Skip to main content
Log in

“Cure” Effects and Mortgage Default: A Split Population Survival Time Model

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using non-agency securitization data consisting of mortgages originated between 1991 and 2007, we find that fraction of defaulted mortgages increases from 10.8% in the pre-crisis period (July 2007) to 19.6% in the post crisis period (July 2009). This paper then applies a split population hazard model, or widely known as a mixture cure model in biometrics literature, to jointly predict incidence (probability) and latency (hazard rate) of mortgage default, and more specifically to analyze the right-tail characteristics of the survival distributions of the sample mortgages. Our results show that negative equity is a highly significant factors driving both default incidence and latency for both adjustable rate mortgages (ARMs) and fixed rate mortgages (FRMs). We also show that borrowers’ credit scores have weaker predictive effects on the latency (survival hazard) risks, but both low FICO and subprime borrowers have higher probability to default in an adverse market condition, ceteris paribus. Borrowers with low credit scores have high default probabilities but with a longer time to default (hazard rate). They are more likely to hang onto their mortgages even if they are “underwater” (negative equity). In terms of the “cured” rate, we show that subprime borrowers with underwater (negative equity) FRM mortgages, and prime ARM borrowers have relatively higher “cured” rates in the mortgage sample. More policy experiments can be conducted using the mixture cure model to test the effectiveness of selected financial assistance programs in the future.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The FHA-HAMP is an effort under the Making Home Affordable (MHA) Program introduced by the US Department of Housing and Urban Development to help distressed homeowners to retain their homes and reduce the impact of foreclosure on families and communities. Details of the program are available: http://www.hud.gov/offices/hsg/sfh/nsc/rep/hampfact.pdf.

  2. They discuss the HAMP and also the Settlement of the Countrywide Financial Corporation in 2008, and their implications on loan modifications for underwater/delinquent homeowners in great details.

  3. In a The New Yorker article “Living by Default,” by Surowiecki James on Decemember 19, 2011, he commented on the double standard on default placed on the corporations and homeowners. The issues of whether it is morally right for borrowers to walk away from negative equity mortgages have been extensively debated in the presses and academic journals.

  4. These numbers were inferred from a set of hypothetical questions they asked the sample respondents participating in the Chicago Booth Kellogg School Financial Trust Index Survey between 2008 and 2010.

  5. There exists another group of defaulters, who are forced by unforeseen non-pecuniary “events”, such as job losses, etc., to exercise the options; even if they are out-of-the-money (Riddiough 1991). These borrowers who default even on positive housing equity positions are idiosyncratic and not within the scope of this study.

  6. The estimate was published by a research team of Morgan Stanley Research comprising Tirupattur, V., Chang, O. and Egan, J. in the ABS Market Insights, “Understanding Strategic Default” on April 29, 2010,

  7. The numbers were reported by the Experian-Oliver Wyman Market Intelligence Reports, “Strategic Default in Mortgages: Q2 2011 update”, which is available at http://www.marketintelligencereports.com. The study reported that strategic defaulters have nearly doubled from 11% in 2Q2007 to 20% in 4Q2008.

  8. See references such as Sy and Taylor (2000); Ibrahim et al. (2001); and others.

  9. In criminology literature, recidivism is defined as the return to criminal activities by ex-convicts (recidivists). The recidivism is observed only when recidivists are arrested and returned to the prison.

  10. For the competing risk model analyses, we also compute another the two indicators (“status_l” and “survdur_l”) for the left-censored sample using the July 2007 cutoff date.

  11. A dummy variable “ARM”, which has a value of 1 for an adjusted rate mortgage (ARM) type; and otherwise, the value is 0 for a fixed rate mortgage (FRM).

  12. FICO score developed by the Fair Isaac Corporation is widely used by lenders as an ex-post credit risk indicator. FICO score is used as a predictive variable in hazard regressions (Danis and Pennington-Cross 2005; Pennington-Cross and Nichols 2000; Pennington-Cross et al. 2000).

  13. As the current market value is not available in the data, we derive the current market value, “CURMKV”, by adjusting the original housing value, “ORGVAL”, using a simple growth rate, (Pt/Po), between the mortgage origination time of t = 0 and the event occurrence time t, using the S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price (Composite 10) index, Pt. The original house value, “ORGVAL”, is defined as the loan principal divided by the original LTV.

  14. As a policy experiment, it will be challenging to identify those who are “cured” (i.e non-defaulters) and those who “failed” under the government’s assistance schemes. However, due to data limitations, we are not able to identify those distressed borrowers who have been put under various government’s assistance schemes.

  15. We could convert the log-hazard estimates of the Weibull model by dividing the coefficients by the negative scale estimate, and then take the exponential term for the results; and we would get the hazard ratio estimates that are close to the PH estimates.

  16. The estimates for the covariate are not reported due to space constraint.

  17. We thank Corbiere and Joly (2007) for sharing the SAS macro programs for the estimation of the mixture cure models.

References

  • Ambrose, B. W., & LaCour-Little, M. (2001). Prepayment risk in adjustable rate Mortgaes subject to initial year discount: some new evidence. Real Estate Economics, 29(2), 305–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • An, M. Y., & Qi, Z. (2012). Competing risk models using mortgage duration data under the proportional hazards assumption. Journal of Real Estate Research, 34(1), 2–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bajari, P., Chu, C. S., & Park, M. (2008). An empirical model of subprime mortgage default from 2000 to 2007. NBER Working Paper.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Calhoun, C., & Deng, Y. (2002). A dynamic analysis of adjustable- and fixed-rate mortgage termination. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 24(1), 9–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciochetti, B. A., Gao, B., Deng, Y., & Yao, R. (2002). The termination of commercial Mortgge contracts through prepayment and default: a proportional hazard approach with competing risks. Real Estate Economics, 30(4), 595–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corbiere, F., & Joly, P. (2007). A SAS macro for parametric and semiparametric mixture cure models. Computer Methods and Programs in Biomedicine, 85(2), 173–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, D. R. (1972). Regression models and life-tables. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B (Methodological), 34(2), 187–220.

  • Danis, M., & Pennington-Cross, A. (2005). A dynamic look at subprime loan performance. The Journal of Fixed Income, 15(1), 28–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demyanyk, Y., & Van Hemert, O. (2011). Understanding the subprime mortgage crisis. Review of Financial Studies, 24(6), 1848–1880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Y. (1997). Mortgage termination: an empirical hazard model with a stochastic term structure. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 14(3), 309–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Y., & Gabriel, S. (2006). Risk-based pricing and the enhancement of mortgage credit availability among underserved and higher credit-risk populations. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38(6), 1431–1460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Y., & Quigley, J. M. (2009). Irrational borrowers and the pricing of residential mortgages. Working Paper: Institute of Real Estate Studies, National University of Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Y., Quigley, J. M., & Van Order, R. (2000). Mortgage terminations, heterogeneity and the exercise of mortgage options. Econometrica, 68, 275–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foote, C. L., Gerardi, K., & Willen, P. S. (2008). Negative equity and foreclosure: theory and evidence. Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 234–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghent, A. C., & Kudlyak, M. (2011). Recourse and residential mortgage default: Evidence from US states. Review of Financial Studies, 24(9), 3139–3186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, L. S., Ashworth, R., Landy, B., & Yin, K. (2010). Negative equity trumps unemployment in predicting defaults. The Journal of Fixed Income, 19(4), 67–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2013). The determinants of attitudes towards strategic default on mortgage. Journal of Finance, 68(4), 1473–1515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haughwout, A., Peach, R., & Tracy, J. (2008). Juvenile delinquent mortgages: Bad credit or bad economy? Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 246–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibrahim, J. G., Chen, M., & Sinha, D. (2001). Bayesian semiparametric models for survival data with a cure fraction. Biometrics, 57, 383–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagtiani, J., & Lang, W. W. (2010). Strategic default on first and second Lien mortgages during the financial crisis. Working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J. B., & Keenan, D. (1995). An overview of the option-theoretic pricing of mortgages. Journal of Housing Research, 6(2), 217–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J. B., Keenan, D. C., & Kim, T. (1993). Transaction costs, suboptimal termination and default probabilities. Journal of American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 21(3), 247–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J. B., Keenan, D. C., & Kim, T. (1994). Default probabilities for mortgages. Journal of Urban Economics, 35, 278–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Key, B. J., Mukherjee, T., Seru, A., & Vig, V. (2010). Did securitization lead to lax screening? Evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, 307–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehnert, A., & Passmore, W. (2006). Comment on: an options-based approach to evaluating the risk of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(1), 177–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, C., Morrison, E., Piskorski, T., & Gupta, A. (2011). Mortgage modification and strategic default: evidence from a legal settlement with countrywide. Columbia Business School: Working paper.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pennington-Cross, A., & Nichols, J. (2000). Credit history and the FHA-conventional choice. Real Estate Economics, 28(2), 307–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pennington-Cross, A., Yezer, A. M., & Nichols, J. (2000). Credit Risk and Mortgage Lending: Who Uses nonprime and Why? Research Institute for Housing America, working paper 00–03.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riddiough, T. J. (1991). Equilibrium mortgage default pricing with non-optimal borrower behavior. Ph.D. dissertation: University of Wisconsin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, P., & Witte, A. D. (1989). Predicting criminal recidivism using ‘split population’ survival time models. Journal of Econometrics, 40, 141–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sy, J., & Taylor, J. M. G. (2000). Estimation in a cox proportional hazards cure model. Biometrics, 56, 227–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandell, K. (1995). How ruthless is mortgage default? A review and synthesis of evidence. Journal of Housing Research, 6(2), 245–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, B. T. (2009). Underwater and Not Walking Away: Shame, Fear and Social Management of the Housing Crisis. Arizona Legal Studies, Discussion paper No. 90–35, the University of Arizona.

  • White, B. T. (2010). The morality of strategic default. UCLA Law Review Discourse, 58, 155–164.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Sumit Agarwal, Yongheng Deng, Timothy Riddiough, James Shilling and Shih-Ti Yu for comments and suggestions on the earlier version of the paper. We would also like to thank Long Wang for capable and efficient research assistance. Errors, if any, remain the responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tien Foo Sing.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, B., Sing, T.F. “Cure” Effects and Mortgage Default: A Split Population Survival Time Model. J Real Estate Finan Econ 56, 217–251 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-017-9597-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-017-9597-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation