Skip to main content
Log in

The effect of stochastic interest rates on a firm’s capital structure under a generalized model

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The lattice approach derived by Broadie and Kaya (J Financ Quant Anal 42(2):279–312, 2007) has traditionally been used to determine the capital structure of a firm in economies with constant interest rates; however, this study argues that the capital structure of a firm should be determined by considering the state of its debt simultaneously with the randomness of interest rates. This study extends the Hilliard et al. (J Financ Res 19(4):585–602, 1996) bivariate binomial model to determine the capital structure of firms, taking into account stochastic interest rates and their correlation with the asset value of the firm. Our simulation results suggest that taking stochastic interest rates into consideration reduces the equity value of a firm while increasing its debt value. The stronger the correlation between variations in the asset value of the firm and the short rate, the stronger the impact of this correlation on the capital structure of the firm.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For further extensions of the model see Leland and Toft (1996), Titman and Tsyplakov (2007) and Hennessy and Whited (2005).

  2. Ju and Hui (2006) use the Vasicek (1977) term structure model to describe the dynamic process of stochastic interest rate when they investigate the effects of stochastic interest rate on determining a firm’s capital structure. Furthermore, their model is constructed under the European style option framework which would be one of our special cases.

  3. β = 0 indicates the Vasicek (1977) Model, and β = 0.5 indicates the Cox et al. (1985) model.

  4. The detailed processes are described in “Appendix 1”.

  5. The detailed processes involved in computing the probability are described in “Appendix 2”.

  6. The processes are detailed in “Appendix 3”.

  7. These parameters are in accordance with those of Broadie and Kaya (2007) and Hilliard et al. (1996).

  8. The criteria used here differ slightly from the criteria used by the original authors, since there are some errors in the Broadie and Kaya paper. The corrected structure is presented in “Appendix 4”.

  9. Initial interest rates in the proposed model are treated in the same way as the constant interest rate in the Broadie and Kaya (2007) model.

  10. Equity s is calculated in the case of stochastic interest rates, and Equity c is calculated in the case of constant interest rates.

References

  • Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Polit Econ 81(3):637–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle PP (1988) A lattice framework for option pricing with two state variables. J Financ Quant Anal 23(1):1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan MJ, Schwartz ES (1978) Corporate income taxes, valuation and the problem of optimal capital structure. J Bus 51(1):103–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadie M, Kaya O (2007) A binomial lattice method for pricing corporate debt and Modeling chapter 11 proceedings. J Financ Quant Anal 42(2):279–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadie M, Chernov M, Sundaresan S (2007) Optimal debt and equity values in the presence of chapter 7 and chapter 11. J Financ 62(3):1341–1377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courtois OL, Nakagawa H (2013) On surrender and default risks. Math Finance 23(1):143–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Ross SA, Rubinstein M (1979) Option pricing: a simplified approach. J Financ Econ 7(3):229–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Ingersoll JE, Ross SA (1985) A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica 53(2):385–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dew-Becker I (2011) Investment and the cost of capital in the cross-section: the term spread predicts the duration of investment. Working paper, Harvard University

  • Goldstein R, Ju N, Leland H (2001) An EBIT-based model of dynamic capital structure. J Bus 74(4):483–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta MC, Lee AC (2006) An integrated model of debt issuance, refunding, and maturity. Rev Quant Finance Account 26(2):177–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy CA, Whited TM (2005) Debt dynamics. J Financ 60(3):1129–1165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilliard JE, Schwartz AL, Tucker AA (1996) Bivariate binomial options pricing with generalized interest rate processes. J Financ Res 19(4):585–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ju N, Hui OY (2006) Capital structure, debt maturity and stochastic interest rates. J Bus 79(5):2469–2502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland HE (1994) Corporate debt value, bond covenants and optimal capital structure. J Financ 49(4):1213–1252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland HE, Toft KB (1996) Optimal capital structure, endogenous bankruptcy and the term structure of credit spreads. J Financ 51(3):987–1019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lesseig V, Stock D (1998) The effect of interest rates on the value of corporate assets and the risk premia of corporate debt. Rev Quant Financ Account 11(1):5–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1973) On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. J Financ 29(2):449–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson DB, Ramaswamy K (1990) Simple binomial processes as diffusion approximation in financial models. Rev Financ Stud 3(3):393–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Titman S, Tsyplakov S (2007) A dynamic model of optimal capital structure. Rev Financ 11(3):401–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasicek O (1977) An equilibrium characterization of the term structure. J Financ Econ 5(2):177–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vassalou M, Xing Y (2004) Default risk in equity returns. J Financ 59(2):831–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang C, Wang N, Yang J (2013) Investment, tobin’s Q and interest rates. Working paper

  • Wong H, Choi TW (2009) Estimating default barriers from market information. Quant Financ 9(2):187–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jun-Biao Lin.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The transformed processes

Our once-transformed processes, Eqs. (3) and (5), are subsequently combined as follows:

$$X_{1} = \sigma_{r} \phi + R$$
(21)
$$X_{ 2} = \sigma_{r} \phi - R$$
(22)

The stochastic processes of the two variables in Eqs. (3) and (5) are therefore:

$$dX_{1} = \sigma_{r} d\phi + dR$$
(23)
$$dX_{2} = \sigma_{r} d\phi - dR$$
(24)

Here, the two variables are mutually orthogonal, a relationship which achieves the final purpose of:

$${\text{cov}}\left( {dX_{1} ,dX_{2} } \right) = cov\left( {\sigma_{r}^{2} - \sigma_{r}^{2} + \sigma_{r}^{2} \rho_{vr} - \sigma_{r}^{2} \rho_{vr} } \right) = 0$$

where ρ vr is the instantaneous correlation between dZ v and dZ r . Hence Eqs. (23) and (24) provide the uncorrelated and constant volatility processes as:

$$\begin{aligned} dX_{1} & = \sigma_{r} \left( {mdt + dZ_{v} } \right) + \left( {a^{*} dt + \sigma_{r} dZ_{r} } \right) \\ & = \left( {\sigma_{r} m + a^{*} } \right)dt + \sigma_{r} \left( {dZ_{v} + dZ_{r} } \right) \\ & = \left( {\sigma_{r} m + a^{*} } \right)dt + \sigma_{r} \sqrt {2\left( {1 + \rho_{vr} } \right)} dZ_{1} \\ & \equiv m_{1} dt + \sigma_{1} dZ_{1} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} dX_{2} & = \sigma_{r} \left( {mdt + dZ_{v} } \right) - \left( {a^{*} dt + \sigma_{r} dZ_{r} } \right) \\ & = \left( {\sigma_{r} m - a^{*} } \right)dt + \sigma_{r} \left( {dZ_{v} - dZ_{r} } \right) \\ & = \left( {\sigma_{r} m - a^{*} } \right)dt + \sigma_{r} \sqrt {2\left( {1 - \rho_{vr} } \right)} dZ_{2} \\ & \equiv m_{2} dt + \sigma_{2} dZ_{2} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Equations (25) and (26) also satisfy the following property:

$${\text{d}}Z_{1} \bot {\text{d}}Z_{2}$$

Therefore, as a result of the above equations, we are able to establish a lattice using the two new independent variables, (X 1, X 2), which are derived from the two original dependent variables, (V, r).

Appendix 2: Verifying the probability of the lattice

Fundamental probability theory creates a problem for the method of changing the variables in Hilliard et al. (1996); that is, the probability could be >1 (or <0) in those cases where the drift and volatility terms have extreme values. The definition of probability in the Cox et al. (1979) model, with Brownian motion, is:

$$p_{*} = \frac{1}{2} + \frac{{m_{*} \sqrt {\varDelta t} }}{{2\sigma_{*} }}$$
(27)

Obviously, when the drift term is greater than the volatility term, the upward probability in the Cox et al. (1979) model violates fundamental probability theory; therefore, prior to establishing the lattice, we need to make some adjustments for the magnitude of the upward probability under the following criteria:

$$p\left( {2k + 1} \right)\sigma \sqrt {\varDelta t} + \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {2k - 1} \right)\sigma \sqrt {\varDelta t} = \mu \varDelta t$$
(28)

where, \(k = 0,\, \pm 1,\, \pm 2,\, \pm 3 \ldots\).

Since the variable m, is the same as the drift term of a particular process, we fix the upward and downward difference of \(2\sigma \sqrt {\varDelta t}\) in order to satisfy the expectation of a stochastic process. We must then check parameter, k, and select appropriate values. Therefore, the upward probability should be modified as follows:

$$p_{*} = \frac{1}{2} - k_{*} + \frac{{m_{*} \sqrt {\varDelta t} }}{{2\sigma_{*} }}$$
(29)

Appendix 3: The changing of the dynamic processes in our model

Following the previous section, we first need to change the dynamic processes for V and r into new processes with the property of constant volatility. This can be achieved by:

$$dX_{1} = m_{1} dt + \sigma_{1} dZ_{1}$$
(30)
$$dX_{2} = m_{2} dt + \sigma_{2} dZ_{2}$$
(31)

where

$$m_{1} = \frac{{\sigma_{r} }}{{\sigma_{v} }}\left( {r_{t} - q - \frac{1}{2}\sigma_{v}^{2} } \right) + a^{*}$$
(32)
$$m_{1} = \frac{{\sigma_{r} }}{{\sigma_{v} }}\left( {r_{t} - q - \frac{1}{2}\sigma_{v}^{2} } \right) - a^{*}$$
(33)

and

$$\sigma_{1} = \sigma_{r} \sqrt {2\left( {1 + \rho_{vr} } \right)}$$
(34)
$$\sigma_{2} = \sigma_{r} \sqrt {2\left( {1 - \rho_{vr} } \right)}$$
(35)

where a * = r β (κ (θ − r ) t  – λ σ r ) − (σ 2 r  β/2)r β–1.

We denote the upward probability in X 1 (X 2) as P 1 (P 2), with the subsequent probabilities for the next four states in our lattice approach being as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} & p_{1} p_{2} = Pr\left( {X_{1} + \sigma_{1} \sqrt {\varDelta t} ,X_{2} + \sigma_{2} \sqrt {\varDelta t} } \right) \\ & \left( {1 - p_{1} } \right)p_{2} = Pr\left( {X_{1} - \sigma_{1} \sqrt {\varDelta t} ,X_{2} + \sigma_{2} \sqrt {\varDelta t} } \right) \\ & p_{1} \left( {1 - p_{2} } \right) = Pr\left( {X_{1} + \sigma_{1} \sqrt {\varDelta t} ,X_{2} - \sigma_{2} \sqrt {\varDelta t} } \right) \\ & \left( {1 - p_{1} } \right)\left( {1 - p_{2} } \right) = Pr\left( {X_{1} - \sigma_{1} \sqrt {\varDelta t} ,X_{2} - \sigma_{2} \sqrt {\varDelta t} } \right) \\ \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Appendix 4: Some errors in Broadie and Kaya (2007)

Following on from Broadie and Kaya (2007), the payouts to a firm’s shareholders and bond holders can be expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} If\, V_{T} & \ge \frac{C}{r} , then \\ E & = V_{T} - \frac{C}{r} \\ D & = \frac{C}{r} \\ F & = V_{T} \\ If\, V_{T} & < \left( {1 - \tau } \right)C\varDelta t + \frac{C}{r} , then \\ E & = 0 \\ D & = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)V_{T} \\ F & = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)V_{T} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(37)

However, their equations provide no detailed explanation of the process of inference even where there is no convergence. According to the explanation provided by the authors, the criteria in the terminal nodes have less effects than those in the non-terminal nodes. Our study, which applies the algorithm in Eq. (37), provides a new result on the criteria for approximating the infinite case, as shown in Eq. (19). The basic meaning of our new criteria is that an infinite maturity debt could be terminated by immediately repaying the residual value at the specified date, with the assumption being that the specified date expires along with the time periods. Thus, the criteria in our computation are (1) the principal is the residual value of the perpetual bond, \(\left( \frac{c}{r} \right)\); and (2) the cash flow, (δ T ) also has to be calculated.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chang, CC., Lin, JB. & Yang, CC. The effect of stochastic interest rates on a firm’s capital structure under a generalized model. Rev Quant Finan Acc 45, 695–719 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-014-0452-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-014-0452-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation