Skip to main content
Log in

Is higher variance necessarily bad for investment?

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider decision-making under risk in which random events affect the value of the portfolio multiplicatively, rather than additively. In this case, a higher variability in the rate of return not only is associated with a higher risk, a bad property, but also engenders a higher expected return, a good property. As a result, certain expected utility maximizing investors, namely those with the lowest risk aversion, will prefer some portfolios with higher variances in the rate of return over others with lower ones. This is demonstrated, and implications are considered.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Here we measure variability by means of σ2, the variance of logarithms. The variance and Gini coefficient for the terminal wealth distribution are monotonic functions of σ2.

  2. Note that CARA implies increasing relative risk aversion (IRRA).

  3. Note that \( \lim_{a \to 0} {{U^{a} (x)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{U^{a} (x)} a}} \right. \kern-0pt} a} = x + U_{0} (x) \): the risk neutral utility function \( U(x) = x \) is in essence common to both families.

  4. The value of the limiting CARA parameter a 0 is immaterial for drawing this conclusion. However, if we set \( y = 1 - U^{a} (w) = \exp \left\{ { - aw} \right\} \), so that \( \ell n\left[ { - \ell n\left[ y \right]} \right] = \ell n\left[ a \right] + \ell n\left[ w \right] \sim \) \( N\left( {\mu + \ell n\left[ a \right],\sigma^{2} } \right) \), we see that y follows the ‘double lognormal distribution,’ introduced by Meinhold and Singpurwalla (1987), whose mean can be approximated as \( E\left[ y \right] = 1 - E\left[ {U^{a} (w)} \right] \simeq\) \( \left( {1 - \sigma^{2} \exp \left\{ {\mu + \ell n\left[ a \right]} \right\}} \right)^{{ - \sigma^{ - 2} }} \) given our parameter values, so long as \( \sigma^{2} < {1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 {\exp \left\{ {\mu + \ell n\left[ a \right]} \right\}}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\exp \left\{ {\mu + \ell n\left[ a \right]} \right\}}} \) (ibid., page 106); and some manipulation then shows that a necessary condition for \( \frac{\partial }{\partial \nu }E\left[ {U^{a} (w)} \right] > 0 \), so that a higher variability is preferred, is that \( a < \exp \left\{ { - 1 - \mu } \right\} \), i.e. \( a_{0} \le \exp \left\{ { - 1 - \mu } \right\}. \)

  5. See also the comment by Hawawini and Vora (1981) and the response of Levhari and Levy (1981).

  6. The groups comprise values below and above the given quantile.

References

  • Aitchison J, Brown JAC (1957) The lognormal distribution: with special reference to its uses in economics. University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1970) Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Brockett PL, Kahane Y (1992) Risk, return, skewness and preference. Manag Sci 38(6):851–866

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hawawini GA, Vora A (1981) The capital asset pricing model and the investment horizon: comment. Rev Econ Stat 63(4):633–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang AY (2013) Value at risk estimation by quantile regression and kernel estimator. Rev Quant Finan Acc 41(2):225–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson NL, Kotz S (1970) Continuous univariate distributions-1. Houghton Mifflin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Levy H (1977) The capital asset pricing model and the investment horizon. Rev Econ Stat 59(1):92–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Levy H (1981) The capital asset pricing model and the investment horizon: reply. Rev Econ Stat 63(4):637–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy H (1973) Stochastic dominance among log-normal prospects. Int Econ Rev 14:601–614

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy H, Schwarz G (1997) Correlation and the time interval over which the variables are measured. J Econom 76:341–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy H, Guttman I, Tkatch I (2001) Regression, correlation and the time interval: additive-multiplicative framework. Manag Sci 47(8):1150–1159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meinhold RJ, Singpurwalla ND (1987) A Kalman-filter smoothing approach for extrapolations in certain dose-response, damage assessment, and accelerated-life-testing studies. Am Stat 41:101–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Shalit S, Yitzhaki S (2010) How does beta explain stochastic dominance efficiency? Rev Quant Finan Acc 35:431–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki S (1987) On the relation between return and income. Q J Econ 102(1):77–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki S (2003) Gini’s mean difference: a superior measure of variability for non-normal distributions. Metron 41:285–316

    Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki S, Lambert PJ (2013) The relationship between the absolute deviation from a quantile and Gini’s mean difference. Metron, forthcoming

Download references

Acknowledgments

We wish to thank Haim Levy and Jack Meyer for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper, and a perceptive referee whose systematic and astute comments have helped us to improve the presentation of our ideas.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter J. Lambert.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Yitzhaki, S., Lambert, P.J. Is higher variance necessarily bad for investment?. Rev Quant Finan Acc 43, 855–860 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0395-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0395-3

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation