Skip to main content
Log in

Can capacity markets be designed by democracy?

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the United States, Regional Transmission Organizations (RTOs) operate the power grid serving nearly 70% of electricity customers and are critical organizations for ensuring reliable system operations and facilitating the integration of new technologies and market participants. RTOs are designed to be stakeholder-driven organizations, with rules and policies crafted through a highly participatory process. While the decisions that RTOs make have implications for industry, society and the environment, their decision processes have not been modeled in any systematic way. In this paper, we develop a modeling framework for the stakeholder process of PJM, an RTO serving thirteen states plus the District of Columbia, adapting some of the seminal literature from political science and political economy on the theory of voting systems. This modeling framework can generate predictions of stakeholder process outcomes, identify strong coalitions among stakeholders and identify shifts in political power in the formulation of RTO market rules. We illustrate this analysis framework using a detailed data set from stakeholder deliberations of capacity market reform in PJM. Our model predicts that the current structure of the stakeholder process in PJM makes the passage of capacity market reforms through the stakeholder process virtually impossible because it creates strong coalitions that would favor or oppose changes to capacity market rules. In the capacity market case, we also identify a small subset of voters that act as swing voters and confirm that political power is shifted to these voters by deviations from otherwise strong coalitions and abstentions from the voting process altogether. Our framework represents the first attempt to model the decision-making behavior of RTOs in any systematic way, and points towards emerging research needs in evaluating the governance structure of RTOs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Reproduced with permission from Blumsack et al. (2017), PJM (2015b)

Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Source: Author calculations based on Pfeifenberger et al. (2014)

Fig. 7

Source: Author calculations based on Pfeifenberger et al. (2014)

Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The concept of the critical voter is similar to that of a pivotal supplier in electricity market power analysis (Blumsack et al. 2002; Brandts et al. 2014; Mayes et al. 2012). A power producer is considered as a pivotal supplier if the demand cannot be met without its capacity.

  2. Given how close the Status Quo package was to Package 11, as shown in Fig. 7, it is somewhat surprising that the voting scores for Status Quo and Package 11 are so different. Why this was is not clear, although Yoo (2016) point out that there was broad dissatisfaction with the capacity market construct at the time that these votes were taken.

  3. This may sound like a strong assumption. Johnson, et al. (2015) offer some qualitative and anecdotal evidence in support of the notion that stakeholder discussions on different market products tended to be focused on those products rather than on spillover effects into other market products.

  4. We consider only when the clearing price is settled between point a and b because it was the area of concern of the proposals at the moment of votes were taken. Therefore, \( 0 \le\upalpha \le 4 \).

References

Download references

Funding

Funding was provided by the U.S. National Science Foundation under Award Number SBE-1261867.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Seth Blumsack.

Appendix

Appendix

Consider abstention from sector B (a B ). Then, the threshold condition considering a B is Eq. (A-1).

$$ \frac{{X_{B} }}{{\textit{TN}_{B} - a_{B} }} + \frac{{X_{A} }}{{\textit{TN}_{A} }} > 1.665 - \mathop \sum \limits_{i \in C\backslash A,B} w_{i, j} $$
(A-1)

Y-intercept (I B ) and X-intercept (I A ) of this inequality condition with the abstention (a B ) are:

$$ I_{B} = \left( {\textit{TN}_{B} - a_{B} } \right)\left( {1.665 - \mathop \sum \limits_{i \in C\backslash A,B} w_{i, j} } \right)\quad I_{A} = \textit{TN}_{A} \left( {1.665 - \mathop \sum \limits_{i \in C\backslash A,B} w_{i, j} } \right) $$
(A-2)

From Eq. (5), we know that Y-intercept (\( I_{B}^{{\prime }} \)) and X-intercept (\( I_{A}^{{\prime }} \)) of the inequality condition without abstention are:

$$ I_{B}^{{\prime }} = \textit{TN}_{B} \left( {1.665 - \mathop \sum \limits_{i \in C\backslash A,B} w_{i, j} } \right)\quad I_{A}^{{\prime }} = \textit{TN}_{A} \left( {1.665 - \mathop \sum \limits_{i \in C\backslash A,B} w_{i, j} } \right) $$
(A-3)

Since \( I_{A} = I_{A}^{{\prime }} \), we check that abstention (a B ) rotates the threshold line anchored to an intercept (I A ).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yoo, K., Blumsack, S. Can capacity markets be designed by democracy?. J Regul Econ 53, 127–151 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-018-9354-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-018-9354-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation