1 Introduction

We believe that human connection is central to buyer engagement. On Etsy, we emphasize that the items listed for sale are brought to life by real people.

-Etsy, Inc., 2018 Annual Report.

The e-commerce website Etsy was founded in 2005 as a marketplace for handmade products. In an era of technological advancement, Etsy’s business model is notable: Everything that is listed in the marketplace must be “handmade or unique and assembled with production partners, vintage or craft supplies” (Etsy, Inc, 2019a, p. 11). In a wide range of categories—including jewelry, clothing, toys and furniture—the sellers’ production processes could readily be automated, which could potentially result in improved quality and fewer defective products. Nevertheless, the number of buyers and sellers on Etsy has been rising with gross merchandise sales (GMS) surpassing 2.5 billion U.S. dollars in the second quarter of 2020 (Fig. 1). It is, therefore, worth understanding why this sector of the economy can persist in the twenty-first century.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Business activity on Etsy since 2014 (data source: Etsy, Inc)

In this paper, I offer an explanation for the observed puzzle. I argue that a handmade effect on the consumer side (Fuchs et al., 2015) can explain why some firms—like those selling on Etsy—do not adopt superior production processes and instead choose to produce and advertise their products as handmade. I present a model that features a unit mass of shoppers. They come in two types: quality shoppers, and conscious shoppers. In this setting, product differentiation has two dimensions (e.g., Economides, 1989): All shoppers value product quality equally, but they differ in the weight that they give to the production process. From a firm’s perspective, there are nontrivial interactions: Hand production comes at a higher effort cost, and may be inferior at translating any given effort into quality.

I show that when a fraction of shoppers is sufficiently concerned about the conditions under which the product is manufactured and, therefore, is willing to pay a handmade premium, the firm adopts a handmade strategy. A minimum quality standard, however, can alter the firm’s behaviour and induce switching to machine production. When hand production is associated with increasing marginal cost, I show that a niche handmade product can be perceived to be of higher quality than a mass market machine-made product.

I extend the model to settings in which two ex-ante identical firms decide simultaneously on the production process, pricing strategy, and per-unit effort. I show that the existence of sufficiently conscious shoppers can explain the specialisation of firms and, thus, the observed co-existence of handmade and machine-made products in the economy. I show that such specialisation is efficient, and robust to collusion if the proportion of conscious shoppers in the market is not too large and their concern about the conditions under which the product is manufactured is not too high.

I then introduce conformist shoppers who behave exactly like conscious or quality shoppers depending on their beliefs. In this setting, a monopolist may be able to use a handmade strategy to signal a social norm of conscious consumption. When credible, this strategy generates a crowding-in effect and explains sales growth even in markets where conscious shoppers are believed to be in the minority. Finally, I show that my model can shape intuitions also on ethical production, and can explain the mainstreaming of Fair Trade in Europe in the late 1990s (Renard, 2003) through such a crowding-in effect.

1.1 Related Literature

My paper relates to the growing economic literature on ethical consumption (e.g., Stiefenhofer, 2019). The empirical literature has focused on estimating consumers’ willingness to pay a premium for ethical products (e.g., Galarraga & Markandya, 2004; Loureiro & Lotade, 2005; Arnot et al., 2006). For example, when buying more expensive Fair-Trade products, consumers reveal their preferences for ethical products. They are inferred to obtain additional utility from the product’s Fair-Trade label. My model builds on these insights: conscious shoppers gain utility from buying a handmade product whereas quality shoppers care only about product quality.

My extension to two firms relates to how product differentiation can relax price competition. In his classical work on monopolistic competition, Chamberlin (1933) notes that product differentiation leads buyers to pair with sellers according to their preferences. Firms evade price competition by focusing buyers’ attention towards a trade-mark, or by competing on the basis of quality. In my model, attention is focused on the production process: A handmade strategy relaxes price competition. Champsaur and Rochet (1989) obtain a similar result by allowing firms to choose non-overlapping qualities followed by prices. Sebald and Vikander (2019) consider a related signaling game in which a monopolist faces a fraction of consumers who care about what other consumers believe.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Sect. 2 introduces the model. I discuss my main results when the firm acts as a monopolist in Sect. 3, and when the firm is part of a duopoly in Sect. 4. In Sect. 5, I explain how a monopolist may use a handmade strategy to signal a social norm of conscious consumption. Section 6 concludes with an application to Fair Trade, and avenues for future research.

2 Model

The key mechanism in my model is the handmade effect: Some consumers perceive that handmade products symbolically contain the producer’s love for the product and its production process (Fuchs et al., 2015). In particular, they may value that the product is crafted and touched by someone with a passion for the product (Argo et al., 2008). Moreover, the handmade label imbues the product with the producer’s personality or “face” (Johnston & Baumann, 2007). The product may be perceived to embody the creator’s unique personal expression (Kreuzbauer et al., 2015). Conversely, machine-made products cannot absorb the producer’s passion given that the product is often not touched at all during its production (Markoff, 2012).

A second value channel is the “authenticity” of the producer: Some consumers may value that the producer of a handmade product assumes responsibility for the production process; business decisions under machine production do not convey a producer’s values but are perceived as marketing strategy (Carroll & Wheaton, 2009; Lehman et al., 2019). I formalise the handmade effect on the consumer side through a fraction C of shoppers being conscious of this handmade effect. These conscious shoppers care about the conditions under which the product is manufactured: They value production by hand h over machine production m. Thus, conscious shoppers base their buying decision on an enlarged set of product attributes compared to the other shoppers (Lancaster, 1966): price, product quality, and the production process.

2.1 Timing and Actions

The firm F and a unit mass of shoppers (the market) play a two-stage game: In the first stage, the firm chooses the production process \(k \in \{h,m\}\), the product’s per-unit price \(p_k\), and the per-unit effort level \(x_k \ge 0\). I assume that product quality is jointly determined by the production process and effort, which I will describe in more detail below.

In the second stage, having observed the firm’s decision, the shoppers choose whether to buy one unit of the product. They have an outside option that yields a zero payoff. Let C and \(Q=1-C\) be the fraction of conscious shoppers and quality shoppers in the market, respectively. Let \(a_i \in \{0,1\}\), \(i= C,Q\), be their buying decision.

2.2 Firm’s Payoffs

For a given k, the firm chooses the per-unit price and the per-unit effort level to solve the profit maximisation problem

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{(p_k,x_k)\in \mathbb {R}_+^2} \Pi (p_k, x_k; k) = \max _{(p_k,x_k)\in \mathbb {R}_+^2}(a_C C + a_Q Q )\bigg [p_k - \frac{c_k}{2} x_k^2\bigg ]. \end{aligned}$$

The firm’s per-unit cost is \(c(x_k) = \frac{c_k}{2}x_k^2\). Therefore, the firm’s profit depends on the cost parameter \(c_k> 0\), where \(c_h > c_m\). Intuitively, it is more costly to produce one unit of the product by hand. For example, for a given effort level, it requires more time to knit a pair of socks by hand. The assumption that \(c_h > c_m\) then captures the firm’s opportunity cost of time in a reduced form. Note that for tractability the per-unit cost increases in effort but remains constant in the level of output produced. I will relax this assumption in Sect. 3.1.

2.3 Quality Shoppers’ Payoffs

Quality shoppers choose to buy one unit of the product if it maximises their utility:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{a_Q \in \{0,1\}} V_Q(a_Q;k) = \max _{a_Q \in \{0,1\}} a_Q [q(x_k,k) - p_k]. \end{aligned}$$

Not buying yields a zero payoff. Conversely, buying one unit yields a payoff of \(q(x_k,k)-p_k\). The value \(q(\cdot )\) represents the benefit from consuming one unit. Following the literature on vertical differentiation (e.g., Mussa & Rosen, 1978), the benefit rises linearly with the product’s quality.Footnote 1

Assumption 1

(Product Quality) \(q(x_k,k) = A_k x_k\) with \(A_m \ge A_h \ge 1\).

I assume that the product’s per-unit quality is increasing at a constant rate \(A_k\) in the firm’s effort level. The production process, therefore, scales the shoppers’ benefit for a given amount of effort, where \(q(0,m)=q(0,h)\) and \(q(x,m)\ge q(x,h)\) for all \(x>0\): Production by hand results in weakly lower product quality and, thus, in a weakly lower benefit for quality shoppers.Footnote 2

This could be due to physical and mechanical variance, or the possibility of human error in the production of h. Compared to the potentially inconsistent quality of handmade products, machine production allows for uniform product quality (Liebl & Roy, 2003), and increased precision (Markoff, 2012). Watches are one example: Machine-made quartz watches are “significantly more precise than the most expensive Swiss mechanical watches made by the hands of a skilled watchmaker in Geneva” (Kreuzbauer et al., 2015, p. 764).

Intuitively, the quality shoppers choose to buy one unit of product k if the quality is weakly greater than the price set by the firm in the first stage. What is more, quality shoppers only care about the end product: They shop for the highest quality. Thus, for a given price, they weakly prefer the firm to offer a machine-made product.

Arguably, some handmade products are of higher quality than mass-produced products. One example is the high-value niche wine production in France: compared to the machine harvesting in the Australian wine industry, France’s handcrafted artisan methods yield a limited quantity of high quality (Aylward & Carey, 2009). A second example is Aston Martin: Its limited number of expensive hand-built cars are recognised as authentic and well designed (Carney, 2016). The extension to convex production cost in Sect. 3.1 will accommodate these settings.

2.4 Conscious Shoppers’ Payoffs

Conscious shoppers choose to buy one unit of the product if it maximises their utility:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{a_C \in \{0,1\}} V_C(a_C;k) = \max _{a_C \in \{0,1\}} a_C [q(x_k,k) - p_k + \theta \nu (k)]. \end{aligned}$$

The exogenous parameter \(\theta > 0\) measures their sensitivity to the production process.Footnote 3 The designation of a product as handmade to trigger \(\theta\) for segment C is exogenously determined; for example, through the enforcement of a Handmade Policy (Etsy, Inc, 2019b).

Assumption 2

(One-sided Concern) \(\nu (k) = \mathbb {I}(k=h)\).

Let \(\mathbb {I}(x=y)\) be an indicator function that is equal to unity if its argument holds true, and zero otherwise. I normalise the conscious shoppers’ utility gain from consuming a handmade product to unity. Moreover, I assume that their utility loss from consuming a machine-made product is zero. A one-sided concern of conscious shoppers is a natural assumption given that most firms that use m do not mention the production process explicitly when marketing their product (Fuchs et al., 2015). Consequently, only production by hand is salient when conscious shoppers make the buying decision.

Intuitively, conscious shoppers care about more than product quality: They are also concerned about the conditions under which the product is manufactured. Depending on their sensitivity to the production process, buying one unit of a product that is marketed as handmade may be more important than the product’s quality. Carfagna et al. (2014, p. 165) provide empirical support for my choice of utility function: Consumers who are strong supporters of the Do-It-Yourself ethic are “less concerned about quality and outcome and more oriented to the process”.

2.5 Solution Method and Preliminary Results

I solve the model by first considering the shoppers’ decision problem. The shoppers buy one unit of the product if \(V_i(1;k) \ge V_i(0;k)\), \(i=C,Q\). Therefore, conscious shoppers’ maximum willingness to pay is \(p_{C,k}:=q(x_k,k)+ \theta \nu (k)\), and quality shoppers are willing to pay \(p_{Q,k}:=q(x_k,k)\) for \(k=h,m\): Quality shoppers are always willing to pay a weakly higher price for the machine-made product. Depending on the conscious shoppers’ concern about the conditions under which the product is manufactured, they may be willing to pay a higher price for the handmade product: \(q(x,m) \gtrless q(x,h) + \theta\) for \(x>0\).

In the first stage, the firm infers that quality shoppers are willing to pay less for a handmade product than are conscious shoppers. In particular, the firm sets a price of \(p^*_h = p_{Q,h}\) to sell one unit of the handmade product to the whole market. Quality shoppers are indifferent between buying and not buying at \(p^*_h\). The firm sets a price of \(p_h^{**} = p_{C,h}\) to sell one unit of the handmade product to a fraction of the market. Conscious shoppers are indifferent at \(p_h^{**}\). Conversely, under Assumption 2, quality shoppers’ and conscious shoppers’ willingness to pay for a machine-made product coincides. Thus, the firm always sells one unit of the machine-made product to the whole market. The optimal price \(p^*_m=p_{Q,m}=p_{C,m}\) makes all shoppers indifferent.

3 The Firm’s Production Decision

In this section, I analyse the implications of a handmade effect on the firm’s optimal production process: Can the presence of conscious shoppers lead to situations in which the firm prefers producing h? Specifically, how strong does the handmade effect have to be to make h preferable?

Proposition 1

(Equilibrium) If

$$\begin{aligned} C\theta > (1-C)\Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m) +C \big [\Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m) - \Pi (p^*_h, x^*_h; h)\big ], \end{aligned}$$
(1)

the firm sells h to conscious shoppers only and makes profit

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi (p^{**}_h, x^{**}_h; h) = C[\Pi (p^*_h, x^*_h; h) + \theta ] = C \bigg [\frac{A_h^2}{2c_h} + \theta \bigg ]>0, \end{aligned}$$

where \(p_h^{**}= p_h^* + \theta =A_hx_h^{**} + \theta\) and \(x_h^{**}= x_h^* =A_h/c_h\). Otherwise, the firm sells m to the whole market and makes profit

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m) = \frac{A_m^2}{2c_m}>0, \end{aligned}$$

where \(p_m^*=A_mx_m^*\) and \(x_m^*=A_m/c_m\).

Proof

Detailed proofs of all results are in Appendix A. \(\square\)

If production is by hand, \(k=h\), the conscious shoppers’ sensitivity to the production process and the comparative size of segment C determines whether the firm: (i) sells to the whole market at \(p_h^*\); or (ii) sells to conscious shoppers only at a higher price \(p_h^* + \theta\). The optimal quality of the handmade product is unaffected by this decision. Moreover, given that profit turns out to be positive for a given production process, the firm always chooses to produce.

Therefore, when conscious shoppers’ concern \(\theta\) is below a certain threshold that decreases in the size of segment C, the firm compares its profit from selling h or m to the whole market. In this case, however, a handmade strategy can never be optimal: The firm cannot charge a handmade premium but faces increased marginal cost and potentially reduced product quality for a given effort level.

For a concern \(\theta\) above this threshold, the firm compares its profit from selling h to conscious shoppers only with its profit from selling m to the whole market. In this case, a handmade strategy can be optimal if the market segment of conscious shoppers is sufficiently large and concerned enough about the production conditions. This allows the firm to extract a sufficiently high handmade premium from this fraction of the market.

In particular, condition (1) in Proposition 1 says that the total premium needs to outweigh the loss from: (i) not serving market segment \(1-C\); and (ii) selling to segment C under increased marginal cost and reduced product quality for a given effort level. Thus, a handmade product that is sold in equilibrium classifies as a specialised product (Pepall, 1992): It is targeted to those shoppers whose willingness to pay for the special handmade feature is particularly high.

Church and Oakley (2018, p. 894) provide empirical support for the handmade premium on Etsy: “Handmade products sold for an average of 78% more than their traditionally manufactured counterparts, even after controlling for shop size, reputation and social media performance”. Fuchs et al. (2015) provide experimental evidence: Participants were, on average, willing to pay 17 percent more when a bar of soap was presented as handmade rather than machine-made.

Johnson and Myatt (2006) obtain a similar result: Optimal product design relates to whether a firm uses a mass market or a niche production strategy. They show that when valuations are relatively homogeneous, the firm prefers to serve a large fraction of potential consumers through a product design that has universal appeal. Under heterogeneity, in contrast, the firm restricts sales to a relatively small niche through a product design that caters to specialised tastes. In my model, given Assumption 2, a change from machine to hand production is likewise associated with a dispersion in the distribution of shoppers’ willingness to pay, which is profitable for the firm if \(\theta\) is sufficiently large.

Due to the assumption that \(A_m \ge A_h \ge 1\) and \(c_h> c_m> 0\), the firm chooses to produce a higher quality product under machine production. If the firm nonetheless finds it optimal to sell a handmade product to conscious shoppers, regulators may be concerned that the firm substitutes a handmade label for quality, which would leave conscious shoppers ill-informed (Leland, 1979).

Therefore, regulators may introduce a minimum quality standard \(\bar{q}\) that will be binding for production by hand, \(\bar{q} > q(x_h^{**},h)\), but will not be binding for machine production, \(q(x_m^*,m) > \bar{q}\). In other words, regulation affects only the firm that produces by hand, and forces this firm to increase the handmade product’s quality to \(\bar{q}\). Under what conditions does such regulation alter the firm’s behaviour? Specifically, when does \(\bar{q}\) induce the firm to switch to producing m, reversing the handmade effect? How does \(\bar{q}\) impact welfare?

Proposition 2

(Minimum Quality Standard) Suppose condition (1) holds: If regulation enforces \(\bar{q} \in (q(x_h^{**},h), q(x_m^*,m))\) and the enforced quality standard exceeds \(\check{q}\), where

$$\begin{aligned} \check{q} :=q(x_h^{**},h) + \sqrt{q(x_h^{**},h)^2 - \frac{q(x_m^*,m) q(x_h^{**},h)}{C} + 2 q(x_h^{**},h) \theta } > q(x_h^{**},h), \end{aligned}$$

then the firm switches to producing m.

Proposition 2 highlights that regulation may have unintended consequences if the enforced quality standard exceeds a certain threshold \(\check{q}\), and this threshold falls below \(q(x_m^*,m)\). Moreover, a minimum quality standard can alter the firm’s behaviour even without productivity differences: The higher effort cost for handmade products induces the firm to choose \(q(x_h^{**},h) < q(x_m^*,m)\) also when \(A_h=A_m\). A natural measure of welfare in this setting is the economic surplus from trade: the sum of the firm’s profit and the consumer surplus. As the firm increases the price \(\bar{p}= \bar{q}+ \theta\) one-for-one with increases in the quality standard, the consumer surplus remains constant in \(\bar{q}\) and is equal to zero. Therefore, the economic surplus is

$$\begin{aligned} ES :={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} C\theta + C\big (\bar{q}- \frac{c_h}{2A_h^2} \bar{q}^2 \big ) & \quad if \ \ q(x_h^{**},h)< \bar{q} \le \check{q},\\ \frac{A_m^2}{2c_m} & \quad if \ \ \check{q}< \bar{q} < q(x_m^*,m). \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

Intuitively, as long as the minimum quality standard does not induce the firm to switch to producing m, a more stringent standard causes the firm’s profit, and thus economic surplus, to fall. For a standard that exceeds a certain threshold, the firm switches; and given that the standard is not binding for machine production, economic surplus remains constant. Thus, my result contrasts with the possibility to create welfare-improving standards when there is competition in the dimension of quality (Economides, 1993).

3.1 Convex Production Cost

In my benchmark model, I assumed that the per-unit cost remains constant in the level of output produced. I focus on the effect of the production process on optimal effort and product quality, and provide conditions under which the handmade effect induces the firm to produce by hand.

In some settings, however, the workforce may become exhausted when hand production is scaled up due to the manual handling of materials whereas machine production prevents fatigue through mechanisation (ILO, 2010). Also, managerial coordination may become more complex at higher volumes. Thus, I relax the assumption of constant per-unit cost for h in this section. I show that increasing marginal cost reinforces my result that a handmade strategy is associated with lower sales. Moreover, it allows a niche handmade product to be of higher quality than a mass market machine-made product.

I model the firm’s profit maximisation problem in such settings as

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{(p_k,x_k)\in \mathbb {R}_+^2} \Pi (p_k, x_k; k) = \max _{(p_k,x_k)\in \mathbb {R}_+^2}(a_C C + a_Q Q ) p_k - (a_C C + a_Q Q )^{\alpha _k} \bigg [\frac{c_k}{2} x_k^2\bigg ], \end{aligned}$$

where \(\alpha _h > \alpha _m=1\). Unlike the benchmark model, the above specification permits: (i) the firm’s marginal production cost for the handmade product to be lower than for the machine-made product whenever sales of the handmade product fall short of \(s_1 :=\Big [\frac{1}{\alpha _h} \frac{c_m}{c_h} \big (\frac{x_m}{x_h}\big )^2\Big ]^{\frac{1}{\alpha _h-1}}\); and (ii) the firm’s total production cost for the handmade product to be lower for a given level of output below \(s_2 :=\alpha _h^\frac{1}{\alpha _h-1}s_1\); see Fig. 2.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Production cost as a function of output

If production is by hand, \(k=h\), the firm’s optimal effort \(x_h^*\) and profit \(\Pi (p_h^*, x_h^*;h)\) remain unchanged when selling the handmade product to the whole market. When selling to conscious shoppers only, the optimal effort level becomes \(x_h^{**} = \frac{C}{C^{\alpha _h}} \frac{A_h}{c_h} > x_h^*\), and the firm makes profit \(\Pi (p^{**}_h, x^{**}_h; h) = C \Big [\frac{C}{C^{\alpha _h}} \frac{A_h^2}{2c_h} + \theta \Big ]>0\), where \(p_h^{**}= A_h x_h^{**} + \theta\). Therefore, the firm chooses to sell a handmade product to conscious shoppers only at \(p_h^{**}\) over the whole market at \(p_h^*\) if

$$\begin{aligned} \theta \ge \frac{1-C^{2-\alpha _h}}{C} \Pi (p^*_h, x^*_h; h). \end{aligned}$$
(2)

Under increasing marginal cost, a niche handmade product has two advantages: First, the firm can charge conscious shoppers a handmade premium. Second, the firm can offer a product of higher quality when selling to conscious shoppers only, rather than to the whole market.

The second effect offsets the decrease in profit from lower sales independent of conscious shoppers’ concern: A handmade strategy can be beneficial for the firm even when \(\theta\) is low. The firm charges a slightly higher price to segment the market, and exclude quality shoppers. This slightly higher price allows the firm to meet demand with a high-quality product. In fact, given \(\theta > 0\), the firm will never choose to sell a handmade product to the whole market for \(\alpha _h \ge 2\): The deterioration in quality and, thus, the reduction in shoppers’ willingness to pay would be too large.

As before, a handmade strategy cannot be optimal if condition (2) does not hold. If the condition holds, or if \(\alpha _h \ge 2\), the firm compares its profit from selling a mass market machine-made product with a niche handmade product. In particular, condition (1) in Proposition 1 modifies to

$$\begin{aligned} C\theta > (1-C)\Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m) +C \bigg [\Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m) - \frac{C}{C^{\alpha _h}} \Pi (p^*_h, x^*_h; h)\bigg ]. \end{aligned}$$

The total handmade premium that induces the firm to choose a handmade strategy is lower under increasing than under constant marginal cost. Moreover, the handmade product that is sold in equilibrium is of higher quality than the machine-made product if the fraction of conscious shoppers is sufficiently small: \(C < \widetilde{C}\), where \(\widetilde{C} :=\Big (\frac{A_h c_m}{A_m c_h}\Big )^\frac{1}{\alpha _h-1} \in (0,1)\). Thus, increasing marginal cost can accommodate handmade products that are associated with higher quality and attention to detail (Dickson & Littrell, 1998).

3.2 Multi-product Monopolist

In my benchmark model, I implicitly assume that the firm is limited to one product for the handmade effect to be credible. When conscious shoppers learn that the firm produces both, they are willing to pay as little as quality shoppers for the handmade product as the firm loses its authenticity. Alternatively, the firm has to commit to having divisions m and h behave as independent profit maximisers to generate the handmade effect (Baye et al., 1996). This divisionalisation induces competition within the firm, and will be analysed in Sect. 4.Footnote 4

The restriction that the firm is limited to one product fits, for example, the U.S. craft beer market. U.S. craft breweries are mostly independently owned and are outside larger corporate ownership: “less than 25 percent of the craft brewery is owned or controlled [...] by a beverage alcohol industry member that is not itself a craft brewer” (Brewers Association, 2021). The world’s largest tea company—Unilever—provides an example in the application to Fair Trade (Sect. 6.1): The company has switched to sustainable sourcing of its entire tea supply, including the conversion of its leading tea brand Lipton (Poret, 2010).

There exist, however, counterexamples, such as the banana company Dole, which offers shoppers a standard product and an organic option that is Fair-Trade certified. Thus, I relax the restriction in this section: I show that the unrestricted monopolist always sells to the entire market, and that it adds a second product line h to its standard product line m if the total handmade premium is sufficiently large.

First, note that if the monopolist produces both products and sets prices \(p_m^* = q(x_m,m)\) and \(p_h^{**}= q(x_h,h)+\theta\), then conscious and quality shoppers are indifferent between buying and not buying m, but only conscious shoppers are indifferent between buying and not buying h. Quality shoppers would not buy h at a premium: \(p_{Q,h}<p_h^{**}\). Therefore, offering two product lines with pricing schedule \((p_m^*, p_h^{**})\) is incentive-compatible for all shoppers as long as I assume that conscious shoppers buy h when indifferent between the two products and not buying.

Moreover, due to the lower marginal cost and the potentially higher product quality under machine production the monopolist always chooses to sell m to quality shoppers to maximise profit. Therefore, the monopolist needs to consider whether it is profit-maximising to add a second product line h in order to sell a handmade instead of a machine-made product to conscious shoppers.

If the firm adds a second product line h, it makes profit \(\Pi (p^{**}_h, x^{**}_h; h) = C[\Pi (p^*_h, x^*_h; h) + \theta ]\) from selling to segment C; if it offers only one standard product line m to the entire market, the firm makes profit \(C\Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m)\) from selling to segment C. Comparing the profits in the segment of conscious shoppers, the firm adds product line h if

$$\begin{aligned} C\theta > C \big [\Pi (p^*_m, x^*_m; m) - \Pi (p^*_h, x^*_h; h)\big ]. \end{aligned}$$
(3)

Compared to condition (1), the total handmade premium now only needs to outweigh the loss from selling to segment C under increased marginal cost and reduced product quality for a given effort level. Therefore, the model with a restricted monopolist and an unrestricted monopolist make identical predictions if the total premium is so low that condition (3) does not hold: All shoppers are served a machine-made product. If the total premium is moderate so that condition (3) but not (1) holds, the unrestricted monopolist sells h rather than m to segment C. If the total premium is high, a niche production strategy is optimal only for the restricted monopolist. The unrestricted monopolist offers two product lines to serve the entire market.

In contrast to Mussa and Rosen (1978) and Deneckere and McAfee (1996), the unrestricted monopolist in my model does not cannibalise some of its high-quality market m when introducing the lower-quality product h because my shoppers have identical valuations for quality. Intuitively, the firm does not face a negative externality that would limit its possibilities for capturing all of the consumer surplus when adding a second product line. Hence, the unrestricted monopolist achieves perfect discrimination instead of imperfect discrimination in my model.

4 Duopoly

In many product categories—such as soap and ceramic tableware—the availability of high-quality machine production does not prevent firms from selling handmade products (Fuchs et al., 2015): Consumers are given the choice of buying a handmade or a machine-made product. What is more, there is specialisation: The products tend to be sold by different firms. I model this setting with the above framework extended to two firms, \(F_i\) and \(F_j\): Each firm can specialise in m or h, and can sell to both segment C and Q. The firms choose the production process, the product’s per-unit price, and the per-unit effort level, simultaneously. Shoppers continue to have unit demand.

When is specialisation an equilibrium outcome such that both the handmade product and the machine-made product are offered in the market? Specifically, under which conditions does \(F_i\) produce and sell h to conscious shoppers, and \(F_j\) produce and sell m to quality shoppers? What are the equilibrium prices and profits under specialisation?

Proposition 3

(Specialised Equilibrium) There exists an equilibrium in which \(F_i\) sells h to conscious shoppers at \(p_h^{**} - \bar{\varepsilon }\), and \(F_j\) sells m to quality shoppers at \(p_m^*\) if

$$\begin{aligned} \theta \ge \bigg (C + \frac{1-C}{C}\bigg ) \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m) - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h) \ge \bigg (\frac{C}{1-C} + \frac{1-C}{C}\bigg ) \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h). \end{aligned}$$
(4)

Under specialisation, \(F_i\) and \(F_j\) make the same profit and the price discount offered on h is

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\varepsilon } = \theta - \bigg [ \bigg (\frac{1-C}{C}\bigg ) \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m) - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)\bigg ] < \theta . \end{aligned}$$

Specialisation is an equilibrium outcome if the conscious shoppers’ sensitivity to the production process is sufficiently high. Specifically, condition (4) prevents a profitable deviation for \(F_j\) and \(F_i\), respectively.Footnote 5 Only a one-sided price reduction on h but not m can be a specialised equilibrium: \(F_j\) charges \(p_m^*\), while \(F_i\) charges \(p_h^{**} - \bar{\varepsilon }\). Given Assumption 2, conscious shoppers would want to deviate to buying a machine-made product if \(F_j\) reduced \(p_m^*\) while \(F_i\) charged \(p_h^{**}\).Footnote 6 The discount offered on h is strictly positive and bounded above by \(\theta\), which prevents a profitable deviation for quality shoppers. The price discount on h leaves conscious shoppers with strictly positive utility, whereas quality shoppers are left with zero utility: They are indifferent at \(p_m^*= p_{C,m}\).

Proposition 3 highlights that the presence of conscious shoppers and the choice of production process \(k \in \{h,m\}\) can break the usual price competition. Instead of a Bertrand duopoly in which the two firms target overlapping market segments and compete prices down to marginal cost to capture shoppers, \(F_i\) and \(F_j\) choose to act as monopolists in distinct market segments. The firms can act as monopolists because the segments do not adjust in response to relative price changes.

My result is in line with d’Aspremont et al. (1979, p. 1149), who note that “oligopolists should gain an advantage by dividing the market into submarkets in each of which some degree of monopoly would reappear”. A similar result has been obtained by Shaked and Sutton (1982) in a different setting: When consumers are identical in tastes but differ in income, price competition is relaxed through product differentiation. Mohliver et al. (2019) obtain differentiation in a counter-positioning equilibrium. Firms take opposing stances on a social issue that is characterised by: (i) how much people care about the issue; and (ii) what proportion of the population supports the issue.

The intuition behind Proposition 3 is akin to the one of Mussa and Rosen (1978): A sufficiently strong sensitivity allows the two firms to choose a price-quality schedule that allocates the two shopper types to the two different products h and m by a process of self-selection. Furthermore, given that conscious shoppers focus more on production conditions than on quality, tastes have to be sufficiently diverse for the handmade product to co-exist alongside the machine-made product of higher quality (Eaton & Lipsey, 1989).

An important question for policy is whether such specialisation is efficient. I define an outcome as efficient if it maximises the economic surplus from trade between the firms and the shoppers. The surplus is the sum of those shoppers’ marginal benefits that buy a product in equilibrium minus the production costs; equivalently, this is the sum of the firms’ profits and the consumer surplus. Therefore, the economic surplus in the specialised equilibrium is

$$\begin{aligned} ESS:= & Q A_m x_m^* + C(A_h x_h^*+ \theta ) -Qc(x_m^*) - Cc(x_h^*) \\= & Q \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m) + C\Pi (p_h^*, x_h^*;h) + C\theta = 2 Q \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m) + C \bar{\varepsilon }. \end{aligned}$$

Given that conscious shoppers obtain the handmade product and quality shoppers obtain the machine-made product in the specialised equilibrium, a scenario in which the two firms compete in selling h to conscious shoppers only cannot be more efficient. Furthermore, it follows from Proposition 1 that competing in selling h to the whole market cannot be more efficient either. Therefore, I can focus on \(F_i\) and \(F_j\) competing in selling m to the whole market to establish the specialised equilibrium’s efficiency.

Proposition 4

(Efficiency) The specialised equilibrium is efficient.

Intuitively, the existence of a specialised equilibrium implies its efficiency: The conscious shoppers’ sensitivity to the production process and its associated surplus \(C\theta\) is so high in the specialised equilibrium that it trumps the loss \(C[\Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*,m) - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)]\) in surplus from selling a lower-quality product to conscious shoppers.

Some of the gains from efficiency are passed along to conscious shoppers because \(F_i\)’s pricing behaviour is disciplined by the presence of a potential competitor (Bain, 1949): The discount \(\bar{\varepsilon }\) serves as a means to deter the switching of \(F_j\) into hand production, and thereby coordinates the firms’ behaviour on specialisation. Consequently, the potential competition moderates \(F_i\)’s profit but falls short of more vigorous competition (Gilbert, 1989): The discount is smaller than the conscious shoppers’ surplus that would be created by perfect competition.

In my analysis so far, I have made the implicit assumption that \(F_i\) and \(F_j\) play non-cooperatively. I now relax this assumption and allow the two firms to collude in order to study the robustness of the specialised equilibrium in Proposition 3. Under which conditions do the firms not have an incentive to merge to a monopolist, selling a single product k, when sharing the monopolist’s profit equally? In particular, either \(F_i\) can merge with \(F_j\) to sell m to the whole market, or \(F_j\) can merge with \(F_i\) to sell m to a fraction of the market.

Proposition 5

(Stability) The specialised equilibrium is stable if \(\theta \le \frac{2(1-C)}{C} \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m) - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)\) and \(C\le \frac{1}{2}\).

Corollary 1

(Collusion) In the specialised equilibrium, there exists \(\bar{C}:=\frac{\sqrt{5}-1}{2}>\frac{1}{2}\) such that \(F_i\) and \(F_j\) can profitably collude as (i) h- or m-monopolist for \(C > \bar{C}\), and (ii) m-monopolist for \(\bar{C} \ge C > \frac{1}{2}\).

Intuitively, the specialised equilibrium is robust to collusion if the proportion of conscious shoppers in the market is not too large and the conscious shoppers’ concern about the conditions under which the product has been manufactured is not too high. Specifically, merging to sell m to the whole market is profitable for \(F_i\) and \(F_j\) when conscious shoppers are in the majority. Merging to sell h to a fraction of the market requires a larger critical mass \(\bar{C}\).

5 Signaling a Social Norm of Conscious Consumption

The baseline model with conscious and quality shoppers explains why a firm chooses production by hand over machine production through a handmade effect on the consumer side. However, the baseline model does not capture the rising demand for and the mainstreaming of costly handmade products (Richards, 2018), the sales growth on dedicated marketplaces like Etsy (Fig. 1), and social movements such as “buyhandmade.org” (Walker, 2007).

In this section, I consider how the firm’s handmade strategy can be indicative of a social norm of conscious consumption. As a consequence, shoppers who are not conscious to begin with convert into conscious shoppers and also buy premium-priced handmade products. I develop a signaling model with a single firm in the spirit of Sliwka (2007): quality and conscious shoppers’ decision criteria are fixed from the outset, whereas conformist shoppers are influenced by social norms. Under which conditions can the firm credibly signal a social norm of conscious consumption, inducing those conformist shoppers to buy premium-priced handmade products in equilibrium?

5.1 The Extended Model

Shoppers come in three types: As before, quality shoppers care only about product quality whereas conscious shoppers also care about the conditions under which the product is produced. Following Sliwka (2007), I refer to these two types as the steadfast shoppers: Their decision criteria are fixed from the outset. The fraction of conscious shoppers among the steadfast is given by \(\varphi\), and is drawn from some prior distribution.

Conformist shoppers constitute the third type. Because these shoppers are uncertain about the appropriate consumption behaviour, they are influenced by social norms. For example, if the firm is selling a handmade product, conformist shoppers will take the production conditions positively into account only if they believe that many other shoppers also do. I model this as follows: The production process is payoff-relevant for a conformist shopper if and only if she believes that sufficiently many other steadfast shoppers are also conscious about the production process. In particular, the utility of a conformist shopper is equal to \(V_C(a_C;k)\) if she believes that the median steadfast shopper is conscious, and equal to \(V_Q(a_Q;k)\) otherwise.Footnote 7

As an established firm, it will typically have learned from previous shoppers’ behaviour or will have undertaken market research. Therefore, I assume that the firm knows the fraction of conscious shoppers among the steadfast to be either high or low, \(\varphi \in \{ \varphi _H, \varphi _L\}\). Moreover, I assume that the firm’s private information about the fraction of conscious shoppers is pivotal: \(\varphi _H> 1/2 > \varphi _L\).

Consequently, when conformist shoppers are able to infer the firm’s private information from its production process, they revise their preferences. Conversely, when conformist shoppers cannot infer the firm’s private information, then \(\mathbb {E}(\varphi )= \gamma \varphi _H + (1- \gamma ) \varphi _L \lessgtr 1/2\) with commonly known prior \(\gamma :=\Pr (\varphi = \varphi _H) \in (0,1)\) determines whether conformist shoppers behave like conscious or quality shoppers. The fraction of conformist shoppers in the market has mean \(\eta\) according to the common prior expectation; see Fig. 3.

Fig. 3
figure 3

The extended market

The timing is as follows. In the first stage, the firm privately observes \(\varphi \in \{\varphi _H,\varphi _L \}\). As before, the firm chooses the production process \(k \in \{h,m\}\), the product’s per-unit price \(p_k\), and the per-unit effort level \(x_k \ge 0\). In the second stage, the shoppers choose whether to buy one unit of the product. All shoppers have unit demand irrespective of the production process.

Given that the firm’s choice of the production process may reveal its private information, the extended model is a signaling game. Moreover, depending on a conformist shopper’s belief about \(\varphi\), her action will always correspond exactly to either that of a steadfastly quality shopper or a steadfastly conscious shopper. Hence, the firm’s profit in the extended model depends on its production process k and whether conformist shoppers act like conscious or quality shoppers.

Assumption 3

\(\Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)+ \theta > \Pi (p_m^*, x_m^*;m)\).

Before deriving the key result, I make the assumption that the firm would be better off using a handmade strategy if the market consisted entirely of steadfastly conscious shoppers.

5.2 Separating Equilibrium

The key idea is that it may be attractive for the firm to choose a handmade strategy to signal its private information that most shoppers are conscious. However, even a credible handmade strategy comes with a trade-off: While the firm is better off when conformist shoppers convert into conscious shoppers, quality shoppers do not buy a premium-priced handmade product.

The handmade strategy will be a credible signal when there is separation in equilibrium: A firm that privately observes \(\varphi _H\) produces by hand, and a firm that privately observes \(\varphi _L\) uses machine production. Specifically, when the conformist shoppers believe that the handmade strategy is indeed a credible signal, neither firm can have an incentive to deviate from this strategy. If \(\varphi\) is the firm’s private information about the fraction of conscious shoppers among the steadfast, its expected profit under machine production is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m) = [\varphi (1-\eta ) + (1-\varphi )(1- \eta ) + \eta ]\frac{A_m^2}{2c_m}=\frac{A_m^2}{2c_m}. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Given Assumption 2, the firm sells to the whole market at price \(p_m^*= A_m x_m^*\). Intuitively, under a one-sided concern of conscious shoppers, the market composition is irrelevant for the firm’s pricing decision under machine production.

When the firm produces by hand, it must prefer losing out on the fraction of quality shoppers. This follows from Proposition 1: A handmade strategy can never be optimal for a firm that sells to the whole market of shoppers. The firm would have an incentive to deviate. Hence, I assume that \(\eta \ge \tilde{\eta }(\varphi _H)\) in the separating equilibrium, where

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\eta }(\varphi _H) :=\frac{1}{1-\varphi _H} \bigg [ \frac{\Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)}{\Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h) + \theta } - \varphi _H \bigg ], \end{aligned}$$

which implies that \(p_h^{**}= A_hx_h^* + \theta\) and \(x_h^{**} = x_h^* = A_h/c_h\) are optimal. As quality shoppers’ maximum willingness to pay is \(p_h^*= A_h x_h^*\), this type will not buy the handmade product.

Simultaneously, the firm benefits from an amplified handmade effect: Because conformist shoppers become conscious, they are willing to pay the handmade premium. Hence, there is greater demand for the premium-priced handmade product. The firm’s expected profit under hand production is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi (p_h^{**},x_h^{**};h) = [\varphi (1- \eta ) + \eta ]\bigg [\frac{A_h^2}{2c_h} + \theta \bigg ]. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Comparing Eqs. (5) and (6), and solving for \(\eta\) highlights that the firm will use a handmade strategy when the fraction of conformist shoppers is larger than the threshold

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\eta }(\varphi ) :=\frac{1}{1-\varphi }\Bigg [\frac{\Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m)}{\Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)+ \theta } - \varphi \bigg ]. \end{aligned}$$

This threshold is decreasing in \(\varphi\), since higher values imply a lower fraction of steadfastly quality shoppers who do not buy the premium-priced handmade product. As a result, a handmade strategy becomes more attractive. I use the threshold to derive the separating equilibrium.Footnote 8

Proposition 6

(Separating Equilibrium) If \(\theta < \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m)/ \varphi _L - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)\), a separating equilibrium exists in which the firm sells a premium-priced handmade product to steadfastly conscious and conformist shoppers after observing \(\varphi _H\), and sells a machine-made product to the whole market after observing \(\varphi _L\) if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \eta \in [\max \{0, \hat{\eta }(\varphi _H) \}, \hat{\eta }(\varphi _L)], \end{aligned}$$

where \(\hat{\eta }(\varphi _H)< \hat{\eta }(\varphi _L)<1\) and \(\hat{\eta }(\varphi _L)>0\).

The conscious shoppers’ sensitivity to the production process and the fraction of conformist shoppers jointly determine whether the separating equilibrium in Proposition 6 exists. The greater is the fraction of conformists, the smaller is the range of concerns \(\theta\) for which separation is possible: A handmade strategy becomes more appealing because the firm’s expanded market for a premium-priced handmade product grows faster than its base market shrinks.

Moreover, if \(\theta\) is small, a separating equilibrium exists when there are neither too few or too many conformists. Specifically, when \(\theta < \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m)/ \varphi _H - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)\), the lower bound is given by \(\hat{\eta }(\varphi _H)\). When there are few conformist shoppers, even a firm that privately observes \(\varphi _H\) prefers to sell a machine-made product. The higher is the fraction of conformist shoppers, the more attractive it is to signal optimism about the social norm of conscious consumption. But when there are too many conformist shoppers, even a firm that privately observes \(\varphi _L\) would want to imitate this signal, and it would no longer be credible.

If the conscious shoppers’ sensitivity is above this value, the total handmade premium from selling to steadfastly conscious and conformist shoppers is so high that a firm that observes \(\varphi _H\) would never want to deviate to machine production. In this case, the separating equilibrium exists when there are not too many conformists and \(\theta < \Pi (p_m^*,x_m^*;m)/ \varphi _L - \Pi (p_h^*,x_h^*;h)\).

Intuitively, the fewer are the number of steadfastly conscious shoppers, the higher is the cost of using a handmade strategy in the absence of conformists: The firm cannot offset the loss in sales to quality shoppers through higher prices that are charged to conformists. Hence, a firm that knows that the fraction of conscious shoppers among the steadfast is low may want to avoid a handmade strategy even if such a strategy could increase the conformists’ willingness to pay. In other words, separation is possible when this firm does not find it profitable to convert conformists as there are too few.Footnote 9

The key result in Proposition 6 is that the firm can use a handmade strategy to create a credible social norm of conscious consumption: The firm that observes \(\varphi _H\) is able to expand its market and mainstream costly handmade products. In essence, a credible signal generates sales growth through a crowding-in effect: Conformist shoppers convert into conscious shoppers when observing the firm’s handmade strategy. Importantly, this crowding-in effect can operate in a market in which the firm that observes \(\varphi _H\) believes that steadfastly conscious shoppers are in the minority. Specifically, even when the fraction of steadfastly conscious shoppers is arbitrarily small (i.e. \(\eta \rightarrow 1\)), a handmade strategy may credibly signal a social norm of conscious consumption.

Norm-based interventions and marketing campaigns (e.g., Cialdini et al., 2006) provide empirical support for my result. The credibility problem that limits a campaign’s effectiveness is highlighted by Benabou and Tirole (2011). The interaction between conscious shoppers’ concern and credibility is also observed by Melloni et al. (2019): In a cheap-talk model, CEO activism is more likely to be a credible and, thus, profitable strategy when shoppers care greatly about the type of firm that they buy from.

6 Discussion

In this paper, I developed a model that explains a handmade strategy of firms in an era of technological advancement through a handmade effect on the consumer side.

6.1 Further Applications: Fair Trade

My model generates insights whenever a firm chooses between a conventional production process and an alternative production process. The latter includes Fair Trade, organic produce, and local produce. To demonstrate, I relate my assumptions to Fair-Trade production and underline my predictions with empirical evidence in Fair Trade.

My assumptions capture several key characteristics of Fair Trade: First, Fair-Trade products and conventional products—such as coffee and chocolate—are functional substitutes for shoppers: “Fair Trade and traditionally marketed products show at most very little divergence and hardly differ with respect to their functional utility” (Mohan, 2010, p. 34). Second, Fair Trade may be less productive in the short-run. While higher environmental standards ensure sustainability, land may not be farmed as extensively. Farmers are also encouraged to reduce their use of pesticides (Nicholson, 2018). Fair Trade is more costly for the same per-unit effort level: Firms pay a licence fee for the Fair-Trade label, and pay a living wage to workers, which may exceed the legal minimum.Footnote 10 Moreover, providing a safe working environment may increase costs.

Conscious shoppers obtain utility from buying a product with a Fair-Trade label.Footnote 11 Importantly, these shoppers “care about the production process not because of its effects on the quality of the product itself but for other attributes of the process, such as environmental impacts, effects on animal welfare, country of origin, and so on” (Antle, 1999, p. 1002). In essence, the Fair-Trade firm sells a bundle: The conventional product, plus a contribution to a social or ecological production process (Steinrücken & Jaenichen, 2007) or a donation to the farmer (Reinstein & Song, 2012). As is argued by Richardson and Stähler (2014), the mechanism may be a warm glow from the knowledge that a Fair-Trade firm pays its growers a wage premium.

In my baseline model, selling a Fair-Trade product is the outcome of a profit maximisation problem: The firm weighs the additional costs against the expected benefits. In particular, the firm faces the trade-off that it can charge a Fair-Trade premium but only caters to a niche market of conscious shoppers. In my model, this Fair-Trade premium is the conscious shoppers’ maximum willingness to pay for the subjective services of the Fair-Trade label.Footnote 12 My model is in line with the observation that Fair-Trade products are more expensive than conventional products but do not deliver any extra physical quality (Mohan, 2010).

When the firm is part of a duopoly, conventional and Fair-Trade products may co-exist, as is observed in the economy. Moreover, the firms’ specialisation leads to market segmentation and allows for third-degree price discrimination: The Fair-Trade label prevents conventional products from entering the Fair-Trade market. When the firm faces conformist shoppers, my model predicts a growth in Fair-Trade sales if the firm can use a Fair-Trade strategy to create a credible social norm of conscious consumption. In particular, the conversion of conformist shoppers into conscious shoppers resembles the increased public awareness and understanding of the Fair-Trade rationale, and its mainstreaming in Europe in the late 1990s (Renard, 2003).Footnote 13

The predicted crowding-in effect aligns with the finding that building positive attitudes and removing skepticism positively impacts Fair-Trade buying behaviour (De Pelsmacker & Janssens, 2007). Consequently, my model not only predicts that “consumers of Fair Trade products form a kind of speciality market club, which can be joined voluntarily by those who are willing to pay extra for the Fair Trade product bundle” (Mohan, 2010, p. 43), but also that the sales growth of Fair-Trade products in Europe can be explained through a credible signal that most steadfast shoppers care.

6.2 Concluding Remarks

In my analysis, I made several simplifying assumptions: While a one-sided concern of conscious shoppers kept my model tractable, one could envisage situations in which regulation enforces firms to state their production process on the packaging. As a result, both hand and machine production are salient when conscious shoppers make the buying decision: \(\nu (h)>0>\nu (m)\). A firm that chooses machine production may then not want to serve all shoppers because conscious shoppers’ maximum willingness to pay falls short of quality shoppers’ maximum willingness to pay: \(p_{C,m} < p_{Q,m}\).

I also assumed that conscious shoppers and quality shoppers do not interact. However, when quality shoppers buy a handmade product that is also purchased by conscious shoppers, they may incur positive spillovers. For example, quality shoppers may value being perceived as conforming to a social norm of green consumerism (Carlsson et al., 2010). Future research could adapt the baseline model to a setting in which quality shoppers are willing to pay more than what is warranted by the handmade product’s quality if they are likely to meet a conscious shopper who bought the handmade product in stage 3.Footnote 14 Consequently, a handmade strategy may also be optimal for a firm that caters to the whole market.

Finally, future work could endogenise conscious shoppers’ sensitivity to the production process through a handmade spectrum (Etsy, Inc, 2019b): At one end would be producers literally making products with their own hands; and producers designing products with partners physically producing them would fall into an intermediate range. Instead of a binary choice k of the production process, a firm would then choose \(\theta \in [0, \bar{\theta }\)] to position itself on the spectrum, where \(\theta =0\) corresponds to the machine production of all components and per-unit cost \(c(x_\theta )\) increases in \(\theta\).