Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Government Behavior on Urban Land Supply: Does it Follow a Prospect Preference?

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the role of the prospect theory preferences in influencing the relationship between performance goals and subsequent performances. We find an inverted-U relationship between the goal of the central government and the performance of local governments in land supply based on China’s land supply data between 2005 and 2013. The higher land supply goals of the central government initially increase and then decrease the land supply by local governments. We further explore the inverted-U relations by considering local governments’ prospect theory preferences theoretically and empirically. Our findings indicate that local governments are goal-dependent and risk-seeking in face of the extraordinarily ambitious goals set by the central government.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The disposition effect refers to that investors prefer to sell stocks that have risen in value since purchase, rather than stocks at a loss relative to purchase price (Barberis, 2013). The endowment effect originally refers to the gap between the willingness to accept and the willingness to pay.

  2. It is a little bit different from the standard prospect theory model, in which the model is developed under certainty in this case. Thaler (1980) argued in his influential paper that the prospect theory is also valuable for riskless choice though it was originally developed as a theory of risky choice.

  3. For example, in Fig. 3a, when n is 0.5 and 1, MBV is always higher than MC, the optimal excess supply rate m equals the upper limit n, and takes the value of 0.5 and 1, respectively. Then n increases to 5, m takes the value of the intersection point, which is higher than 1. Finally, n grows to 10, m takes the value of a new intersection point, which is less than the value when n = 5. That is, m increases with n when n increases from 0.5 to 5, but then decreases with n when n increases from a certain value higher than 5 to 10.

  4. Gender is not considered because there are only two female governors in our sample.

References

  • Atkinson, J. W. (1958). Towards experimental analysis of human motives in terms of motives, expectancies, and incentives. In J. W. Atkinson (Ed.), Motives in fantasy, action, and society (pp. 288–305). New York: Van Nostrand.

  • Barberis, N, C. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(1), 173–195

  • Bellante, D., & Link, A, N. (1981). Are public sector workers more risk averse than private sector workers?. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 34(3), 408–412

  • Bozeman, B., & Kingsley, G. (1998). Risk culture in public and private organizations. Public Administration Review, 109–118, 58

  • Bruhin, A., Fehr-Duda, H., & Epper, T. (2010). Risk and rationality: Uncovering heterogeneity in probability distortion. Econometrica, 78(4), 1375–1412

  • Buurman, M., Delfgaauw, J., Dur, R., & Van den Bossche, S. (2012). Public sector employees: Risk averse and altruistic?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 83(3), 279–291

  • Chen, C, A., & Bozeman, B. (2012). Organizational risk aversion: Comparing the public and non-profit sectors. Public Management Review, 14(3), 377–402

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G, G. (2011). Individual risk attitudes: Measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(3), 522–550

  • Erez, M. (1977). Feedback: A necessary condition for the goal setting-performance relationship. Journal of Applied Psychology, 62(5), 624, 627

  • Erez, M., & Zidon, I. (1984). Effect of goal acceptance on the relationship of goal difficulty to performance. Journal of Applied Psychology, 69(1), 69, 78

  • Feng, L., Bao, H, X., & Jiang, Y. (2014). Land reallocation reform in rural China: A behavioral economics perspective. Land Use Policy, 41, 246–259

  • Garland, H. (1984). Relation of effort-performance expectancy to performance in goal-setting experiments. Journal of Applied Psychology, 69(1), 79, 84

  • Genesove, D., & Mayer, C. (2001). Loss aversion and seller behavior: Evidence from the housing market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(4), 1233–1260

  • Heath, C., Larrick, R, P., & Wu, G. (1999). Goals as reference points. Cognitive Psychology, 38(1), 79–109

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 68(3):263–291

  • Kim, C, H., & Kim, K, H. (2000). The political economy of Korean government policies on real estate. Urban Studies, 37(7), 1157–1169

  • Kleingeld, A., van Mierlo, H., & Arends, L. (2011). The effect of goal setting on group performance: A meta-analysis. Journal of Applied Psychology, 96(6), 1289–1304

  • Levy, J, S. (2003). Applications of prospect theory to political science. Synthese, 135(2), 215–241

  • Li, L, C. (2010). Central-local relations in the People’s republic of China: Trends, processes and impacts for policy implementation. Public Administration and Development, 30(3), 177–190

  • Locke, E, A. & Latham, G, P. (1990). A theory of goal setting and task performance. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall

  • Locke, E, A., & Latham, G, P. (2002). Building a practically useful theory of goal setting and task motivation: A 35-year odyssey. American Psychologist, 57(9), 705, 717

  • Locke, E, A., Shaw, K, N., Saari, L, M., & Latham, G, P. (1981). Goal setting and task performance: 1969–1980. Psychological Bulletin, 90(1), 125, 152

  • McDermott, R. (2004). Prospect theory in political science: Gains and losses from the first decade. Political Psychology, 25(2), 289–312

  • Meng F, Y., & Li C. (2015). Coordination and integration of urban-rural development-analysis on path dependence of China's land policy. China Soft Science, (5), 1–11. (in Chinese)

  • Mercer, J. (2005). Prospect theory and political science. Annual Review of Political Science, 8, 1–21

  • Motowidlo, S, J., Dunnette, M, D., & Loehr, V. (1978). A laboratory study of the effects of goal specificity on the relationship between probability of success and performance. Journal of Applied Psychology, 63(2), 172, 179

  • Rablen, M, D. (2010). Performance targets, effort and risk-taking. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31(4), 687–697

  • Rosen, A, B., Tsai, J, S., & Downs, S, M. (2003). Variations in risk attitude across race, gender, and education. Medical Decision Making, 23(6), 511–517

  • Stedry, A, C., & Kay, E. (1966). The effects of goal difficulty on performance: A field experiment. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 11(6), 459–470

  • Thaler, R. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1(1), 39–60

  • Tian, L., & Ma, W. (2009). Government intervention in city development of China: A tool of land supply. Land Use Policy, 26(3), 599–609

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. Journal of Business, 59(4): S251-S278

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297–323

  • Wedeman, A. (2001). Incompetence, noise, and fear in central-local relations in China. Studies in Comparative International Development, 35(4), 59–83

  • Wilson, R, K. (2011). The contribution of behavioral economics to political science. Annual Review of Political Science, 14, 201–223

  • Wood, R, E., Mento, A, J., & Locke, E, A. (1987). Task complexity as a moderator of goal effects: A meta-analysis. Journal of Applied Psychology, 72(3), 416, 425

  • Wu, F. (2002). China’s changing urban governance in the transition towards a more market-oriented economy. Urban Studies, 39(7), 1071–1093

  • Wu, S., & Yang, Z. (2018). Impacts of land supply planning on local government land supply behaviour: An analysis based on prospect theory. Journal of Tsinghua University, 58(9), 849–857. (in Chinese)

  • Wu, G., Heath, C., & Larrick, R. (2008). A prospect theory model of goal behavior. Unpublished manuscript, University of Chicago

  • Xu, J., & Yeh, A. (2009). Decoding urban land governance: State reconstruction in contemporary Chinese cities. Urban Studies, 46(3), 559–581

  • Yu, J., Xiao, J., & Gong, L. (2015). Political cycle and land leasing: Evidence from Chinese cities. Economic Research Journal. (2), 88–144. (in Chinese)

  • Zhang, Y. (2012). A view from behavioral political economy on China’s institutional change. China Economic Review, 23(4), 991–1002

  • Zhang, L., Gao, Y, H., & Xu, X, X. (2013). Land leasing under the corruption. Management World, (12): 43–51. (in Chinese)

Download references

Acknowledgements

* We highly appreciate the comments by participants in 2017 APRERS. Wu and Yang acknowledge the financial support by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Project No: 72004008, 71673154, 72011530136), and the China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (Project No: 2020 M670120).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zan Yang.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

none.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1 Value function of local governments with prospect theory preferences

Figures 5a and 5b show the value functions for a local government who has the prospect theory preference. Following Wu and Yang (2018), we assume the local performances m are the same in Figs. 5a and 5b, while the central goals n in Fig. 5a is lower than that in Fig. 5b. As we can see, the value increase (∆V) is much bigger in Fig. 5a than that in Fig. 5b.

That is, for local governments with prospect theory preferences, the value increase (∆V) from the better performance (m) is dependent on the target (n). The higher n, the lower marginal value (MBV), as a result of the reference dependence and the sensitivity diminishing.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Value function of local governments. Note: Figs. 5a and 5b are the value functions for local governments who have the prospect theory preference. m are the same in Figs. 5a and 5b, while n in Fig. 5a is smaller than that in Fig. 5b

Appendix 2 Impacts of β and λ on the goal-performance relationship

If local governments follow the prospect theory preferences, the risk seeking degree β would also have impacts on the n − m relationship. As shown in Fig. 6, a negative correlation dominates the relationship when the β value approaches zero, while a positive correlation dominates the relationship when the β value approaches one. There is the possibility to have a monotone positive n − m relationship when the β is extremely high (extremely low degree of risk seeking) and the marginal cost of land supply increasing is relatively low.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Marginal benefits and costs in increasing land supply for local governmnets with prospect theory preferences, simulation of β. Note: According to Tversky and Kahneman (1992), λ=2.25. S0 is normalized to 1

If local governments follow the prospect theory preference, the loss aversion parameter λ would also have impacts on the n − m relationship. As shown in Fig. 7, a negative correlation dominates the relationship when the λ value approaches one, while a positive correlation dominates the relationship when the λ value is high. There is the possibility to have a monotone positive n − m relationship when the λ is extremely high (extremely high degree of loss aversion) and the marginal cost of land supply increasing is relatively low.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Marginal benefits and costs in increasing land supply for local governmnets with prospect theory preferences, simulation of λ. Note: According to Tversky and Kahneman (1992), β=0.88. S0 is normalized to 1

Appendix 3 Impacts of β measured by political cycle on the goal-performance relationship

Table 6 shows the results with β measured by the political cycle, pre _ pcpc and aft _ pcpc. pre _ pcpc is a dummy variable equal to 1 for the preceding year of the provincial communist party congress dummy, and 0 otherwise. aft _ pcpc is a dummy variable equal to 1 for the year after the provincial communist party congress, and 0 otherwise. Political behavior is expected to be more risk averse before the end of an old cycle, and more risk seeking at the beginning of a new cycle, therefore pre _ pcpc indicates lower β and aft _ pcpc suggests higher β.

The inverted-U shape relation is robustly significant after controlling the β parameter measured by the political cycle dummy. Furthermore, as shown in the four bottom rows, when pre _ pcpc value changes from 0 to 1 (in columns 1 and 3), which indicates decreasing β, the symmetric lines in the inverted-U m − n relationship move left. When aft _ pcpc value changes from 0 to 1 (in columns 2 and 4), which indicates increasing β, the symmetric lines in the inverted-U m − n relationship move right. That is, as the theoretical model in Appendix 2 indicates, a negative correlation dominates the m − n relationship when β is low, while a positive correlation dominates the m − n relationship when β is high.

Table 6 Impacts of β measured by political cycle on the goal-performance relationship

Appendix 4 Utility function of local governments with expected utility preferences

Now we consider the condition where local governments follow an expected utility preference. All things are the same except the benefit function. If local governments follow an exponential expected utility preference, the utility improvement ∆U from increasing land supply from S0 to S1 should be ∆U = U(S1) − U(S0) = [(1 + m)S0]θ − (S0)θ. In that case, MBUdecreases with m because θ<1, while MC still increases with m. Therefore, there is one internal solution \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) when MC = MBU. And it is obvious that \( \frac{\partial \left({MB}^U\right)}{\partial n}=0 \) and \( \frac{\partial (MC)}{\partial n}=0 \), which means the central target n has no impact on the marginal utility and the marginal cost, which indicates that \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) has nothing to do with n. That indicates, for local governments that have the expected utility preference, the optimal local performance m is independent of the central target n. That cannot explain the findings in this paper.

It needs to mention that if the \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) is no bigger than n, governments with the expected utility preference have one optimal \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) which is independent of n; but if the \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) is bigger than n, governments with the expected utility preference have the optimal \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) equal to n. We provide a simple simulation for \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) to solve this problem in Fig. 8. As we can see in Fig. 8, the intersected solutions \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) are relatively small, ranging from 0.6 to 0.9 with alternatively different definitions of MC. And that may be an overvalued \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) since lower θ means lower \( {m}_U^{\ast } \), and higher S0 means lower \( {m}_U^{\ast } \). Even if θ equals to its upper limit 1, the \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) is also relatively low. Since the central target n in the national residential land supply plan is relatively high as mentioned in Section 3, it could be expected that \( {m}_U^{\ast } \) is no larger than n, and the optimal local performance is independent of the central target n for local governments with expected utility.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Marginal benefits and costs in increasing land supply for local governments with expected utility preferences. Note: It plots the relationship between MBU and MC if local governments follows the expect utility theory preference. The intersections of MBU and MC are the optimal solutions \( {m}_U^{\ast } \). In the simulation of MBU, S0 is normalized to 1; and according to Tversky and Kahneman (1992), we assume the θ in the utility is also 0.88. In the simulation of MC, since MC > 0, thus we take three different forms of MC to make the MC′′ > 0 (MC = m2), MC′′ = 0 (MC = m), and MC′′ < 0 (MC = m0.4), respectively

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wu, S., Yang, Z. Government Behavior on Urban Land Supply: Does it Follow a Prospect Preference?. J Real Estate Finan Econ 67, 264–286 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-021-09832-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-021-09832-6

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation