Skip to main content
Log in

Access regulation and the transition from copper to fiber networks in telecoms

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we study the impact of different forms of access obligations on firms’ incentives to migrate from the legacy copper network to next generation broadband infrastructures. We analyze geographically differential access prices of copper (that depend on whether or not an alternative fiber network has been deployed in the area) and ex-ante access obligations for fiber networks. We discuss how these regulatory schemes fare in addressing the tension among different objectives, such as the promotion of static efficiency, fostering investments in new infrastructures, and avoiding unnecessary duplication of (fiber) networks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Czernich et al. (2011).

  2. More specifically, the EC has set 30 Mbps as a minimum level of broadband connection that should be available to all EU citizens by 2013. As a longer term target, the EC has defined 100 Mbps as the minimum level of broadband connection that at least half of the EU households should have access to by 2020.

  3. Currently, 7.2 % of all fixed lines provide speeds over 30 Mbps, and only 1.3% over 100Mbps.

  4. Similar concerns have been raised by Crandall et al. (2013). The potential impact of access policies in the transition from copper to fiber networks is also acknowledged by the EC; see the EU Recommendation C(2010) 6223 on “Regulated Access to NGANs” (September 2010). In December 2012 the EC presented a new draft of recommendation stating that the access prices of the traditional copper networks should remain stable over the coming years in order to sustain investment in next-generation network by both incumbent and entrant firms (European Commission, 2012; paragraphs 44 and 45).

  5. In New Zealand, for example, the copper and fiber access prices are also set by different regulators (i.e., the national regulatory authority and the government).

  6. See for example, Gans and Williams (1999),Gans (2001), Foros (2004), Bourreau and Doğan (2005), Hori and Mizuno (2006), Hori and Mizuno (2009); Kotakorpi (2006) and Vareda and Hoernig (2010). These papers explore the impact of the access scheme on investment, when the investment decisions are “zero-one” in nature.

  7. See also Brito et al. (2012) who focus on the nature of innovation, which can be either drastic or non-drastic. Bourreau et al. (2012a) provide a review of the literature, with a particular focus on the process of migration from the legacy to the next generation infrastructures, and discuss the possibility of geographical access regulation.

  8. See Appendix H and Cullen International (2013).

  9. Bourreau et al. (2012) only briefly touches this question within a specified competitive setting.

  10. The analysis provided by Bourreau et al. (2012), which does not consider regulation of the fiber network, constitutes our benchmark case in this paper.

  11. This sequence of moves reflects the idea that incumbent firms may have specific advantages in the deployment of fiber. For example, in many countries, the ducts that are necessary to roll out fiber networks are owned by the incumbent operator. Besides, as the incumbents own and operate the copper network, they have detailed information about consumers’ location, etc., which the entrant operators do not necessarily have. Computations for the equilibria of the coverage subgame when firms move simultaneously and when the entrant moves first are available upon request. The qualitative nature of our main results do not change with the modifications in the timing.

  12. We assume away any investment costs for linking each consumer to the network.

  13. We solved the coverage subgame when firms can decide whether or not to deploy fiber in any area \(z\in \left[ 0,\overline{z}\right] \) (under uniform access pricing). The equilibrium is characterized with the same global coverage and the same level of infrastructure duplication as in our main model. The difference between the two coverage equilibria is that in the former, the ownership of fiber infrastructure in partially covered areas (i.e., monopoly fiber infrastructure) is split between the incumbent and the entrant, whereas it all belongs to the entrant in the latter. The computations for this alternative coverage subgame are available upon request from the authors.

  14. Allowing for negative values of \(\tau \) avoids corner solutions where all consumers purchase one of the two firms’ services. Note also that although fiber roll-out in market \(z\) gives the firm an ability to reach all customers in that market, not all customers end up buying broadband access, i.e., fiber coverage in market \(z\) does not imply market coverage in \(z\).

  15. That is, for \(i=1,2\), we have \(\pi _{i}^{O,N}>0\), and \( \pi _{i}^{N,O}(a)>0\) for \(a\) not too high.

  16. The profits in the last stage of the game for each industry configuration (1–3) can be found in Appendix A. In Appendix B, we provide the properties of the profit functions.

  17. There is also a potential asymmetric corner equilibrium. However, to simplify the exposition, we focus on the interior equilibria. Though there are multiple candidate equilibria, the equilibrium is always unique.

  18. When the entrant moves first, we find that the coverage subgame has the same two potential interior equilibra, so the qualitative nature of our main results remain unchanged. When firms move simultaneously, we have multiple equilibria, which complicates the regulator’s decision.

  19. See Proposition 1 in Bourreau et al. (2012).

  20. We also solved the model for the case where there is no access to copper. This case yields the highest fiber coverage in equilibrium, but the lowest per-area welfare due to the absence of service-based competition. The computations are available upon request.

  21. This result is provided as an example by Bourreau et al. (2012) in Lemma 4.

  22. See for example Crandall et al. (2004) and Waverman et al. (2007).

  23. A higher quality can be attained through investments in technologies such as vectoring, which increases the speed of broadband services on copper significantly.

  24. See Appendix C for the proof.

  25. In countries where the deployment of the vectoring technology (or of similar technologies) are subject to the regulator’s authorization, the regulators should bare this consequence in mind.

  26. Directive 2009/140/EC (“Better Regulation Directive”, recital 7) explicitly considers the possibility of defining different geographical markets and remedies according to the prevailing competitive conditions.

  27. Bourreau et al. (2012b) study geographical access rules that apply to the fiber network, without considering access to copper.

  28. When the entrant builds a larger fiber network, it leases access to the copper network only in the areas where the incumbent also uses the copper technology, and hence, there is no room for differential access pricing. See Appendix E where we determine the coverage equilibrium, and show that when the entrant dominates fiber roll-out, coverage depends only on the access charge in the uncovered areas.

  29. Note that the “global” social optimum can also be achieved with a configuration where the incumbent does not dominate the fiber investments.

  30. In our setting, the benefits of (fiber) network duplication are due to higher quality of services and more intense (facility-based) competition. There may be other benefits of duplication including the elimination of admistrative problems related to access provision.

  31. See Appendix F for the signs of the different terms in (6) and (7).

  32. When \(a^{N}\) is very small, \(w^{N,O}(a^{N})\) is high and \(c(z_{1}^{m})\) is small as there is little investment. Therefore, \( w^{N,O}(a^{N})-w^{O,O}(a^{O})-c(z_{1}^{m})\) is likely to be positive. Conversely, when \(a^{N}\) is high, \(w^{N,O}(a^{N})\) is low and \(c(z_{1}^{m})\) is high. Therefore, \(w^{N,O}(a^{N})-w^{O,O}(a^{O})-c(z_{1}^{m})\) is likely to be negative. Since \(w^{N,O}(a^{N})-w^{O,O}(a^{O})-c(z_{1}^{m})\) decreases with \(a^{N}\), it is possible to find the \(a^{N}\) that makes it equal to zero.

  33. In Appendix H we report a snapshot of the current regulatory framework and wholesale broadband remedies on Next Generation Access regulation in selected OECD countries.

  34. Access is required in the areas where a firm holds a monopoly in the fiber. For example, for a given location where the incumbent has fiber coverage, the incumbent is required to provide to access to the entrant only if the entrant has no fiber coverage in that area.

  35. See Appendix G1.

  36. This is because the wholesale migration condition when the entrant dominates fiber investments is \(\widetilde{a}\le \widetilde{a} _{1}^{\max }=s^{N}-s^{O}\), and it is \(\widetilde{a}\le \widetilde{a} _{2}^{\max }\left( a\right) =s^{N}-s^{O}+a\) otherwise.

  37. The entrant’s and the incumbent’s equilibrium investment decisions can be found in Appendix G2.

  38. The proof of this result is available upon request. The intuition is rather straightforward; there are fewer regulatory tools than the regulatory objectives.

  39. In some countries, the regulator may be politically or administratively constrained by the existing copper access rules. For example, in the EU, the Commission ruled that the existing copper access schemes should remain unchanged (for details, see the EU document on Telecommunications single market in EU, September 11th, 2013; http://ec.europa.eu/digital-agenda/en/news/communication-commission-european-parliament-council-european-economic-and-social-committee-a-0).

  40. See Appendix G3 for the proof. Note that this result holds if the marginal investment cost is convex, and it does not necessarily hold when the marginal investment cost is concave.

  41. This holds when the marginal investment cost is convex. See Appendix G3 for the formal proofs.

  42. In some European countries, such as Belgium and the Netherlands, there is an on-going debate on whether the incumbents that move from copper to fiber should be imposed to switch off the former.

  43. Note that the switch-off of copper is relevant only under the industry configuration (4) and when incumbent dominates fiber investements.

  44. In this example, when \(a>0.35\), we have a corner equilibrium where the incumbent invests more. In this case, we find that \(\widetilde{a}^{w}\) first increases then decreases with \(a\).

  45. We obtained similar results with other values for \( \overline{z}\). Note that \(k\) plays a limited role in these simulations; it is mainly a scaling factor for the equilibrium investments.

  46. This is true as long as differential pricing differs from uniform pricing, i.e., \( a^{N}\ne a^{O}\). Note that when \(s^{N}=1.2\), the schemes are identical as the regulator sets \(a^{N}=a^{O}=0\).

  47. We have checked the robustness of these results by running simulations for a larger set of parameters \(s^{O}\in \left\{ 0.5,0.6,...,1.0\right\} \) and \(s^{N}\in \left\{ s^{O}+0.1,s^{O}+0.2,...,\overline{s}^{N}\left( s^{O}\right) \right\} \), with \(\overline{s}^{N}\left( s^{O}\right) =\min \left\{ 1+2s^{O},(1+5s^{O})/4\right\} \).

  48. We also simulated the equilibrium when there are no access requirements (neither to copper nor to fiber), that is, when the only way to enter the market is by investing in fiber. As one can expect, this case yields even a higher fiber coverage than with fiber access, but social welfare is lower than in all other cases. This is because the welfare gains from larger fiber coverage is offset by reduced welfare in uncovered areas due to the elimination of competition.

  49. Note that, even though fiber access yields the highest social welfare, the variation of welfare under different regimes is not significant. This is because for a given \(s^{N}\), the variation in equilibrium fiber coverage under different regimes is relatively small (for example, it varies between 7 and \(9\%\) for \(s^{N}=1.1\), and between \(35\% \) and \(42\%\) for \(s^{N}=1.4\), as full coverage is set at \(\overline{z}=4\)), and the access price to copper in the uncovered areas is the same under all regimes (set at marginal cost).

  50. For larger values \( s^{N}\), we have a corner equilibrium defined by (\(z_{1}^{c},\widehat{z}_{1}\) ).

  51. As in the baseline model, there is also a corner asymmetric equilibrium. We focus however on the interior equilibria.

  52. Note that in Italy and in the UK the physical unbundling of fiber connections is not allowed. However, national regulators are implementing an equivalent wholesale service that corresponds to a “virtual” (and not physical) wholesale connection to final customers. This wholesale service is known as VULA (Virtual Unbundled Local Access). For further details on NGA remedies, see also Bourreau et al. (2010).

References

  • Bourreau, M., & Doğan, P. (2005). Unbundling the local loop. European Economic Review, 49, 173–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourreau, M., & Doğan, P. (2006). Build-or-Buy strategies in the local loop. American Economic Review, 96, 72–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourreau, M., Cambini, C., & Doğan, P. (2012). Access pricing, competition, and incentives to migrate from “Old” to “New” technology. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30(6), 713–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourreau, M., Cambini, C., & Hoernig, S. (2012a). Exante regulation and co-investment in the transition to next generation access. Telecommunications Policy, 36(5), 399–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourreau, M., Cambini, C., & Hoernig, S. (2012b). Geographical access rules and investments. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 9013.

  • Brito, D., Pereira, P., & Vareda, J. (2012). Incentives to invest and to give access to non regulated new technologies. Information Economics and Policy, 24(3–4), 197–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crandall, R. W., Ingraham, A. T., & Singer, H. J. (2004). Do unbundling policies discourage CLEC facilities-based investment? Topics in Economic Analysis and Policy, 4(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crandall, R., Eisenach, J. A., & Ingraham, A. T. (2013). The long-run effects of copper-loop unbundling and the implications for fiber. Telecommunications Policy, 37, 262–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cullen International. (2013). Report on NGN deployment and regulatory issues. Brussels: Cullen International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Czernich, N., Falck, O., Kretschmer, T., & Woessmann, L. (2011). Broadband infrastructure and economic growth. The Economic Journal, 121, 505–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission - DG Info. (2012). Digital agenda scorecard 2012: Fast and ultra-fast internet access. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foros, Ø. (2004). Strategic investments with spillovers, vertical integration and foreclosure in the broadband access market. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22, 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J., & Williams, P. (1999). Access regulation and the timing of infrastructure investment. The Economic Record, 75(229), 127–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J. (2001). Regulating private infrastructure investment: optimal pricing for access to essential facilities. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 20(2), 167–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J. (2007). Access pricing and infrastructure investment. In J. Haucap & R. Dewenter (Eds.), Access pricing: Theory and practice. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haydock, J., Langus, G., Lipatov, V., Neven, D., & Shier, G. (2012). Costing methodologies and incentives to invest in fibre. Prepared for DG information society and media—European Commission. London: Charles River Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hori, K., & Mizuno, K. (2006). Access pricing and investment with stochastically growing demand. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 705–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hori, K., & Mizuno, K. (2009). Competition schemes and investment in network infrastructure. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 35, 179–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderst, R., & Peitz, M. (2012). Market asymmetries and investments in NGA. Review of Network Economics, 11(1), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., & Shapiro, C. (1985). Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. American Economic Review, 75, 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotakorpi, K. (2006). Access price regulation, investment and entry in telecommunications. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1013–1020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ovum. (2013). Regulating NGA: Remedies in wholesale broadband access. London.

  • Plum. (2011). Costing methodology and the transition to next generation access. Report for ETNO. London.

  • Valletti, T. M., Hoernig, S., & Barros, P. D. (2002). Universal service and entry: The role of uniform pricing and coverage constraints. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 21(2), 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vareda, J., & Hoernig, S. (2010). Racing for investment under mandatory access. The BE Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 10(1), 34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waverman, L., Meschi, M., Reillier, B., & Dasgupta, K. (2007). Access regulation and infrastructure investment in the telecommunications sector: An empirical investigation. LECG Report. http://www.etno.be/Portals/34/ETNO%20Documents/LECG_Final_Report.pdf.

  • WIK. (2011). Wholesale Pricing. Report for ECTA, April, Bad Honnef, Germany: NGA Take-Up and Competition.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the Editor, Michael Crew, and two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank Keizo Mizuno and participants at the 13th ACCC Regulatory Conference 2012 in Brisbane (AUS), and at the workshop “Public Intervention and Regulation” held in Capri (2012). Marc Bourreau acknowledges financial support from Orange. Carlo Cambini acknowledges financial support from the Italian Ministry of Education (No. 20089PYFHY_004).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlo Cambini.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Appendix A: Profits (per-area) for industry configurations (1) - (3)

Let \(s_{i}\) denote firm \(i\)’s quality, with \(s_{i}\in \left\{ s^{O},s^{N}\right\} \), and \(i=1,2\).

(1) Service-based competition within the copper network.

We have \(s_{1}=s_{2}=s^{O}\). The incumbent’s profit is \( \pi _{1}^{O,O}=p_{1}q_{1}+aq_{2}\), and the entrant’s profit is \( \pi _{2}^{O,O}=(p_{2}-a)q_{2}\). In the equilibrium of the quantity-setting game, we have \(\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) =\left( (1+s^{O})^{2}+5a\left( 1-a\right) +5as^{O}\right) /9\) and \(\pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a\right) =(1+s^{O}-2a)^{2}/9\). Note that \(\pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a\right) \ge 0\) if and only if \(a\le \overline{a}^{O}=\left( 1+s^{O}\right) /2\). Besides, the incumbent’s gross profit is maximized at \(\widehat{a}^{O}=\arg \underset{a}{ \max }\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) =(1+s^{O})/2=\overline{a}^{O}\).

(2) Infrastructure-based competition between the copper and the fiber networks.

i. The incumbent uses its copper network and the entrant uses its own fiber network.

We have \(s_{1}=s^{O}\) and \(s_{2}=s^{N}\). The incumbent’s profit is \(\pi _{1}^{O,N}=p_{1}q_{1}\), and the entrant’s profit is \( \pi _{2}^{O,N}=p_{2}q_{2}\). In equilibrium, we have \( \pi _{1}^{O,N}=(1+2s^{O}-s^{N})^{2}/9\) and \(\pi _{2}^{O,N}=(1+2s^{N}-s^{O})^{2}/9 \).

ii. The incumbent uses a fiber network and the entrant uses the incumbent’s copper network.

We have \(s_{1}=s^{N}\) and \(s_{2}=s^{O}\). The incumbent’s profit is \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}=p_{1}q_{1}+aq_{2}\), and the entrant’s profit is \( \pi _{2}^{N,O}=(p_{2}-a)q_{2}\). In equilibrium, we have \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) =((1+2s^{N}-s^{O})^{2}+5a\left( 1-a\right) +a(s^{N}+4s^{O}))/9\) and \(\pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a\right) =(1+2s^{O}-s^{N}-2a)^{2}/9\). Note that \( \pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a\right) \ge 0\) if and only if \(a\le \overline{a} ^{N}=\left( 1+2s^{O}-s^{N}\right) /2\), and that \(\overline{a}^{N}<\overline{a }^{O}\) as \(s^{N}>s^{O}\). The incumbent’s gross profit is maximized at \( \widehat{a}^{N}=\arg \underset{a}{\max }\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) =(5+s^{N}+4s^{O})/10>\overline{a}^{N}\).

(3) Infrastructure-based competition between the fiber networks.

We have \(s_{1}=s_{2}=s^{N}\). The incumbent’s profit is \( \pi _{1}^{N,N}=p_{1}q_{1}\), and the entrant’s profit is \( \pi _{2}^{N,N}=p_{2}q_{2}\). In equilibrium, we have \( \pi _{1}^{N,N}=(1+s^{N})^{2}/9\) and \(\pi _{2}^{N,N}=(1+s^{N})^{2}/9\)

1.2 Appendix B: Properties of per-area profits

B1.

From the expressions of profits given in Appendix A, we have \( \partial \pi _{2}^{k,O}\left( a\right) /\partial a\le 0\), for \(k=O,N\). Furthermore, \(\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) \) increases with \(a\), for all \( a\le \widehat{a}^{O}=\overline{a}^{O}\). Similarly, \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) \) increases with \(a\), for all \(a\le \overline{a}^{N}<\widehat{a}^{N} \), as we have \(\partial ^{2}\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) /\partial a^{2}<0\) and \(\partial \pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) /\partial a\left( a=\overline{a} ^{N}\right) =2\left( s^{N}-s^{O}\right) /3>0\).

B2.

First, since \(\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) \) increases with \(a\) for \(a\le \widehat{a}^{O}=\overline{a}^{O}\), we have \(\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) \ge \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( 0\right) =\left( 1+s^{O}\right) ^{2}/9\). Since \(s^{O}<s^{N}\), we have \(\pi _{1}^{O,N}<\left( 1+s^{O}\right) ^{2}/9\), and hence, \(\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) >\pi _{1}^{O,N}\) for all \(a\). Second, since \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) \) increases with \(a\) for all \( a\le \overline{a}^{N}\), we have \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) \ge \pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( 0\right) =(1+2s^{N}-s^{O})^{2}/9\). As \(s^{N}>s^{O}\), we then have \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a\right) >(1+s^{N})^{2}/9=\pi _{1}^{N,N}\).

1.3 Appendix C: Quality of the copper network and the fiber coverage

We study the effect of a higher quality for the copper network, \(s^{O}\), on firms’ investment in fiber. We focus on the two asymmetric equilibria, \(\left\{ z_{2}^{m},z_{1}^{c}\right\} \) if the entrant dominates in fiber investment, and \(\left\{ z_{1}^{m},z_{2}^{c}\right\} \) if it is the incumbent that dominates. We find that \(z_{1}^{c}\), \(z_{1}^{m}\), \(z_{2}^{m}\) , and \(z_{2}^{c}\) decrease with the quality of the copper network, \(s^{O}\). Indeed, \(\partial z_{1}^{c}/\partial s^{O}=\partial (\pi _{1}^{N,N}-\pi _{1}^{O,N})/\partial s^{O}=-4(1+2s^{O}-s^{N\ })/9\le 0\), since \( s^{N}<1+2s^{O}\) from our assumptions. We have \(\partial z_{1}^{m}/\partial s^{O}=\partial (\pi _{1}^{N,O}-\pi _{1}^{O,O})/\partial s^{O}=-\left( a+4+4s^{N}\right) /9\le 0\), and \(\partial z_{2}^{m}/\partial s^{O}=\partial (\pi _{2}^{O,N}-\pi _{2}^{O,O})/\partial s^{O}=-4\left( 1+s^{N}-a\right) /9\le 0\), as \(a\le \overline{a}^{O}\) and \(s^{N}>s^{O}\). Finally, we have \(\partial z_{2}^{c}/\partial s^{O}=\partial (\pi _{2}^{N,N}-\pi _{2}^{N,O})/\partial s^{O}=-4\left( 1+2s^{O}-s^{N}-2a\right) /9\le 0\), since \(a\le \overline{a}^{N}\).

1.4 Appendix D: Social welfare in local areas

D1. Expressions for social welfare.

Recall that \(s_{i}\) is the quality offered by firm \(i\). Consumer surplus is given by \(CS=\int _{\widetilde{\tau }}^{1}\left( \tau - \widehat{p}^{*}\right) d\tau \), where \(\widehat{p}^{*}=p_{1}^{ *}-s_{1}=p_{2}^{*}-s_{2}\) is the quality-adjusted price in the equilibrium of the quantity-setting subgame, and \(\widetilde{\tau }=\widehat{p }^{*}\) is the marginal consumer. We find that \(CS=\left( 2+s_{1}+s_{2}-a\right) ^{2}/18\). The local social welfare is \( w=CS+\pi _{1}+\pi _{2}\), and \(w=\left( 4+4s_{2}+a\right) \left( 2+2s_{2}-a\right) /18+11\left( s_{1}-s_{2}\right) ^{2}/18+4\left( a+1+s_{2}\right) \left( s_{1}-s_{2}\right) /9\).

D2. Variations of local welfare with the copper access price

When there is service-based competition within the copper network, we have \(s_{1}=s_{2}=s^{O}\), and we find that \(\partial w^{O,O}/\partial a=-\left( a+1+s^{O}\right) /9<0\). When firm 1 uses a fiber network and firm 2 uses the copper network, we have \(s_{1}=s^{N}\) and \( s_{2}=s^{O}\), and we find that \(\partial w^{N,O}/\partial a=-\left( a+1+5s^{O}-4s^{N}\right) /9<0\), as \(1+5s^{O}-4s^{N}>0\) under our assumptions on \(s^{N}\).

1.5 Appendix E: Equilibrium coverage with differential access pricing

The entrant’s investment decisionAssume that firm 1 has covered the areas \(\left[ 0,z_{1}\right] \). Firm 2’s profit is then given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{2}(z_{1},z_{2})=-C\left( z_{2}\right) +\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }c} z_{2}\pi _{2}^{N,N}+\left( z_{1}-z_{2}\right) \pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if } z_{2}\le z_{1} \\ z_{1}\pi _{2}^{N,N}+\left( z_{2}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{2}^{O,N}+\left( \overline{z }-z_{2}\right) \pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{2}>z_{1} \end{array} \right. \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Similar to Bourreau et al. (2012), we define \(z_{2}^{c}\left( a^{N}\right) =\left( c\right) ^{-1}\left( \pi _{2}^{N,N}-\pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) \right) \) and \(z_{2}^{m}\left( a^{O}\right) =\left( c\right) ^{-1}\left( \pi _{2}^{O,N}-\pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) \right) \). Note that depending on the values of \(a^{O}\) and \(a^{N}\) we can have either \( z_{2}^{m}(a^{O})>z_{2}^{c}(a^{N})\) or the opposite. If \(z_{2}^{m}>z_{2}^{c}\) , the entrant’s best-response is

$$\begin{aligned} z_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }ll} z_{2}^{m}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}\le \widehat{z}_{1} \\ z_{2}^{c}\left( a^{N}\right) &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}>\widehat{z}_{1} \end{array} \right. \text {,} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\widehat{z}_{1}\left( a^{O},a^{N}\right) \in \left[ z_{2}^{c},z_{2}^{m} \right] \) is the lowest \(z_{1}\) such that \(\Pi _{2}\left( z_{1},z_{2}^{c}\left( a^{N}\right) \right) \ge \Pi _{2}\left( z_{1},z_{2}^{m}\left( a^{O}\right) \right) \). If \(z_{2}^{c}\ge z_{2}^{m}\), the entrant’s best-response is

$$\begin{aligned} z_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l} z_{2}^{m}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}\le z_{2}^{m} \\ z_{1} &{} \text {if} &{} z_{2}^{m}<z_{1}\le z_{2}^{c} \\ z_{2}^{c}\left( a^{N}\right) &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}>z_{2}^{c}\end{array} \right. \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

The incumbent’s investment decisionThe profits of the incumbent in both cases are as follows. If \(z_{2}^{c}<z_{2}^{m}\), firm 1’s profit is given by:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi _{1}(z_{1},z_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) )\\&\quad =-C\left( z_{1}\right) +\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} z_{1}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( z_{2}^{m}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,N}+\left( \overline{z}-z_{2}^{m}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if } z_{1}\in \left[ 0,\widehat{z}_{1}\right] \\ z_{2}^{c}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( z_{1}-z_{2}^{c}\right) \pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{1}\in \left[ \widehat{z}_{1},\overline{z}\right] \end{array} \right. \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

If \(z_{2}^{c}\ge z_{2}^{m}\), firm 1’s profit is given by

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi _{1}(z_{1},z_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) )\\&\quad =-C\left( z_{1}\right) +\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} z_{1}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( z_{2}^{m}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,N}+\left( \overline{z}-z_{2}^{m}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if } z_{1}\in \left[ 0,z_{2}^{m}\right] \\ z_{1}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( \overline{z}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{1}\in \left[ z_{2}^{m},z_{2}^{c}\right] \\ z_{2}^{c}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( z_{1}-z_{2}^{c}\right) \pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{1}\in \left[ z_{2}^{c},\overline{z}\right] \end{array} \right. \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Let \(z_{1}^{c}=\left( c\right) ^{-1}(\pi _{1}^{N,N}-\pi _{1}^{O,N})\), and \( z_{1}^{m}\left( a^{O},a^{N}\right) =\left( c\right) ^{-1}(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) )\). When \(z_{2}^{c}<z_{2}^{m}\) and when \(z_{2}^{c}\ge z_{2}^{m}\), we have the same two potential asymmetric equilibria as in the case with uniform access pricing, and either the incumbent or the entrant dominates fiber investments. That is, the equilibrium coverage is either \(\left\{ z_{1}^{m}\left( a^{O},a^{N}\right) ,z_{2}^{c}\left( a^{N}\right) \right\} \) or \(\left\{ z_{1}^{c},z_{2}^{m}(a^{O})\right\} \)).Footnote 51

1.6 Appendix F: Sign of first-order derivatives of welfare

  1. (i)

    \(\partial z_{1}^{m}/\partial a^{O}<0\), \( \partial z_{1}^{m}/\partial a^{N}>0\) and \(dz_{2}^{c}/da^{N}>0\). Since \(\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) \) increases with \(a^{N}\) and \( \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) \) increases with \(a^{O}\), we have \(\partial z_{1}^{m}/\partial a^{O}<0\) and \(\partial z_{1}^{m}/\partial a^{N}>0\). Since \(\pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) \) decreases with \(a^{N}\), then \( dz_{2}^{c}/da^{N}>0\).

  2. (ii)

    \(w^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) -c\left( z_{1}^{m}\right) \) can be either positive or negative. From the definition of \(z_{1}^{m}\), we have \(c\left( z_{1}^{m}\right) =\pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) \). We find that

    $$\begin{aligned} \Delta _{1}(a^{O},a^{N})&=w^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) -\left( \pi _{1}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -\pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a^{O}\right) \right) \\&=\left( 3\left( a^{N}\right) ^{2}-3\left( a^{O}\right) ^{2}+2a^{N}\left( s^{N}-3s^{O}-2\right) \right. \\&\quad \left. +\left( s^{N}-s^{O}\right) ^{2}+4a^{O}\left( 1+s^{O}\right) \right) /6\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

    We have \(\Delta _{1}(a,a)=(s^{N}-s^{O})(s^{N}-s^{O}+2a)/6>0\). However, we can have \(\Delta _{1}(a^{O},a^{N})<0\) too. For example, assume that \(s^{O}=1\), \( s^{N}=1.2\), then \(\Delta _{1}(0,0.2)<0\).

  3. (iii)

    \(w^{N,N}-w^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -c\left( z_{2}^{c}\right) <0\). From the definition of \(z_{2}^{c}\), we have \(c\left( z_{2}^{c}\right) =\pi _{2}^{N,N}-\pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) \). We find that \(w^{N,N}-w^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -\left( \pi _{2}^{N,N}-\pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) \right) =\left( 3(a^{N})^{2}-2a^{N}\left( 1+s^{O}\right) -\left( s^{N}-s^{O}\right) ^{2}\right) /6\equiv \Delta _{2}\). \( \Delta _{2}\) is a second-degree polynomial with an inverted bell-shape, and we have \(\left. \partial \Delta _{2}/\partial a^{N}\right| _{a^{N}=0}<0\) and \(\Delta _{2}\left( a^{N}=0\right) <0\). Besides, we have \(\Delta _{2}\left( a^{N}=\overline{a}^{N}\right) <0\). Therefore, \(\Delta _{2}<0\) always holds, and hence, \(w^{N,N}-w^{N,O}\left( a^{N}\right) -c\left( z_{2}^{c}\right) <0\).

1.7 Appendix G: Access to fiber

G1. Profits with access to fiber.

When one firm (firm 1 or firm 2) leases access to the fiber network of its rival, both firms offer services of quality \(s^{N}\). Let firm \(i\) be the access provider, and firm \(j\ne i\) be the access seeker, with \( i,j=1,2\). We find that \(\widetilde{\pi }_{i}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) =\left( (1+s^{N})^{2}+5\widetilde{a}(1+s^{N}-\widetilde{a})\right) /9\) and \(\pi _{j}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) =\left( 1+s^{N}-2\widetilde{a} \right) ^{2}/9\). Firm \(j\) has a positive demand if \(\widetilde{a} \le (1+s^{N})/2\). We find that \(\partial \widetilde{\pi }_{i}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) /\partial \widetilde{a}\ge 0\) for \(\widetilde{a} \le (1+s^{N})/2\), and that \(\partial \pi _{j}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) /\partial \widetilde{a}\le 0\).

G2. Equilibrium of the coverage game.

The entrant’s investment decisionGiven firm 1’s coverage \(z_{1}\), firm 2’s profit is

$$\begin{aligned}&\widetilde{\Pi }_{2}\left( z_{1},z_{2}\right) \\&\quad =\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} z_{2}\pi _{2}^{N,N}+\left( z_{1}-z_{2}\right) \pi _{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a }\right) +\left( \overline{z}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( z_{2}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{2}\le z_{1} \\ z_{1}\pi _{2}^{N,N}+\left( z_{2}-z_{1}\right) \widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-z_{2}\right) \pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( z_{2}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{2}>z_{1} \end{array} \right. \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

We define \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\) and \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\) as the values of \(z_{2}\) that maximize the first and second lines of \(\widetilde{\Pi } _{2}\left( z_{1},z_{2}\right) \), respectively, for \(z_{2}\in \left[ 0, \overline{z}\right] \). We have \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a} \right) =\left( c\right) ^{-1}(\pi _{2}^{N,N}-\pi _{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a }\right) )\) and \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) =\left( c\right) ^{-1}(\widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -\pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a\right) )\). Since the wholesale migration condition holds, we have \(\pi _{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \ge \) \( \pi _{2}^{N,O}\left( a\right) \), which implies that \(\widetilde{z} _{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \le z_{2}^{c}\left( a\right) \). Additionally, we have \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) \le z_{2}^{m}\left( a\right) \) as \(\widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \le \pi _{2}^{O,N}\) for all \(\widetilde{a}\le \widetilde{a}_{1}^{\max }\). Finally, we have \(\partial \widetilde{z} _{2}^{c}/\partial \widetilde{a}\), \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}/\partial \widetilde{a}\), \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}/\partial a\ge 0\). That is, increasing the access price to the copper network or to the fiber network increases fiber coverage. The entrant’s best-response function is then

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{z}_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) \!=\! \left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }ll} \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m} &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}\le \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) \\ z_{1} &{} \text {if} &{} \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) <z_{1} \!\le \!\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \\ \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c} &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1} \!>\! \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \end{array} \right. \quad \!\text {and}\quad \widetilde{z}_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) \!=\!\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }ll} \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m} &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}\!\le \!\widetilde{z}_{1}\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) \\ \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c} &{} \text {if} &{} z_{1}\!>\!\widetilde{z}_{1}\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

for \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}>\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\) and \(\widetilde{z} _{2}^{c}\le \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\), respectively, where \(\widetilde{z}_{1}\) is the lowest \(z_{1}\) such that \(\widetilde{\Pi }_{2}\left( z_{1},\widetilde{z }_{2}^{c}\right) \ge \widetilde{\Pi }_{2}\left( z_{1},\widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}\right) \) holds.

The incumbent’s investment decisionIn the case where \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}>\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\), firm 1’s profit is

$$\begin{aligned}&\widetilde{\Pi }_{1}(z_{1},\widetilde{z}_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) )\\&\quad =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} z_{1}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-\widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( z_{1}\right) &{} \text { if }z_{1}\in \left[ 0,\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right] \\ z_{1}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( \overline{z}-z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( z_{1}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{1}\in \left[ \widetilde{z} _{2}^{m},\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\right] \\ \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\pi _{1}^{N,N}+\left( z_{1}-\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\right) \widetilde{\pi }_{1}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) +\left( \overline{z} -z_{1}\right) \pi _{1}^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( z_{1}\right) &{} \text {if }z_{1}\in \left[ \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c},\overline{z}\right] \end{array} \right. \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\widetilde{z}_{1}^{c}\), \(\widetilde{z}_{1}^{d}\) and \(\widetilde{z} _{1}^{m}\) denote the maxima of the first, second, and third lines of \( \widetilde{\Pi }_{1}(z_{1},\widetilde{z}_{2}^{\text {BR}}\left( z_{1}\right) ) \), respectively, for \(z_{1}\in \left[ 0,\overline{z}\right] \). Firm 1’s profit can be written in a similar way for \(\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\le \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\), which yields three maxima for different ranges of values for \(z_{1}\). Similar to the baseline setting, we find two potential asymmetric equilibria, one in which the incumbent invests more than the entrant \(\left( \left\{ \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m},\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\right\} \right) \), and one where it is the entrant that invests more \(\left( \left\{ \widetilde{z} _{1}^{c},\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right\} \right) \).

G3: Regulator’s choice of the access price of fiber.

Consider first the case where the incumbent invests more than the entrant. The equilibrium coverage are \(z_{1}^{*}=\widetilde{z} _{1}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) \) and \(z_{2}^{*}=\widetilde{z} _{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \), and the social welfare is \(W= \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) w^{N,N}+\left( \widetilde{z} _{1}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) -\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \right) w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-\widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) \right) w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\right) -C\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\right) \). Assuming an interior solution, the socially optimal access price of fiber solves

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial W}{\partial \widetilde{a}}&=\frac{d\widetilde{z} _{2}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) }{d\widetilde{a}}\left( w^{N,N}-w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z} _{2}^{c}\right) \right) \\&\quad +\frac{\partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) }{\partial \widetilde{a}}\left( w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{ a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\right) \right) \\&\quad +\left( \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}-\widetilde{z}_{2}^{c}\right) \frac{ dw^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) }{d\widetilde{a}}\equiv G\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) =0\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\widetilde{a}^{w}\) denote the solution of \(G\left( a,\widetilde{a} ^{w}\right) =0\). From the implicit function theorem, provided that the second-order condition holds, the sign of \(\partial \widetilde{a} ^{w}/\partial a\) has the same sign as \(\partial ^{2}W/\partial \widetilde{a} \partial a\). We find that

$$\begin{aligned} \text {sign}\left[ \frac{\partial \widetilde{a}^{w}}{\partial a}\right]&= \text {sign}\left[ \frac{\partial ^{2}W}{\partial \widetilde{a}\partial a} \right] \!=\!\text {sign}\left[ \frac{\partial ^{2}\widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) }{\partial \widetilde{a}\partial a}\left( w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \!-\! w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z} _{1}^{m}\right) \right) \right. \\&-\frac{\partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) }{ \partial \widetilde{a}}\left( \frac{dw^{O,O}\left( a\right) }{da}+\frac{ \partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}}{\partial a}c^{\prime }\left( \widetilde{z} _{1}^{m}\right) \right) +\left. \frac{\partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}}{ \partial a}\frac{dw^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) }{d\widetilde{a}}\right] \text {.} \end{aligned}$$

The second term is positive as \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}/\partial \widetilde{a}\ge 0\), \(dw^{O,O}\left( a\right) /da\le 0\), \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}/\partial a\le 0\) and \(c^{\prime }\left( z\right) \ge 0\) . The third term is also positive as \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}/\partial a\le 0\) and \(dw^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) /d\widetilde{a}\le 0\). If \( w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\right) \ge 0\), the first term is positive if \( \partial ^{2}\widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) /\) \(\partial \widetilde{a}\partial a\ge 0\). We find that

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial ^{2}\widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) }{ \partial \widetilde{a}\partial a}\\&\quad \!=\!\frac{\partial \widetilde{\pi }_{1}^{N,N}}{ \partial \widetilde{a}}\frac{\partial \pi _{1}^{O,O}}{\partial a} c^{\prime \prime }\left[ \left( c\right) ^{-1}\left( \widetilde{\pi } _{1}^{N,N}\!-\!\pi _{1}^{O,O}\right) \right] \Big /\left( c^{\prime }\left[ \left( c\right) ^{-1}\left( \widetilde{\pi }_{1}^{N,N}\!-\!\pi _{1}^{O,O}\right) \right] \right) ^{3}\!\ge \! 0\text {,} \end{aligned}$$

as \(\partial \widetilde{\pi }_{1}^{N,N}/\partial \widetilde{a}\ge 0\), \( \partial \pi _{1}^{O,O}/\partial a\ge 0\), and \(c^{\prime }\ge 0\), and provided that \(c^{\prime \prime }\ge 0\) (i.e., the investment cost is convex). It follows that \(\partial \widetilde{a}^{w}/\partial a\ge 0\). Finally, if \( w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{1}^{m}\right) <0\), the first term is negative and therefore, the sign of \(\partial \widetilde{a}^{w}/\partial a\) is ambiguous.

Now, we consider the case where the entrant invests more than the incumbent; the equilibrium coverage are \(z_{1}^{*}=\widetilde{z} _{1}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \) and \(z_{2}^{*}=\widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) \). The social welfare is \(W=\widetilde{ z}_{1}^{c}w^{N,N}+\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}-\widetilde{z}_{1}^{c}\right) w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) +\left( \overline{z}-\widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}\right) w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -C\left( \widetilde{z}_{1}^{c}\right) -C\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \). Assuming an interior solution, the socially optimal access price to fiber solves the first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial W}{\partial \widetilde{a}}&=\frac{d\widetilde{z} _{1}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) }{d\widetilde{a}}\left( w^{N,N}-w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z} _{1}^{c}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) \right) \right) \\&\quad +\frac{\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) }{\partial \widetilde{a}} \left( w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \right) \\&\quad +\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}-\widetilde{z}_{1}^{c}\right) \frac{ dw^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) }{d\widetilde{a}}\equiv H\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) =0\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\widetilde{a}^{w}\) denote the solution of \(H\left( a,\widetilde{a} ^{w}\right) =0\). From the implicit function theorem, provided that the second-order condition holds, the sign of \(\partial \widetilde{a} ^{w}/\partial a\) has the same sign as \(\partial ^{2}W/\partial \widetilde{a} \partial a\). We find that

$$\begin{aligned} \text {sign}\left[ \frac{\partial \widetilde{a}^{w}}{\partial a}\right]&= \text {sign}\left[ \frac{\partial ^{2}W}{\partial \widetilde{a}\partial a} \right] \!=\!\text {sign}\left[ \frac{\partial ^{2}\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a, \widetilde{a}\right) }{\partial \widetilde{a}\partial a}\left( w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}\right) \right) \right. \\&-\frac{\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) }{ \partial \widetilde{a}}\left( \frac{dw^{O,O}\left( a\right) }{da}+\frac{ \partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}}{\partial a}c^{\prime }\left( \widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}\right) \right) +\left. \frac{\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}}{ \partial a}\frac{dw^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) }{d\widetilde{a}}\right] \end{aligned}$$

As \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}/\partial \widetilde{a}\ge 0\), the second term is negative if \(dw^{O,O}\left( a\right) /da+\) \(\partial \widetilde{z} _{2}^{m}/\partial a\times c^{\prime }\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \ge 0 \), and we assume that this is the case (note that \(dw^{O,O}\left( a\right) /da\le 0\), while \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}/\partial a\times c^{\prime }\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \ge 0\)). The third term is always negative as \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}/\partial a\ge 0\) and \( dw^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) /d\widetilde{a}\le 0\). Finally, we find that \(w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \le 0\), as

$$\begin{aligned}&w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \\&\quad =w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -\left( \widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a} \right) -\pi _{2}^{O,O}\left( a\right) \right) \\&\quad =\frac{1}{9}\left[ 5\widetilde{a}\underset{(-)}{\underbrace{\left( \widetilde{a}-\left( 1+s^{N}\right) \right) }}+\underset{(-)}{\underbrace{ \left( 1+s^{O}-2a\right) ^{2}-\left( 1+s^{N}\right) ^{2}}}\right] \le 0\text { .} \end{aligned}$$

The first term of sign\(\left[ \partial \widetilde{a}^{w}/\partial a\right] \) is then positive as

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial ^{2}\widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\left( a,\widetilde{a}\right) }{ \partial \widetilde{a}\partial a}\\&\quad \!=\!\frac{\partial \widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}}{ \partial \widetilde{a}}\frac{\partial \pi _{2}^{O,O}}{\partial a} c^{\prime \prime }\left[ \left( c\right) ^{-1}\left( \widetilde{\pi } _{2}^{N,N}\!-\!\pi _{2}^{O,O}\right) \right] \Big /\left( c^{\prime }\left[ \left( c\right) ^{-1}\left( \widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}-\pi _{2}^{O,O}\right) \right] \right) ^{3}\!\le \! 0\text {,} \end{aligned}$$

since \(\partial \widetilde{\pi }_{2}^{N,N}/\partial \widetilde{a}\ge 0\), \( \partial \pi _{2}^{O,O}/\partial a\le 0\), and \(c^{\prime }\ge 0\), and provided that \(c^{\prime \prime }\ge 0\). Though the sign of \(\partial \widetilde{a} ^{w}/\partial a\) is ambiguous in general, we can have \(\partial \widetilde{a} ^{w}/\partial a\le 0\) when the entrant dominates fiber investments in particular when \(w^{N,N}\left( \widetilde{a}\right) -w^{O,O}\left( a\right) -c\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \) is high enough (provided that \( dw^{O,O}\left( a\right) /da+\) \(\partial \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}/\partial a\times c^{\prime }\left( \widetilde{z}_{2}^{m}\right) \ge 0\) and that the investment cost is convex).

1.8 Appendix H: NGA regulation in selected OECD countries

In the following table we report the current state of regulatory interventions on NGA infrastructures in some selected OECD countries. Different types of both physical or “passive” (access to ducts or to dark fibre) and service-level or “active” (unbundling, bitstream) wholesale broadband remedies are considered. “Yes” means that the wholesale product/service is regulated; “no”, that it is not. The data are drawn from Cullen International (2013), Ovum (2013) as well as from direct interviews with national regulators.Footnote 52

Country

Geographically segmented remedies

Access to

In-building fiber

Fiber Unbundling

Bitstream on FFTH

  

ducts

dark fibre

   

France

National

Yes

No

Yes (sym.)

No

No

Germany

National

Yes

Yes

Yes (sym.)

Yes \(^{\ddag }\)

Yes

Italy

Competitive areas

Yes

Yes

Yes (sym.)

No (VULA)

Yes

 

Non-comp. areas

Yes

Yes

Yes (sym.)

No (VULA)

Yes

Netherlands

National

No

Yes\(^{\lozenge }\)

No

Yes \(^{\ddag }\)

No

Portugal

National

Yes

Yes

Yes (sym.)

No

No

Spain

National

Yes \(^{*}\)

Yes\(^{\lozenge }\)

Yes (sym.)

No

Yes\(^{\dag }\)

UK

Competitive areas

Yes

No

No

No (VULA)

No

 

Non-comp. areas

Yes

No

Yes (sym.)

No (VULA)

Yes

Australia

National

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

Yes

Japan

National

Yes (asym.)

Yes (asym.)

Partially

Yes

No

New Zealand

National

No

Yes \(^{\#}\)

No

Yes \(^{\#}\)

Yes

USA

National

No

No

No

No

No

  1. * Only in urban areas; \(\lozenge \) When access to ducts is not possible; ‡ Only for residential customers; † Only for bandwidth under 30Mbit/s; # Point-to-point fibre only until 2019

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bourreau, M., Cambini, C. & Doğan, P. Access regulation and the transition from copper to fiber networks in telecoms. J Regul Econ 45, 233–258 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-014-9245-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-014-9245-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation