1 Introduction

The new United States Vertical Merger GuidelinesFootnote 1 (VMG) supersede the section on non-horizontal mergers in the U.S. Department of Justice (“DOJ”) 1984 Merger Guidelines,Footnote 2 the last merger guidelines that were issued by one of the U.S. antitrust agencies that addressed non-horizontal mergers.Footnote 3 When the DOJ issued those earlier guidelines, the dominant economic theories about vertical mergers were the single monopoly profit theoremFootnote 4 and the Cournot/Spengler models of complementary and successive monopoly.Footnote 5 The former laid out conditions under which vertical mergers are competitively neutral. In the latter, a complementary products/vertical merger results in the reduction of prices to consumers through the elimination of double marginalization (EDM).Footnote 6 A universally-acknowledged exception to the single monopoly profit theorem is the avoidance of rate regulation, and that theory was the basis for the Reagan-era DOJ decision to force the break-up of AT&T.

A major deficiency in the economic theory of vertical mergers as of 1984 was that it ignored a primary reason to be concerned that vertical mergers might be anticompetitive. Steven Salop and David Scheffman provided the key insight. They coined the term and provided a model that captured the incentive to “raise rivals’ costs” (“RRC”).Footnote 7 The successive monopoly cannot capture that phenomenon because, with monopoly at both stages, there are no rivals whose costs might be raised. The so-called “post-Chicago” literature on vertical mergers that arose starting in the late 1980s demonstrated the theoretical possibility of anticompetitive vertical mergers based on static pricing incentives.Footnote 8 In those models, RRC is the mechanism that creates the potential for anticompetitive harm.

In 2007, the European Commission issued non-horizontal merger guidelines.Footnote 9 As input into those guidelines, it commissioned a working paper by Jeffrey Church to review the literature on the economic theory of the competitive effects of vertical mergers.Footnote 10 The Church working paper contained an extensive review of the post-Chicago literature on vertical mergers and suggested policy implications. The EC Guidelines clearly reflect the influence of the Church Report. Until 2020, the US Agencies had not seen fit to issue new non-horizontal merger guidelines. Their failure to do so did not reflect ignorance of the post-Chicago literature on vertical mergers. A more likely explanation is that Agency officials and staff were not convinced that the post-Chicago literature provided a basis for practical policy guidance.Footnote 11

Given that the 1984 Merger Guidelines preceded the post-Chicago literature, a new set of vertical merger guidelines might seem long overdue. Before jumping to that conclusion, however, it is worth considering what the section on non-horizontal mergers in the 1984 Merger Guidelines stated. Reflecting the Chicago school influence, they did state that non-horizontal mergers are “less likely than horizontal mergers to create competitive problems,” but added “they are not invariably innocuous.”Footnote 12 They then laid out the principal theories that the DOJ might use to support a challenge to a vertical merger. Avoidance of rate regulation was one of those theories, but it was not the only one or even the one given the most prominence.

Instead, most of the section is devoted to concerns about entry. First, they point out that large firms at one stage may be likely entrants—and act as a competitive constraint as long as they are perceived to be likely entrants—into an adjacent stage. They stated that a vertical merger might raise entry barriers by foreclosing entry at a single stage. They also raise the possibility that vertical integration might facilitate collusion—based on the theory that detecting deviations from collusive agreements is easier with respect to final goods than with respect to intermediate goods.Footnote 13

The biggest difference between the VMG and the section on non-horizontal mergers in the 1984 Merger Guidelines is the emphasis that the VMG place on how the static pricing incentives that are created by a vertical merger can be to raise rivals’ costs and, in turn, prices to consumers. The VMG stress that the Agencies’ review of vertical mergers resembles in important respects their review of horizontal mergers. The Horizontal Merger GuidelinesFootnote 14 focus primarily on how a horizontal merger is likely to affect static pricing incentives. The key question to ask in assessing whether the VMG signal an improvement in policy is whether the analysis of static pricing incentives should be as central to vertical merger enforcement as it is to horizontal merger enforcement.

Echoing the 1984 merger guidelines, the VMG state, “While the agencies more often encounter problematic horizontal mergers than problematic vertical mergers, vertical mergers are not invariably innocuous.”Footnote 15 A natural question to ask about this statement is, “What distinguishes the relatively small number of vertical mergers that the Agencies believe pose a threat to competition from those that do not?” A clear answer to this question is necessary for the VMG to accomplish the stated goal of “assist[ing] the business community and antitrust practitioners by increasing the transparency of the analytic process underlying the Agencies’ enforcement decisions.”Footnote 16

Horizontal merger enforcement rests on what Sutton (1991) termed “robust theory.” In analyzing horizontal mergers and making their cases in court, the Agencies use a variety of models tailored to the specifics of a case. While the details of the models affect the quantitative predictions, the element that is common to all the models is the prisoner’s dilemma nature of decisions about what price to charge and how much to produce in oligopolistic markets. The standard oligopoly models taught in any undergraduate industrial economics course (and, for that matter, intermediate and even introductory microeconomics courses) capture the logic underlying horizontal merger enforcement.

The same is not true of vertical mergers. To understand this point, it is useful—indeed crucial – to consider the simplest possible models in which RRC and EDM can both occur. Since the Bertrand model with differentiated products has emerged as the primary theoretical underpinning for horizontal merger enforcement, the natural extension to evaluate vertical mergers is to allow for Bertrand competition with differentiated products at one stage and some form of market power – perhaps monopoly – at the adjacent stage.Footnote 17

If one is to assume duopoly at one stage and monopoly at the other, the monopoly stage can be “upstream,” “downstream,” or complementary. The difference in the models concerns the timing of decisions.Footnote 18 In a model of an upstream monopolist selling a necessary input to two competing downstream firms, the monopolist selects its price first in the pricing game, and the duopolists simultaneously set their prices second. In a model of competing manufacturers or service providers (such as a video programming service) that sell through a monopoly multi-product distributor, the duopolists move first in the pricing game. If the stages are modeled as complementary, then all the firms choose the price(s) of their respective stage simultaneously.Footnote 19 In this article, I focus on the second of these cases.Footnote 20 As I show in a companion paper,Footnote 21 the results from the first and the third are similar.Footnote 22

2 A Simple Model with Both EDM and RRC

Consider two upstream firms that produce differentiated products that they sell to a downstream firm, which then sells (or distributes) to the final consumers.

Let demand be given byFootnote 23:

$$ q_{i} = b_{i0} - b_{ii} p_{i} + b_{ij} p_{j} \;\; i,j \in \left( {1,2} \right), j \ne i $$
(1)

where qi and pi are the price and quantity of good i. Let wi be the upstream price of good i and assume that both prices exceed marginal cost, which we can assume to be 0.

The monopolist’s profit-maximizing prices areFootnote 24:

$$\begin{aligned} & \quad \quad p_{i} = b_{i0} - \frac{[2b_{ii} b_{jj} - b_{ij} (b_{ij} + b_{ji} )](b_{i0} - w_{i} ) + b_{ii} (b_{ij} - b_{ji} )(b_{j0} - w_{j} )}{4b_{11} b_{2 2} - (b_{i j} + b_{ji} )^{2}} \quad\quad i,j \in (1,2),j \ne i \end{aligned}$$
(2)

If the downstream monopolist merges with, say, upstream firm 1, it gets good 1 at marginal cost. As a result, the effect of the merger on the static pricing incentives depends on how a reduction in w1 affects p1 and p2. Intuitively, it might seem that such a merger would provide an incentive to reduce p1 and increase p2, and that is one of the qualitative possibilities. But there are two others: One—which is an application of what is known as “Edgeworth’s Paradox of Taxation”Footnote 25 – is that the merger provides an incentive to increase both prices. This possibility implies that the static pricing effects of EDM do not necessarily benefit consumers. But the other possibility is that the merger provides an incentive to reduce both prices, so RRC is not an inevitable result of a vertical merger either.

One might hypothesize that the two less-intuitive qualitative results are mere theoretical curiosities—similar to Giffen goods—and that there should be a strong presumption that the pricing incentives that are created by a vertical merger fall into the intermediate case of a reduction in the price of the product that the monopolist now produces and an increase in the product that competes with it. But, in Eq. (2), when \({b}_{12}= {b}_{21}\), the downstream price of good 2 does not depend on the upstream price of good 1.Footnote 26 If the income effects from price changes of the two goods are negligible, then the cross-price slopes of the Marshallian demands are also the cross-price effects of the compensated demand curves; and the equality of the cross effects is the Slutsky-Hicks condition that is needed for the demand system to imply an underlying utility function. Symmetry of cross-price effects is a much weaker condition than completely symmetric demand.

Demand curves do not have to be linear; and, even if all individual demand curves obey the Slutsky-Hicks condition, the market demand curves that are derived from aggregating them need not do so.Footnote 27 But there is nothing perverse about linear demand curves, and the Slutsky-Hicks conditions are a natural base case even if they do not have to hold literally. If b21 < b12, then EDM with respect to Good 1 does provide the merging firm with an incentive to increase p2. But, in that case, a merger of the downstream monopolist with the supplier of Good 2 would provide an incentive to reduce p1 (as well as p2).

The above analysis does not explicitly model the upstream equilibrium prior to the merger or how a vertical merger affects the pricing incentives of the remaining upstream firm. If we assume that the two upstream goods are strategic complements, however, a vertical merger would provide an incentive for the upstream competitor of the merged firm to reduce its price, which would in turn provide an additional incentive for the downstream monopolist to reduce prices to final consumers.

The model of a vertical merger between an upstream monopolist and one of two competing downstream firms yields similar conclusions.Footnote 28 With symmetric cross-price effects, a vertical merger results in a reduction in all prices—not only the two downstream prices but also the price that the merged firm charges its downstream competitor. That is, RRC does not occur. When the stages are modeled as complementary, a complementary-goods merger does give the merged firm an incentive to charge more for the component to be used in conjunction with its competitor’s product, but the combined price that purchasers of the competitor’s product pay for the two components decreases.

3 Policy Implications

3.1 Interpreting the Economic Theory of the Effect of Vertical Mergers

Some economists have argued that there is no basis in economic theory for a presumption that vertical mergers in concentrated markets pose less of a threat to competition than do horizontal mergers, and that the potential anticompetitive effect from a vertical merger is in effect the same as in a horizontal merger.Footnote 29 Simple economic models contradict such assertions.

In the above model, a horizontal merger of the competing duopolists would provide static pricing incentives to increase prices. That qualitative result is not sensitive to the assumptions about the functional form of demand, the specific parameters of the demand relationship, or the precise oligopolistic interaction between the two firms. In the same model, a vertical merger can result in price decreases for both goods and no RRC.

The duopoly-monopoly structure—regardless of which stage is “upstream” – is not simply one of many possible sets of modeling assumptions to make in assessing what economic theory predicts about the likely effects of vertical mergers on static pricing incentives. It is the natural extension of the Bertrand model with differentiated products to consider markets with multiple stages of production, and it is the natural extension of the successive/complementary merger model to consider the possibility of RRC effects.Footnote 30

If this set of assumptions yielded the robust result that vertical mergers in concentrated markets result in price increases, that result would provide the economic logic for competition agencies to treat vertical mergers similarly to horizontal mergers. But those assumptions yield no such result. And, if economists would consider such results to be relevant if those models predicted price increases, then they must consider them equally relevant if, as is the case, they do not.

Economically sound antitrust policy must recognize not only the power of economic analysis but also its limits. Economics is not a precise science. If the Agencies are going to base vertical merger enforcement on their models of how a vertical merger will affect static pricing incentives, then one of two things must be the case: One possibility is that predicted price increases are a robust feature of the underlying models—so that at least the qualitative predictions are not particularly sensitive to model details. If they are not, as is the case with vertical mergers, the second possibility is that the available tools for ascertaining the underlying structure of the model and for measuring model parameters are precise and reliable enough to determine whether a particular merger is likely to be anticompetitive.

In the model in Section II, the combination of linear demand and symmetric cross-price effects implies that a vertical merger between the monopolist and either upstream firm would result in price decreases. As a result, for a model to predict price increases from a vertical merger, it would have to entail either asymmetric cross-price effects or non-linearities in demand; and these features would have to be results, not assumptions.Footnote 31 This is problematic for two reasons: First, it would seem to be rare that it will be possible to measure the demand relationships sufficiently precisely to conclude with the degree of confidence that the Agencies must demonstrate in court that price increases are likely. Second, even if the measurement tools were available, a policy in which the legality of a vertical merger turns on the relative size of cross-price effects or non-linearities in demand is not sufficiently transparent to businesses or to courts.Footnote 32

3.2 Vertical Upward Pricing Pressure

One of the (relatively) recent developments in the review of horizontal mergers is the use of “Upward Pricing Pressure” (“UPP”).Footnote 33 The insight behind UPP is that the effect of a horizontal merger between Firm A and Firm B on static pricing incentives is to add a marginal opportunity cost to the first order condition with respect to each price. More specifically, that opportunity cost in the first order condition for the price of Good A equals the diversion ratio from Good B to Good A multiplied by the price–cost margin on Good B.

UPP is a short-cut relative to complete merger simulation. The shift in a first-order condition is one element of a horizontal merger simulation; but UPP leaves out the simultaneous solution of the multiple first-order conditions for the merged firm as well as any reactions by other competitors and the effect of those reactions on the post-merger equilibrium. There are two key rationales for relying on UPP, and they both have to hold for UPP to be a useful tool in the review of horizontal mergers: First, the other elements of full merger simulation must be difficult to measureFootnote 34; and, second, the qualitative results—and, ideally, the approximate quantitative results—of a full merger simulation must not be sensitive to those additional details.

Moresi and Salop (2013) have observed that vertical mergers create a similar effect on the first order conditions with respect to prices. Suppose Firm U is an upstream monopolist supplier of an input to two firms: A and B. If A and U merge and one compares the pre- and post-merger first-order conditions with respect to the price of Good A, the latter contains an additional term that is equal to the diversion ratio from B to A multiplied by the merged firm’s margin on the upstream good. From this, Moresi and Salop argue that the distinction that many economists draw between the economic effects of horizontal and vertical mergers is artificial.

Despite the similarity between horizontal and vertical upward pricing pressure, the rationale for relying on UPP in the evaluation of horizontal mergers does not apply to vertical mergers and, in fact, is a reason why vertical upward pricing pressure has at most limited use for vertical merger enforcement. To be sure, the first of the necessary conditions does apply. The additional details that are needed for full merger simulation are difficult to measure. But both of the necessary conditions are indeed necessary, and the qualitative results of a vertical merger simulation do in general depend on the additional details.Footnote 35As a result, when an Agency challenges a vertical merger based on its prediction of price increases resulting from the merger, that prediction might prove to be fragile with respect to alternative plausible assumptions.Footnote 36

3.3 Structural Analysis

The 1968 Merger Guidelines laid out structural criteria that were based on concentration ratios and the market shares of the merging parties for both horizontal and vertical mergers. Remarkably, the structural conditions that they laid out for challenging vertical mergers were nearly as restrictive as those for challenging horizontal mergers.Footnote 37

Even though the cross-sectional structure-performance studies of the 1950s and 1960s fell out of favor among academic economists, structural analysis continues to play a role in horizontal merger enforcement. Even the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines state structural criteria that affect the likelihood that the Agencies will challenge a horizontal merger.Footnote 38 Data that the FTC publishes about its merger review confirm that structural criteria are strong predictors of agency actions.Footnote 39 US case law entails a “structural presumption” that mergers of firms with significant market shares in highly concentrated markets are anticompetitive. A reliance on structural criteria in merger enforcement has persisted because it makes merger policy more transparent to businesses, antitrust counsel, and courts.

Economic theory provides support for the proposition that the static pricing incentives created by horizontal mergers of firms with significant market shares is to increase prices, and that theory is part of the justification for the role of market structure in horizontal merger enforcement. There is no such economic theory to support a structural presumption for vertical mergers that is based on static pricing incentives. Even when there is duopoly at one stage and monopoly at the other, economic theory simply does not predict that the static pricing incentives that are created by a vertical merger are necessarily to increase any price, much less to result in a reduction in consumer surplus.

One might hypothesize that even if there can be no general structural presumption in the duopoly-monopoly case, there might be one based on the market share of the firm at the duopoly stage. For example, one might imagine a structural presumption if a dominant firm at one stage seeks to merge with a firm with at least a 60% share at an adjacent stage. But economic theory provides no foundation for such a rule either. Asymmetry in market shares does not imply the asymmetry in cross-price effects that would be needed with linear demands to generate predictions of price increases from a vertical merger.

Moreover, suppose that the legality of a vertical merger in the monopoly-duopoly setting turned on the share of the firm in the duopoly. It is not clear that it would be the merger with the bigger firm that would be objectionable. As the share of the larger firm approaches 100%, the industry would approach successive monopoly; and a model of the static pricing incentives that are created by a vertical merger would predict price reductions. And, suppose that with duopoly shares of 75% and 25%, economic theory predicted price increases from a merger between the monopolist and the smaller firm and price decreases from a merger between the monopolist and the larger firm. Would anyone other than professional economists endorse an antitrust rule that would permit the monopolist at one stage to purchase a large firm at an adjacent stage but not a smaller one?

This latter point about the need for antitrust enforcement to conform with common sense is not limited to structural presumptions. It applies equally to more complicated, less transparent approaches to enforcement. If the methodologies that the Agencies use to analyze vertical mergers would lead to clearance of a merger between a monopolist and a firm at an adjacent stage with a 75% share but would not permit the same monopolist to merger with the smaller firm at the adjacent stage, the underlying policy is equally problematic. Whatever approach or approaches the Agencies plan to use—and the VMG do not make clear what they are—I am not aware of any analysis that the Agencies could rely on to justify structural conditions that are likely to give rise to a vertical merger challenge.Footnote 40

4 Potential Competition as an Economically Sound Basis for Vertical Merger Enforcement

In arguing that the theory of how vertical mergers affect static pricing incentives does not suggest any basis for a structural presumption, I am not arguing against a structural presumption with respect to vertical mergers. But static pricing incentives cannot provide the basis for such a presumption.Footnote 41

Another possible basis for a structural presumption is the threat of entry (or commitment to help entrants and/or small competitors remain viable and expand). One of the challenges that the Agencies have in justifying merger challenges that are based on potential entry is that a merger reduces the competitive effect of potential entry only if one of the parties is the most likely or one of a small number of likely entrants into the other’s markets. This can be difficult to prove, since the Agencies (and the firms themselves) often cannot confidently identify the entire set of potential entrants. In cases of successive dominance, however, since the dominant firm at one stage benefits from competition at the adjacent stage,Footnote 42 it has an additional incentive (relative to other potential entrants) to enter or help other firms enter the adjacent stage. This theory of potential harm from a vertical merger is robust with respect to assumptions about the functional form of demand or the precise nature of game-theoretic interaction either between or within stages. It does not even require that double marginalization results in consumer prices that exceed the joint profit-maximizing price.Footnote 43

An example of a vertical merger that should have been (and was) challenged on potential competition grounds was Time Warner’s 1996 purchase of Turner Broadcasting: Time Warner’s cable systems were dominant distributors in their service territories, and CNN (which was owned by Turner) was the dominant cable news network. At the time, MS-NBC and Fox News threatened CNN’s dominance. Without the merger, Time Warner would have benefited from extra competition in cable news. The merger with Turner gave Time Warner an incentive to block the new entrants.Footnote 44

Another example of vertical merger that should have been (and was) challenged on potential competition grounds was TicketMaster’s 2010 purchase of LiveNation. Ticketmaster was (and remains) the dominant provider of ticketing services for concerts, and LiveNation was the largest promoter of concerts. LiveNation was not only a potential entrant into ticketing – it had already started entering.Footnote 45

Both of these cases were settled with consent agreements. One might question whether the consents provided adequate relief and, if not, whether the mergers should have been blocked rather than cleared with conditions. But the focus of the VMG is on what vertical mergers the Agencies are likely to challenge—not on the appropriate remedies. The VMG do cite potential competition as a possible theory for blocking a vertical merger, but the emphasis that this theory receives in these guidelines is less than it receives in the 1984 Merger Guidelines.

5 Conclusions—A Key Question to Answer

If the VMG provide clarity to businesses, antitrust practitioners, and courts, one should be able to answer the following question: Name two companies that, based on the VMG, cannot engage in a vertical merger and what is the economic principle underlying why?

In the case of horizontal mergers, answering this question is simple: The Coca-Cola Company and PepsiCo cannot merge. Apple and Microsoft cannot merge. Neither can Apple and Google. Probably—although given past U.S. agency enforcement with respect to airlines, it is less clear—Delta Airlines and United Airlines cannot merge. The underlying economic principle is the prisoner’s dilemma applied to actions by competing firms. When one firm takes actions such as a price cut or product improvement to increase its sales, it generally takes business from its competitors. When a sufficiently large fraction of the increased sales would be diverted from the proposed merger partner, then the merger dulls the incentive to behave competitively. The ability to predict how the Agencies will respond to a horizontal merger is not limited to mergers to monopoly. “Three-to-twos”Footnote 46 are likely to be challenged. “Seven-to-sixes” are usually legal.

One can answer the question based on the section on vertical mergers from the DOJ 1984 Merger Guidelines. Whether or not the requisite structural conditions are still present, there was a time when Microsoft’s position in personal computer operating systems and productivity software and Intel’s position in microprocessors for personal computers were dominant to the point of nearly being monopolies. A merger between them likely would have resulted in EDM and, therefore, downward static pricing pressure. Yet, each had a strong incentive to promote entry in the other’s market. Microsoft had an incentive to see ADM—Intel’s main competitor—succeed; and Intel was a major sponsor of Linux: an open-source operating system that threatened Microsoft’s Windows. The rationale for blocking such a merger would be potential competition—not static pricing incentives; and it is a challenge that one could predict based on the 1984 Merger Guidelines.

Because the VMG include potential competition as a possible theory for blocking a vertical merger and because challenges that are based on static pricing incentives are going to be difficult to prove, the VMG are unlikely to have much of an effect on what mergers the Agencies successfully block. But by focusing on static pricing incentives rather than potential competition, they muddy the waters instead of clarifying them.