Skip to main content
Log in

Abstract

This paper is on the new (2023) Merger Guidelines. It makes several arguments: First, that the Guidelines should be understood as existing in a political equilibrium. Second, that the new structural presumption of the Merger Guidelines–HHI = 1,800—is too strict, and that an economically reasonable revision in the structural presumption would have increased rather than decreased the threshold. Whereas the new Guidelines lowers the threshold to HHI 1,800 from HHI 2,500, an economically reasonable revision would have increased the threshold to HHI 3,200. I justify this argument using a bare-bones model of Cournot competition. Third, it seems unlikely, as an empirical matter, that merger enforcement under the existing Guidelines is socially desirable. Fourth, that federal merger enforcement raises serious constitutional issues–which were originally discussed in 1904—and that it may be time now, in view of the new Guidelines, to return to these foundational constitutional questions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914. Section 7 is codified at 15 U.S.C. § 18.

  2. Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976. Codified at 15 U.S.C. § 18a.

  3. Oliver E. Williamson The Merger Guidelines of the U.S. Department of Justice–In Perspective, available at https://www.justice.gov/archives/atr/merger-guidelines-us-department-justice-perspective.

  4. https://www.justice.gov/archives/atr/1982-merger-guidelines.

  5. I refer to the dissents of Justices Oliver Wendell Holmes and Edward Douglass White. See Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.S. 197 (1904).

  6. U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Merger Guidelines (2023), available at: https://www.justice.gov/atr/2023-merger-guidelines.

  7. I am setting to the side the question whether the market is measured accurately, or indeed whether it is possible to define accurately a market for purposes of calculating HHIs. See Kaplow (2021).

  8. Merger Guidelines (2023), at 4 (“Similarly, the factors contemplated in these Merger Guidelines neither dictate nor exhaust the range of theories or evidence that the Agencies may introduce in merger litigation.”). Also, the end of Guideline 2 of the 2023 Guidelines – which describes the ways that mergers can violate the law by eliminating competition – notes that the analyses that are covered within the Guideline are merely common scenarios and that “a wide range of evidence can show that a merger may lessen competition.” Merger Guidelines (2023), at 29.

  9. Justin Hurwitz, Premerger Notification Proposal Faces a Rocky Path, The Regulatory Review (Aug 28, 2023), https://www.theregreview.org/2023/08/28/hurwitz-premerger-notification-proposal-faces-a-rocky-path/.

  10. Id.

  11. Oliver Williamson, supra note 3 (“One of the consequences of issuing Guidelines is that firms considering merger would face less antitrust enforcement uncertainty. Inasmuch, however, as such uncertainty served mainly to deter mergers, many of the career staff viewed uncertainty as an ‘advantage.’ Of greater concern is that the issuance of Guidelines would serve to introduce a floor, below which the burden of bringing a case would have to be borne by the Division. The previous practice of progressively ratcheting down admissible market shares would be brought to a halt. That the 1968 Guidelines were stringent can thus be thought of as a compromise. To propose more permissive market shares would, in effect, concede error–by the antitrust enforcement agencies and the courts–in earlier cases.”).

  12. One question this argument generates is why merger enforcement occurred for 54 years – 1914 to 1968 – before the first Guidelines appeared? Why didn’t large firms lobby to curtail agency discretion during the period before 1968? Probably the most important reason is that for most of this 54 year period, Clayton Act Section 7 was easily avoided because of statutory loopholes. See Hylton (2003), at 318.

  13. The question of notice under the antitrust laws was first raised in Nash v. United States, 229 U.S. 373 (1913).

  14. See FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1088–90 (D.D.C 1997).

  15. United States v. Bertelsmann SE & Co. KGaA, 646 F. Supp. 3d 1 (D.D.C. 2022).

  16. Guideline 3.3, Procompetitive Efficiencies, requires the merging parties to show verifiability.

  17. One could easily modify this framework by introducing a general weighting scheme where λ = N/(N + K). In this general weighting scheme, the contributions of consumer welfare and producer welfare can be weighted differently in measuring the total welfare impact. On the basis for such a weighting scheme, see Hylton (2010).

  18. DePrano and Nugent (1969); Williamson (1968); Hylton (2003, pp. 330–32).

  19. Bureau of Economic Analysis. Gross Domestic Product, Fourth Quarter and Year 2022 (Third Estimate), GDP by Industry, and Corporate Profits. Available at: https://www.bea.gov/sites/default/files/2023-03/gdp4q22_3rd_0.pdf.

  20. FTC v. Staples, 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1089 (1997).

  21. https://www.statista.com/statistics/222122/us-corporate-profits-by-industry/.

  22. Id (after subtracting industries such as banking, telecommunications, and utilities that are not subject to exclusive merger enforcement by the DOJ and FTC).

  23. One might object that there are income distribution effects that should be considered, even in the case where consumers stand on both sides of the transaction – that is, as purchasers of the product and as owners of the product seller. Suppose the firms in the industry in which the merger occurs are effectively owned by the retirement funds of public school teachers. Under this assumption, there is no reason to believe, in the absence of concrete evidence, that the income distribution effects of the merger would be undesirable. Suppose, further, that the products produced by firms in the industry are luxuries, such as yachts (Hylton, 2010). With this added assumption, the wealth transfer effect on the distribution of income would appear to be desirable.

  24. Admittedly, the actual cases that the FTC and DOJ have litigated over the last two decades have typically involved HHI levels far in excess of the structural triggers (Rose and Shapiro, 2022). However, with respect to proposed mergers’ falling below the structural triggers there is also the deterrent threat of enforcement: the mergers that are deterred by actual enforcement; the mergers that are deterred by investigation and by the threat of investigation, with associated burdens; and the mergers that are deterred by the prospect of enforcement after consummation.

  25. Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.S. 197 (1904).

  26. In White’s dissent in Northern Securities, 193 U.S. at 377, White denounces the majority decision because “the very definition of the power to regulate commerce... excludes the conception that it extends to stock ownership.”.

  27. Holmes’s dissent, 193 U.S. at 410, asserts partnerships are not “contract or combination in restraint of trade” because the partnership lacks requisite proximity to that illegal act.

  28. For a brief discussion of the constitutional infirmities of the federal antitrust statutes, see Hylton (2003), at 52–55. The extent to which the statutory framework is constitutional in application depends on the willingness of enforcers to play by long-established norms. However, a decision by an enforcement agency to deviate from such norms should immediately invite a closer scrutiny by the courts of the constitutional and statutory basis for such a deviation.

  29. The Supreme Court warned against reading the antitrust laws to cobble together lawful acts to create a new unlawful act in Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. linkLine Communications, Inc., 555 U.S. 438 (2009) (no cobbling together a Sherman Act Section 2 violation, by a vertically-integrated dominant firm, out of a combination of high pricing of inputs and low pricing of outputs).

  30. See, e.g., Hylton (2003), at 54–55.

References

  • Adelman, M. A. (1969). Comment on the “H” concentration measure as a numbers-equivalent. Review of Economics and Statistics, 51, 99–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiginger, K. (1996). Confronting the implications of the cournot model with industry and firm data. Small Business Economics, 8, 365–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, J. M. (1940). Toward a concept of workable competition. The American Economic Review, 30, 241–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • DePrano, M. E., & Nugent, J. B. (1969). Economies as an antitrust defense: comment. The American Economic Review, 59(5), 947–953.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenfield, D., Kreisle, N., & Williams, M. (2015). Simulating a homogeneous product merger: a case study on model fit and performance. Working Paper No. 327, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission, Washington. https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/simulating-homogenous-product-merger-case-study-model-fit-performance/rwp_327.pdf

  • Hylton, K. N. (2003). Antitrust law: economic theory and common law evolution. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hylton, K. N. (2010). The law and economics of monopolization standards. In K. N. Hylton (Ed.), Antitrust law and economics. Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hylton, K. N. (2011). Brown shoe versus the horizontal merger guidelines. Review of Industrial Organization, 39, 95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L. (2021). Horizontal merger analysis. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 79, 102714.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nocke, V., & Whinston, M. D. (2010). Dynamic merger review. Journal of Political Economy, 118, 1201–1251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nocke, V., & Whinston, M. D. (2022). Concentration thresholds for horizontal mergers. American Economic Review, 112, 1915–1948.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reisinger, M., & Zenger, H. (2022). The competitive effects of mergers with cournot competition. Retrieved October 12, 2022, from https://ssrn.com/abstract=3881145 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3881145.

  • Rose, N. L., & Shapiro, C. (2022). What next for the horizontal merger guidelines? Antitrust magazine, Spring.

  • Shahshahani, S., & McCarty, N. (2023). Testing political antitrust. New York University Law Review, 98, 1169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, N., & Vives, X. (1984). Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. The RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 546–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1968). Economies as an antitrust defense: the welfare tradeoffs. American Economic Review, 58, 18–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willig, R. D. (1991). Merger analysis, industrial organization theory, and merger guidelines. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, the Brookings Institution, 22, 281–332.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Katelyn Lee for research assistance. I thank Roger Blair, Michael Meurer, Steve Marks, Ben Pyle, and Sepehr Shashahani for comments on an early draft.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

KNH wrote the entire paper.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Keith N. Hylton.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hylton, K.N. Getting Merger Guidelines Right. Rev Ind Organ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09967-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09967-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation