Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Gibrat’s law and the learning process

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper discusses the speed of convergence of small firms in the context of Gibrat’s law for manufacturing and service industries. We analyze unbalanced panel data from 139,922 firms belonging to the Spanish manufacturing and service industries between 1994 and 2002. The results show that small firms grow faster than large firms. The evidence supports the proposition that market structure affects the capacity of firms to grow. In particular, small firms in service industries do not grow as quickly as small firms in manufacturing industries. This is mainly due to the lower medium efficient size (MES) in the service industries diminishing the incentives to grow and the positive effect of MES on the speed of convergence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Between 1994 and 2002, the number of SMEs (firms with more than 1 employee and fewer than 20 employees) increased by 4% in the manufacturing industries and by 23% in the service industries (Source: Directorio Central de Empresas).

  2. Source: Encuesta Anual de Servicios and Encuesta Industrial (Spanish Statistics Institute).

  3. Spanish empirical evidence shows that firms in the service sector are more likely to fail: 58.86% of service firms created in 1994 had failed by the end of 2005. This may be related to the lower sunk costs and more short-term strategies for facing unemployment situations in the service sector.

  4. These authors applied a chi-square test and the equation of the persistence of firm growth. With the chi-square test, Gibrat’s law was accepted for firms operating above the MES. With the equation of persistence of firm growth, Gibrat’s law was accepted in 11 out of 15 cases. However, their results varied according to year and business group.

  5. Oliveira and Fortunato (2004a, b) used unbalanced panel data with 8,072 firms, but with only 419 firms from the service sectors.

  6. As the dependent variable they used current size and as the independent variable they used previous size. In this case, their coefficient was <1.

  7. NACE (from the French abbreviation for nomenclature statistique des activités économiques dans la Communauté Européenne) is a general industrial classification of economic activities within the European Union. This classification is officially recognized by the Accounting Economic System (National Institute of Statistics).

  8. We excluded sectors 16 (industries related to tobacco products) and 23 (industries related to coke, refined petroleum products, and nuclear fuel) because there are few firms in these traditional monopolistic industries.

  9. The original database had 162,208 firms: 80% of the firms survived until 2002. The percentages of firms surviving until 2002 were 68% of those born in 1994, 69% of those born in 1995, 70% of those born in 1996, 74% of those born in 1997, 77% of those born in 1998, 82% of those born in 1999, and 91% of those born in 2000. This evidence is in concordance with previous empirical literature (Segarra et al. 2002; Segarra and Teruel 2007).

  10. Calculations are available upon request.

  11. The income per worker includes the sales per worker plus other incomes obtained by the firm.

  12. Evans (1987a, b), Hall (1987) and Dunne et al. (1989) differentiated between a latent firm growth equation and a real firm growth equation. The former includes surviving and nonsurviving firms and would raise a sample selection bias arising from exit. The latter estimates the growth of surviving firms.

  13. The Hausman test does not accept the null hypothesis about the absence of correlation between individual effects and explanatory variables. Furthermore, the Breusch and Pagan (B and P) test does not accept the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity in the error distribution, conditional on a set of variables which are presumed to influence the error variance.

  14. Calculations are available upon request.

  15. The F and chi-squared test are the values reported by the fixed effects and random effects estimations. They test whether the model is significant or not. The tests do not accept the null hypothesis about the nonsignificance of the model.

  16. For example, in 2006 the capital per worker intensity in the manufacturing industries was equal to 15.113 euros and in the service industries was equal to 9.376 euros (Spanish Statistical Institute).

  17. The estimations of the effect of the effect of capital per worker intensity and the microfirms on individual sectors are available upon request.

References

  • Acs, Z. J. (1996). Small firms and economic growth. In P. H. Admiraal (Ed.), Small business in the modern economy (pp. 1–62). Oxford, UK: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1990). Innovation and small firms. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1990). La econometría de datos de panel. Investigaciones Económicas, 14, 3–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (1995). Innovation and industry evolution. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (2002). The dynamic role of small firms: Evidence from the U.S. Small Business Economics, 18, 13–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Thurik, A. R. (2000). Capitalism and democracy in the 21st century: From the managed to the entrepreneurial economy. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Lehman, E. E. (2005). Mansfield’s missing link: The impact of knowledge spillovers on firm growth. Journal of Technology Transfer, 30, 207–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Mahmood, T. (1994). Firm selection and industry evolution: The post-entry performance of new firms. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 4, 243–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Carree, M. A., van Stel, A. J., & Thurik, A. R. (2002). Impeded industrial restructuring: The growth penalty. Kyklos, 55, 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Klomp, L., & Thurik, R. (1999). Do services differ from manufacturing? In D. B. Audretsch & R. Thurik (Eds.), Innovation, industry evolution and employment (pp. 230–252). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Klomp, L., Santarelli, E., & Thurik, A. R. (2004). Gibrat’s Law: Are the services different? Review of Industrial Organization, 24, 301–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. H. (1995). Econometrics of panel data. West Sussex: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L. (1995). Sunk costs, firm size and firm growth. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 43, 161–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, J. L. (2006). Testing Gibrat’s Law for small, young and innovating firms. Small Business Economics, 26, 117–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carree, M. A., van Stel, A. J., Thurik, A. R., & Wennekers, A. R. M. (2002). Economic development and business ownership: An analysis using data of 23 OECD countries in the period 1976–1996. Small Business Economics, 19, 271–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Correa, A., Acosta, M., González, A. L., & Medina, U. (2003). Size, age and activity sector on the growth of small and medium firm size. Small Business Economics, 21, 289–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuadrado-Roura, J. R., & Garcia-Tabuenca, A. (2004). ICT policies for SMEs and regional disparities. The Spanish case. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 16, 55–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das, S. (1995). Size, age and firm growth in an infant industry: The computer hardware industry in India. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 111–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, P., & Hughes, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 42, 115–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, T., Roberts, M. J., & Samuelson, L. (1989). The growth and failure of U.S. manufacturing plants. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 671–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ericson, R., & Pakes, A. (1995). Markov-perfect industry dynamics: A framework for empirical work. Review of Economic Studies, 62, 53–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S. (1987a). The relationship between firm growth, size, and age: Estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 567–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S. (1987b). Tests of alternative theories of firm growth. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 657–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fariñas, J. C., & Moreno, L. (2000). Firm’s growth, size and age: A nonparametric approach. Review of Industrial Organization, 17, 249–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fotopoulos, G., & Louri, H. (2004). Firm growth and FDI: Are multinationals stimulating local industrial development? Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 4, 163–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A. (1995). What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 421–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat, R. (1931). Les Inégalités Économiqués; Applications: Aux Inégalités des Richesses, a la Concentration des Entreprises, Aux Populations des Villes, Aux Statistiques des Familles, etc., d’une Loi Nouvelles, La Loi de l’Effet Proportionnel. (Paris).

  • Hall, B. H. (1987). The relationship between firm size and firm growth in the U.S. manufacturing sector. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 583–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, E., & Prais, S. J. (1956). The analysis of business concentration. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 119, 150–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, P. E., & Oulton, N. (1996). Growth and size of firms. The Economic Journal, 106, 1242–1252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251–1271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hyytinen, A., & Toivanen, O. (2005). Do financial constraints hold back innovation and growth? Evidence on the role of public policy. Research Policy, 34, 1385–1403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50, 649–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, M. S. (1985). Growth, acqusition activity and firm size: Evidence from the United Kingdom. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 33, 327–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lotti, F., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2001). The relationship between size and growth: The case of Italian newborn firms. Applied Economics Letters, 8, 451–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat’s Law, innovation, and the growth of firms. The American Economic Review, 52, 1023–1051.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, M., & Segarra, A. (2004). Dinámica Empresarial en las Industrias Maduras Españolas. Economía Industrial, 355–356, 97–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mata, J., & Portugal, P. (2004). Patters of entry, post-entry growth and survival. Small Business Economics, 22, 283–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2004a). Determinants of firm growth: A comparative study between a panel of Portuguese manufacturing and services firms. Paper presented at the 31st Conference of the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics, Berlin.

  • Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2004b). The dynamics of the growth of firms: Are the services different? Paper presented at the Economic Policies in the New Millennium Conference, Coimbra.

  • Pakes, A., & Ericson, R. (1998). Empirical implications of alternative models of firm dynamics. Journal of Economic Theory, 79, 1–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peña, I. (2004). Business incubation center and new firm growth in the Basque Country. Small Business Economics, 22, 223–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2002). Is subsidizing entry an optimal policy? Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 39–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segarra, A., Arauzo, J. M., Gras, N., Manjón, M., Mañé, F., Teruel, M., et al. (2002). La creación y la supervivencia de las empresas industriales. Civitas: Madrid.

    Google Scholar 

  • Segarra, A., & Teruel, M. (2007). Creación y Supervivencia de las Nuevas Empresas en las Manufacturas y los Servicios. Economía Industrial, 363, 47–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, D. S., Wessner, C., Binks, M., & Lockett, A. (2003). Policies promoting innovation in small firms: Evidence from the U.S. and U.K. Small Business Economics, 20, 121–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A., & Bonini, C. P. (1958). The size distribution of business firms. American Economic Review, 48, 607–617.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Whittington, G. (1975). The size and growth of firms. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 15–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snijders, J., & van der Horst, R. (2002). SMEs in focus main results from the 2002 observatory of European SMEs. Belgium: European Communities.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J., & Tether, B. S. (1998). Public policy measures to support new technology-based firms in the European Union. Research Policy, 26, 1037–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutton, J. (1997). Gibrat’s legacy. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 40–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1993). The dynamics of industrial capitalism: perspectives on Alfred Chandler’s scale and scope. Journal of Economic Literature, 31, 199–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voulgaris, F., Asteriou, D., & Agiomirgianakes, D. (2003). The determinants of small firm growth in the Greek manufacturing sector. Journal of Economic Integration, 18, 817–836.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiklund, J., & Shepherd, D. (2003). Aspiring for, and achieving growth: The moderating role of resources and opportunities. Journal of Management Studies, 40, 1919–1941.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research was partially funded by the Xarxa de Referència d’R+D+I en Economia Aplicada and CICYT (SEJ2004-07824/ECON) entitled “La dinámica empresarial: entornos urbanos, mercado de trabajo y modelización econométrica”. I also would like to acknowledge helpful and supportive comments from Agustí Segarra, seminar participants at X Encuentro de Economía Aplicada (Logroño, Spain), and two anonymous referees for useful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mercedes Teruel-Carrizosa.

Appendix

Appendix

Annex 1
figure a

Kernel densities depending on the age

Annex 2 Descriptive statistics and test of mean of the lagged firm size for manufacturing and service industries

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Teruel-Carrizosa, M. Gibrat’s law and the learning process. Small Bus Econ 34, 355–373 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-008-9127-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-008-9127-9

JEL Classifications

Keywords

Navigation