Skip to main content
Log in

Bid Roundness Under Collusion in Japanese Procurement Auctions

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze the “roundness level” of bids—defined as the number of zeros at the end of the bid—in public procurement auctions for construction works in Okinawa Prefecture, Japan, where a bid-rigging case was filed. We hypothesize that bid rigging increases the roundness of bids through the bid coordination process. Specifically, winners choose round numbers to avoid any miscommunication when they announce their planned bids to other ring members, and losers prefer round numbers when they arbitrarily bid above the winning bid. We find that (1) there is a positive relationship between the roundness of a bid and its relative value as a fraction of the reserve price, (2) the roundness of bids is higher when collusion is active than when it is inactive, (3) among the ring bids, the roundness of the lowest bids is even higher than that of the other bids, and (4) bids by non-ring members are also round when collusion is active.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, see Genesove and Mullin (2001), Porter (1983) and Roller and Steen (2006).

  2. Porter and Zona (1993), Bajari and Ye (2003) and Abrantes-Metz et al. (2006) provide methods for detecting bid rigging, and Pesendorfer (2000), Asker (2010) and Ishii (2008, 2009) focus on the mechanism by which the bidding ring rotates wins among its members.

  3. See Schindler and Kibarian (1996) and Anderson and Simester (2003).

  4. Kandel et al. (2001) and Klumpp et al. (2007) report the existence of preferences for round numbers.

References

  • Abrantes-Metz, R. M., Froeb, L. M., Geweke, J. F., & Taylor, C. T. (2006). A variance screen for collusion. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 467–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E. T., & Simester, D. I. (2003). Effects of \(\$9\) price endings on retail sales: Evidence from field experiments. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 1(1), 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asker, J. (2010). A study of the internal organization of a bidding cartel. American Economic Review, 100(3), 724–762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bajari, P., & Ye, L. (2003). Deciding between competition and collusion. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 971–989.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramton, P., & Schwartz, J. A. (2000). Collusive bidding: Lessons from the FCC spectrum auctions. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 17(3), 229–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramton, P. & Schwartz, J. A. (2002). Collusive bidding in the FCC spectrum auctions. Contributions to Economic Analysis and Policy, 1, article 11.

  • Genesove, D., & Mullin, W. P. (2001). Rules, communication, and collusion: Narrative evidence from the sugar institute case. American Economic Review, 91(3), 379–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishii, R. (2008). Collusion in repeated procurement auction: A study of a paving market in Japan. ISER Discussion Paper No. 710, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University.

  • Ishii, R. (2009). Favor exchange in collusion: Empirical study of repeated procurement auctions in Japan. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27(2), 137–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, C., Pennacchi, G., & Sopranzetti, B. (1999). Bank deposit rate clustering: Theory and empirical evidence. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2185–2214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kandel, S., Sarig, O., & Wohl, A. (2001). Do investors prefer round stock prices? Evidence from Israeli IPO auctions. Journal of Banking and Finance, 25(8), 1543–1551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klumpp, J. M., Brorsen, B. W., & Anderson, K. B. (2007). Producers’ preferences for round number prices. Agricultural Finance Review, 67(2), 377–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreul, L. M. (1982). Magic numbers: Psychological aspects of menu pricing. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 23, 70–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesendorfer, M. (2000). A study of collusion in first-price auctions. Review of Economic Studies, 67(3), 381–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, R. H. (1983). A study of cartel stability: The joint executive committee, 1880–1886. Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2), 301–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, R. H., & Zona, J. D. (1993). Detecting of bid rigging in procurement auctions. Journal of Political Economy, 101(3), 518–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roller, L.-H., & Steen, F. (2006). On the working of a cartel: Evidence from the Norwegian cement industry. American Economic Review, 96(1), 321–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schindler, R. M., & Kibarian, T. M. (1996). Increased consumer sales response through use of 99-ending prices. Journal of Retailing, 72(2), 187–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Masaki Aoyagi, Kazuo Ogawa and Fumio Ohtake for helpful suggestions and discussions. I also thank seminar participants for comments. The comments of Lawrence J. White (Editor) and two anonymous referees were extremely useful in the revision process. Any errors are mine. This work was supported by JSPS Grant-in-Aid Numbers 22730204, 22243022.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rieko Ishii.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ishii, R. Bid Roundness Under Collusion in Japanese Procurement Auctions. Rev Ind Organ 44, 241–254 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9408-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9408-6

Keywords

Navigation