeed, there are several reasons why internal and external financing sources not perfect substitutes are, namely the availability of internal finance, access to debt or equity financing, or the functioning of the credit market (Fazzari et al. 1988).

The use of internal sources of financing is influenced by its availability and by moral hazard problems and tax considerations. Moral hazard refers to the difficulty in separating the interests of management and ownership, and when the manager’s investment strategy does not tie in with the owner’s goal of maximizing the firm’s value (Hall and Lerner 2010). In such cases, in order to reduce agency cost,Footnote 2 owners can influence the value of the R&D investment to protect themselves from risk and by limiting access to the use of internal capital (Jensen and Meckling 1976). Tax considerations relate to the fact that debt and retained earnings are taxed differently (Auerbach 1984). For example, debt is tax-deductible at the corporate level (tax savings for interest paid on the debt), whereas using retained earnings as a source of finance could lead to the owner avoiding personal tax on dividends, but the firm’s capital gains are still taxed at the corporate level (Hall and Lerner 2010).

Nonetheless, despite the entrepreneur’s preference for internal or external sources of finance, after-tax considerations, their choices could also be influenced by credit rationing. Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) were among the main contributors in explaining the phenomena of credit rationing, arguing that if rationing exists, it is due to market failures. These authors explained that excessive demand for loans should be solved by an increase in price (interest rate), leading to an adjustment of demand and supply until reaching the market equilibrium. However, imperfect information and adverse selection lead banks to limit the supply because it is difficult for them to identify borrowers who are more likely to repay their loans. So, given the uncertainty about the expected return, due to potential risk, banks prefer to ration the supply of loans, despite the existence of demand.

Consequently, firms can face financing constraints due to the difficulty in accessing external finance but also to the insufficiency or non-availability of internal funds. A major challenge in identifying a financially constrained firm concerns also the nature of the concept, which is more subjective to each firm than empirically observable or directly measurable (Silva and Carreira 2012a).

Fazzari et al. (1988) introduced the sensitivity of investment to cash flow as an indirect measure of financing constraints, on the basis that this indicator can reflect firm liquidity, availability of internal funds for debt repayment and net worth positions, which can also have an impact on the cost of new debt. Despite some criticism and limitations,Footnote 3 this method has been used by many authors to test the effect of financing constraints on the firm’s decision to invest, both in traditional tangible assets (Minton and Schrand 1999; Moyen 2004; Fee et al. 2009) and in innovation or R&D (Himmelberg and Petersen 1994; Bond et al. 2005; Cincera and Ravet 2010; Cincera et al. 2016). Besides cash flow having a positive effect on investment, Himmelberg and Petersen (1994) also defend that its effect on R&D investment could be higher than on an ordinary investment given their different characteristics (tangibility and collateralization).

A more recent alternative to measuring financing constraints is using survey data (Canepa and Stoneman 2002; Iammarino et al. 2009; D’Este et al. 2012; Coad et al. 2016) or company report information (Hadlock and Pierce 2010). These indicators are built on the results of entrepreneur perception and self-evaluation of financing constraints. Direct measures of financing constraints can avoid some bias affecting indirect measures (Hall et al. 2016), but due to the subjective nature of self-assessment, this could also be a potential source of bias (Silva and Carreira 2012b).

The present study focuses on direct assessment of financing constraints through an anonymous survey on SMEs’ access to finance in the euro area (SAFE). Ferrando and Mulier (2013), assessing firms’ financing constraints using a SAFE database and firms’ financial statements, demonstrated that firms which perceived financing constraints have similar characteristics to those faced with an actual situation. So, we can deduce that the potential source of bias due to the self-assessment used for the SAFE database is minimal.

3 Database and sample selection

The database comes from the anonymous “Survey on the Access to Finance of SMEs in the euro area” (SAFE).Footnote 4 SAFE is conducted bi-annually together by the European Central Bank (focusing on large Euro Area countries) and the European Commission (focusing on all EU countries) since 2009. “The companies in SAFE are selected randomly from the Dun & Bradstreet business register (…). The sample sizes in the different countries were selected based on a trade-off between the costs of the survey at the euro area level and representativeness at the country level” (ECB 2016:6). The inquired firms in SAFE included firms with different ownership: family, entrepreneur, other enterprises, public shareholders, venture capitalist, or business angels, among others.Footnote 5 Since SAFE is anonymous, it is not possible to cross information with other sources.

We used data from the five first round of SAFE, which covers the period from 2014 and 2018. The database is constructed using repeated cross-sectional data. Firms surveyed are located in Euro area countries, other EU Member states, and other countries (such as Albania, the Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Iceland, Montenegro, and Turkey). Firms are asked to answer, among other topics, about the availability of financing and market conditions over the past 6 months, as well as their growth ambitions for the next 3 years, underlining financing obstacles to growth.

The present study focuses on SMEsFootnote 6 located in EU28 that expect to grow and need external finance to carry out their growth ambitions since we have information on SAFE about the main dimensions we want to assess only for this group of firms. Only firms answering that they need external financing to realize their growth ambitions are asked about the most limiting factor in acquiring this finance. Similarly, only firms expecting to grow were asked about the amount of external finance to realize their growth ambitions. Taking into account all these criteria, the initial sample (Figure S1 - Supplement material) comprises 44,573 SMEs located in EU28, which expect to increase their turnover in the next 2 to 3 years and need external finance to do so. However, only 27,546 firms provided a valid answer to all questions on the survey, and these form the sample used in the present study.Footnote 7

4 Conceptual framework and methodology

The paper aims at identifying, firstly, which factors on the supply side of financial markets have the highest impact on hindering European firms’ access to finance, and, secondly, assessing how far innovative behavior can induce financing constraints. Therefore, the first two steps involve the definition of being financially constrained and being an innovative firm. Innovative firms are those answering in the SAFE questionnaire that they had introduced in the past 12 months a new (or significantly improved) product, service, process, method, management organization, or way of selling goods or services. This classification also corresponds to the Schumpeter (1934) and OECD (2005) definition of an innovative firm. In the present study, the concept of novelty is only related to firm/entrepreneur point of view.

Concerning firms’ financial status of being financially constrained, we used the answer to the question about how great problem access to finance was for their business in the past 6 months. The answer is on a scale of 1 to 10, where 1 means it is not at all important and 10 means it is extremely important. In order to define the firms’ financial status, we need to determine the limit from which firms are considered financially constrained. Authors using the CIS database (Galia and Legros 2004; Canepa and Stoneman 2008; Iammarino et al. 2009), where the degree of importance of obstacles to innovation activities is on a 4-point Likert scale, from 0 (no effect or not relevant) to 3 (high or very important), classified firms as constrained if they responded 2 (important) or 3 (very important). Following this approach and converting the SAFE scale to the CIS scale, we obtain the limit of 7.5 or more precisely of 8. However, if we observe the mean of the degree of the problem for those firms that considered access to finance as the most pressing of all the problems listed in the survey (Table S2 in Supplement material), these firms reported a score of almost 9. Therefore, we performed preliminary estimationsFootnote 8 using three possibilities for financing constraints, considering the degree of access to finance as an important problem between 7 and 10, 8–10, and 9–10. The model where access to finance is on a scale between 9 and 10 explains the data better, for the reasons that it has higher overall rate of correct classification, pseudo R2, and likelihood functions. Therefore, we defined financially constrained firms as those rating the degree of access to finance as a pressing problem at 9 and 10.

The conceptual framework is based on the fact that innovative behavior can affect access to finance, which consequently could be an obstacle to firm growth ambitions. The underlying dynamic of this process is schematized in Fig. 1, where innovation behavior is observed before or simultaneously to the firms’ perception of access to finance as a pressing problem. As innovation behavior is observed before access to finance as a pressing problem, the inverse relationship (impact of financing on innovation) cannot be precisely tested.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Conceptual framework timeline. Source: Authors’ own elaboration

Endogeneity represents a major issue when we assess the effect of innovation behavior on whatever firms’ reported statement. According to Savignac (2008), the decision to undertake an innovative project is subject to a selective process, and both innovation behavior and financial constraints are affected by common unobservable individual characteristics. One way to deal with unobservable problems is to use a switching simultaneous-equations model, as suggested by Maddala (1983), when selectivity is due to more than one source of bias. An example of this model is the recursive bivariate probit model (RBPM), used by Savignac (2008) and Mancusi and Vezzulli (2014), to assess the effect of financing constraints on the innovation or R&D decision, respectively. The bivariate probit model is based on a probit model with sample selection, following Heckman (1979).

The RBPM adopts a structural approach in which the second equation (\( {y}_{2i}^{\ast } \)) includes the dependent variable of the first equation (y1i) as an endogenous variable, and both variables of interest are binary variables. Explanatory variables (xi) of both equations can have common elements, but also need to have some different exogenous variables in each equation (Maddala 1983). The RBPM assumes that the error terms (εi) are independent and follow a bivariate standard normalization distribution (2). However, the joint estimation of both equations is only required if the correlation coefficient of the two error terms is ρ ≠ 0, in order to generate consistent estimates.

$$ \left\{\begin{array}{c}{y}_{1i}^{\ast }={x}_{1i}{\beta}_1+{\varepsilon}_{1i},\kern1.25em {y}_{1i}=1\ if\ {y}_{1i}^{\ast }>0;0\ \mathrm{otherwise},\\ {}{y}_{2i}^{\ast }={x}_{2i}{\beta}_2+{\theta}_1{y}_{1i}+{\varepsilon}_{2i},\kern1.75em {y}_{2i}=1\ if\ {y}_{2i}^{\ast }>0;0\ \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(1)
$$ \left(\begin{array}{c}{\varepsilon}_{1i}\\ {}{\varepsilon}_{2i}\end{array}\right)\to {\Phi}_2\left[\left[\begin{array}{c}0\\ {}0\end{array}\right],\left[\begin{array}{cc}1& \rho \\ {}\rho & 1\end{array}\right]\right]\kern0.5em \mathrm{where}\ {\Phi}_2\ \mathrm{refers}\ \mathrm{to}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{bivariate}\ \mathrm{standard}\ \mathrm{normal}-\mathrm{distribution}\ \mathrm{function} $$
(2)

The ρ also reports the magnitude and direction of bias due to the endogenous nature of y1i in the second equation. For example, when ρ > 0 this means that ignoring the endogeneity of y1i biases the result of the coefficient θ1 upwards in comparison to estimation taking into account the endogeneity of y1i, whereas when ρ < 0 this implies a downward bias of the results of θ1 when the second equation is estimated ignoring the endogenous nature of y1i (Chiburis et al. 2011).

The advantage of using a RBPM in comparison with an IV-probit regression is twofold. Firstly, to identify a good instrumental variable with IV-probit is not easy when using cross-sectional data. Secondly, when using an IV-probit, the first equation (endogenous variable) is estimated not only considering the identified instrument, but also all the exogenous variables included in the second equation. Consequently, we are not able to control which instruments to use in the first equation. In the case of a RBPM, we can select which variables will explain each equation, and for this reason, it represents a better option of model estimation considering the purpose of the study.

In the present study, the dependent variable of the first equation (y1i), the endogenous variable, refers to firm innovation behavior. The dependent variable of the second equation (\( {y}_{2i}^{\ast } \)) refers to the extent to which firms may be financially constrained. Explanatory variables included in the first equation refer to determinants of innovation activities (Scherer 1965; Crépon et al. 1998; Smolny 2003; Savignac 2008), namely firm characteristics (size, age, type of ownership, and international position of sales) and the degree of competition (proxy for market power).

The second equation is based on the model of Aghion et al. (2004), where being a financially constrained firm is explained by innovation behavior and firms’ characteristics. According to the literature, firm characteristics include size, age, type of ownership, activity sector, international position of sales, and firms’ liquidity indicators (decrease of sales and increase of cost and increased own capital). We also add to the model other factors able to explain the dependent variable, such as factors in the financial market limiting future finance for growth, and the importance of factors for future financing. As regards these last groups of explanatory variables, they included factors explaining market conditions in the financial market, namely obstacles and limitations identified by firms, which could influence future financing and explain the financing constraints. These explanatory variables include factors that can be considered as problems on the supply side (such as collateral requirement, price, and bureaucracy) and variables that reflect potential solutions (important factors to obtain future financing) to facilitate access to finance. A positive relationship between these explanatory variables and the dependent variable (to be financially constrained) could indicate that the more important an obstacle for future financing, the more difficult it is for a firm to access external finance. On the other hand, a negative relationship between these explanatory variables and the variable of interest could indicate that policy intervention in this area or for this kind of firm is less relevant. Both equations also included country and industry fixed effects, which allow capturing the demand for external finance. For more details about variables’ definition see Table S1 in Supplement material.

One possible answer to the question “what is the most limiting factor to get future finance to realize growth ambitions” in SAFE is “financing non-available at all.” Due to a potential tautologicalFootnote 9 issue between this variable and the dependent variable of being financially constrained, we excluded all firms that selected this factor, since the answer provided by firms to that question is exclusive, i.e., firms can only identify one limiting factor as an answer to this question.

A main assumption of the present analysis is that future expectations in terms of financial needs can be used to predict whether the current access to finance represents a pressing problem. In order to test this hypothesis, a preliminary analysis based on a univariate probitFootnote 10 confirmed that the firm’s present financial condition can influence future expectations in terms of access to finance, and consequently, we could expect the inverse relationship also to be true.Footnote 11

Furthermore, as a complementary analysis, we reproduced the same exercise by innovation strategy (simple and complex innovationFootnote 12) and typology (product, process, organization or marketing innovation). Lastly, we estimated two univariate probit models for firms that reported beeing financially constrained, one with a sub-sample composed only of innovative firms and a second with only non-innovative ones. The aim is to assess differences as regards firms’ perception of the characteristics of the supply side of the financial market.

All regression estimations are weighted,Footnote 13 in order to control for firms’ characteristics (size, industry sector and country) representativeness in their country and in the EU. We used the weight variable present in the SAFE database, where the weight of each enterprise is adjusted in each size class, economic sector, and country.

5 Results and discussion

5.1 Sample description: financially constrained vs. non-constrained firms

Table S2 in supplement material reports the distribution of the sample by firm characteristics and financial indicators. The sample is composed of micro (32%), small (34%), and medium-sized firms (34%). Around 80% are more than 5 years old. Regarding the distribution by sector, all categories are quite well represented, despite a higher proportion of services to businesses or individuals (38%) and a smaller one for the construction sector (11%). Nearly 54% of firms sold their goods and/or services in foreign markets in the previous year.

About 64% of the respondents have launched at least one type of innovationFootnote 14 in the market or their own organization (such as a new process, work restructuring, or new way of selling) (Table S3 in supplement material). More than half of innovative companies have adopted a complex innovation strategy, introducing two or more innovation types among the four listed. Product innovation is the typology the most frequently introduced by firms in the market (39%), while, marketing innovation is the least one (28%). Concerning differences between innovation behavior by sector, Table S4 in the supplement material reveals that firms operating in industry sector are more innovative as regards to innovation strategy and typology, except for marketing innovation, which is more frequent in firms operating in trade and services sectors. Firms located in North and South of Europe report a higher likelihood to be innovative and a higher propensity to implement a complex innovation than firms in Central Europe.

Financially constrained firms and non-financially constrained ones (Tables S2 and S3 – supplement material) show significant differences in almost all categories. Innovative, smaller, and younger firms are more frequently financially constrained. Nearly 39% of the observed firms have increased their own capital in the last 6 months, and non-financially constrained firms show a higher growth of their own capital in comparison with their counterparts. Around 8% of the sample have experienced in the last 6 months, a simultaneous decrease in turnover and an increase in costs; however, it seems that non-statistical differences between groups exist.

Approximately 44% of the sampled firms reported no obstacles for obtaining future financing to realize their growth ambitions, despite around 23% of them declared to be financially constrained. Insufficient collateral or guarantee (17%) and too high interest rate or price (15%) were the two most commonly obstacles reported by firms. Differences of means between financially constrained and non-constrained firms are observed in all limiting and important factors to get future financing.

5.2 Interpretation of model estimations: financing constraints for growth ambitions

Starting with the estimation of a univariate probit model where innovation behavior is considered an exogenous variable (column 3 in Table S8 - supplement material), we observe that being an innovative firm has a positive and significant effect on the probability of being financially constrained. Nevertheless, when testing for endogeneity of innovation behavior, including those in an equation system composed of two probit models (first equation referring to innovation behavior and the second to the probability of being financially constrained), the results of RBPM estimation (Table 1) show a significant negative correlation between the errors of both equations (ρ = − 0.79). This conclusion means that to obtain consistent estimators, both probit equations need to be estimated jointly, in order to control for endogeneity bias.

Table 1 Results of recursive bivariate probit model

The negative value of ρ also means that the existing bias due to endogeneity lowers the effect of innovation behavior on the firm’s financial statement of being financially constrained. This assumption is confirmed when we compare the results of the coefficients of innovation behavior obtained with the univariate probitFootnote 15 (β = 0.0895) and the recursive bivariate probit (β = 1.351). This difference reveals that unobservable firm characteristics affecting both equations and the selection process play a vital role and need to be considered to reduce potential bias.

The multicollinearity diagnostic (Table S6 in supplement material) performed using a correlation matrix shows that our independent variables are not correlated with each other, leading to precise estimation.

Regarding the suitability of the first equation, column (1) of Table 1 shows that our exclusion restriction (competition pressing problem) is statistically significant and the explanatory variables are the expected signs. Competition, being equity-backed firms and the presence in international markets (exporter) have a positive impact on the likelihood to innovate. Larger and younger firms are also more likely to innovate, in line with scientific literature. As results of eq. 1 are consistent, it could be considered as a good predictor of innovation behavior, which affects the probability of being financially constrained.

The results of the second equation reveal that after controlling for endogeneity and firms’ characteristics, being an innovative firm has a positive and significant effect on being financially constrained and increases the probability of having difficulties in accessing external finance by 32%, everything else being equal. This result is also in line with the conclusions of Lee et al. (2015), who found that being an innovative firm increases the probability of facing strong credit rationing between 20 and 40%.Footnote 16

As expected and in line with Savignac (2008) and Coad et al. (2016), external financing constraints decrease if firms have improved their capital provided by owners or shareholders, and if firms sold their goods and services in the international market. For instance, being an exporter decreases by 3.6%, the probability of being a financially constrained firm.

Nevertheless, no significant evidence was found concerning the effect of different types of ownership, firm age and size,Footnote 17 and the loss of cash flow due to a simultaneous decrease of turnover and an increase of costs on the likelihood of being financially constrained.

Regarding the main factors limiting future financing for firms’ growth ambitions, the results of marginal effects (column 6 in Table 1) illustrate that firms’ insufficient collateral or guarantee (10%), bureaucracy (5.8%), and too high an interest rate or price (5.2%) are the factors with the highest impact on the probability of being financially constrained.Footnote 18

Concerning the degree of importance of factors for firms’ financing in the future, marginal effects of RBPM show that guarantees for loans (1.1%), making existing public measures easier to obtain (0.064%) and measures to facilitate equity investment (0.6%) have the highest impact on the probability of being financially constrained. Business support services for firms do not appear to be a significant factor explaining the dependent variable. Tax incentives are among the factors with the lowest significant positive effect, despite this factor being the one with the highest score reported by surveyed firms. This may reveal that although important, this instrument is not the most relevant to solve the problem of financing constraints.

A cross-country analysis (Fig. 2) shows that in EU28 the average probability of being financially constrained for firms with growth ambitions is 5.6%. Firms located in Cyprus (20.7%), Greece (18.5%), and Romania (12.5%) are much more constrained than the EU average, whereas those in Luxembourg (1.9%), Slovakia (2.5%), and Estonia (3.1%) are less constrained.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Average probability of innovative firm to be financially constrained, by country. Authors’ own elaboration based on SAFE database. Results refer to descriptive statistics (weighted mean) by country of the estimated probability of being financially constraints and to be an innovative firm. Figure S2 in supplement material shows the geographical distribution of the sample.

5.3 Complementary analysis: assessing differences regarding innovation strategy

As a complementary analysis, we performed the same exercise by innovation strategy and typology. The results of the RBPM are reported in Table S9 in the supplement material. Table 2 displays the marginal effect of innovation behavior, showing that both innovation strategy (simple and complex) and all the four typologies have a positive and significant effect on being financially constrained. Their marginal effect range between 20.7 and 28.7%. The results of the Z-test to assess differences between coefficients reveal that firms introducing a complex innovation are more financially constrained than that gambling for a simple innovation strategy. Regarding differences between the innovation typologies no statistical differences were found.

Table 2 Marginal effect of innovation strategy and typology: effect of innovation behavior on being financially constrained (results of RBPM)

Lastly, to assess differences between innovative and non-innovative firms concerning the determinants of financing constraints, we also estimated a univariate probit regression for being financially constrained for each group. The marginal effects of the main explanatory variables under analysis are displayed in Table 3.

Table 3 Marginal effects of probit model: being financially constrained, by innovation behavior

Regarding the main factors limiting future financing for firms’ growth ambitions, for both innovative and non-innovative ones, firms’ insufficient collateral or guarantee is the factor with the highest impact on the probability of being financially constrained, compared to a situation with no obstacles. Excluding the category of other factors not listed, all the factors do not affect differently both groups.

Concerning the importance of different factors in obtaining future financing, for both groups guarantees for loans, making existing public measures easier to obtain and measures to facilitate equity investments are the most relevant factors. Furthermore, for innovative firms the first two (guarantees for loans and public support) report even a higher effect in comparison with non-innovative ones, once their coefficients are statistically different.

For both groups, the importance of tax incentives displays the smallest effect in comparison with the other significant variable in this category. These findings suggest that on the one hand, firms for which tax incentives are a relevant factor in future financing are less financially constrained, perhaps because this policy measure implies financial compensation for an investment, or an expenditure already made. Hence, firms have a priori financial resources to do so. On the other hand, considering that financing constraints are essentially linked with liquidity problems, the lesser importance of tax incentives could be due to the inappropriate use of this instrument in all stages of the firm’s life and product cycle. Indeed, tax incentives for R&D provide financial support at the starting point of the innovation process, but do not help firms in the next steps, to place innovation in the market.Footnote 19 To obtain financial resources for cash flow, firms can usually resort to a credit line or bank overdraft. However, a recent study (Cincera and Santos 2018) showed that innovative firms, due to their riskier activities, have to pay a higher interest rate and are more likely to see the collateral requirement increased than non-innovative firms. These conclusions are in line with the findings of the present study, where guarantees for loans are one of the main causes of firms’ problems in accessing finance.

6 Conclusion and policy recommendations

The present study presents a direct assessment of financing constraints through the anonymous survey of SMEs in the euro area (SAFE) as regards access to finance. Using a recursive bivariate probit model, the paper contributes to the literature, firstly by identifying which factors on the supply side of the financial market have the most impact on hindering firms’ access to finance and secondly assessing how far innovative behavior can induce financing constraints.

The results show that some firms are more constrained and have more difficulties in accessing external finance. Both internal and external factors affect firms’ access to financing.

Innovative firms are more constrained and are between 21 and 32% more likely to be financially constrained than their non-innovative counterparts.

Concerning characteristics of the supply side of the financial market, insufficient collateral, too much paperwork is involved and too high-interest rate appear to be the most important factors limiting access to future finance. Besides, guarantees for loans, easier access to equity financing, and to direct public support are revealed to be the best solutions to alleviate firms’ financing constraints. In fact, the last two instruments are alternatives to traditional bank debt, usually risk adverse and with a high collateral requirement. On the other hand, tax incentives (indirect public support) seem to be the least relevant factor in alleviating firms’ financing constraints. A possible explanation for this finding could be that this policy measure implies a financial compensation for an investment or expenditure already made, so firms have a priori financial resources to do so. To obtain financial resources for cash flow, firms can usually resort to a credit line, but this short-term debt is also associated with the need for guarantees, so an alternative solution to finance cash flow with no collateral is to ask an equity investor for support.

All these conclusions open up new suggestions for policymakers. As a complement to direct or indirect support for R&D and innovation (more focused on investment in fixed assets), innovative companies also need financial support for daily activities. Launching a new product on the market has not only new production costs but also implies higher working capital needs, in order to pay suppliers and workers while the company finds new customers or markets and generates liquidity. Making venture capital operations easier, providing access to credit lines or secured loans could be complements to direct and indirect support to reduce the financing pressure on innovative firms in Europe.