Skip to main content
Log in

The Transitory and Legacy Effects of the Rental Externality on House Price and Liquidity

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is widely believed that tenant-occupied houses do not show as well as owner-occupied or even vacant units and so are harder to sell. These short term or transitory marketing effects should disappear in subsequent sales by owner-occupiers. Overuse by tenants and poor maintenance by landlords, however may lead to longer term or legacy effects on value and liquidity. We use a 20 year data series on house transactions to estimate these separate effects in a simultaneous model of price and liquidity. The results reveal strong transitory renter effects on both value and liquidity consistent with lower buyer willingness-to-pay. We do not find persistent legacy effects from prior use as rental property. Instead, there appears to be unmeasured quality or a characteristic common to houses suitable for rent that leads to permanently lower market values regardless of previous use in that capacity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Lippman and McCall (1976) provide a seminal influence on search models of housing markets. See Arnott (1989), Haurin (1988), Krainer (2001), Williams (1995), and Wheaton (1990) for a variety of approaches grounded in search or matching environments.

  2. The arrival rate and buyer offer distribution are assumed stationary during the exposure of a given house to the market, which implies that the seller’s optimal reservation price strategy s is also stationary. Over the longer term, of course, both the arrival rate and buyer offer distribution will change as housing demand changes over the market cycle, leading other sellers to adopt different reservation prices in response to the prevailing conditions during the period in which they have their properties on the market.

  3. The new curve will not in general have the same slope or curvature as the original.

  4. The AHS provides information about owners as well as house characteristics. House prices are self-reported by survey participants. It does not provide observed transactions prices or selling time and the confidentiality restrictions mask the intra-urban area location characteristics of the properties included in the survey.

  5. Changes in holding cost per period, h, do not change the utility function; instead, changes in h change the indifference curve map portrayed in E[P], E[τ] space. Recall that sellers care about expected price and expected holding cost. The change in indifference curve shape considered here comes into play because we are looking at the indifference curves in E[P], E[τ] space and not E[P], E[hτ] space over which the primitive preferences represented by the utility function are defined. The shape of the indifference curves in E[P], E[hτ] space remains unaltered by changes in h.

  6. It can be shown that this relationship holds under the assumption that expected price and liquidity (shorter selling time) are normal goods as defined in standard consumer demand theory.

  7. This also means that houses in the sample have a window of exposure of four years or more for rental. This is intended to reduce spurious correlation between house age and rental status, since very new houses have a limited time frame for being observed as rental units while old houses have the entire 20 year time frame of the data period to be observed as rental units.

  8. This screen removes houses that have no porches, carports, or soffit overhang (eves)—an unusual configuration in the price range included in the sample.

  9. Full model estimates for these tables are in an appendix available by request.

  10. Only 69 houses in the $185,000–$320,000 price range were ever tenant-occupied over the twenty year period, which is about 6% of the entire number of houses that were ever renter occupied during the sample period.

References

  • Arnott, R. (1989). Housing Vacancies, Thin Markets, and Idiosyncratic Tastes. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2, 5–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asabere, P. K., & Huffman, F. E. (1993). The Impact of Settlement Period on Sales Price. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 7, 213–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belkin, J., Hempel, D. J., & McLeavey, D. W. (1976). An empirical study of time on market using multidimensional segmentation of housing markets. AREUEA Journal, 4, 57–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, B., & Ford, E. J. (1975). Concentration of rental housing property and rental housing markets in urban areas. AREUEA Journal, 3, 7–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clauretie, T. M., & Wolverton, M. L. (2006). Vacant or rent: the optimal decision for absentee home sellers. Journal of Real Estate Research, 28, 25–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eberts, R. W., & Gronberg, T. J. (1982). Wage gradients, rent gradients, and the price elasticity of demand for housing: an empirical investigation. Journal of Urban Economics, 12, 168–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edel, M., & Sclar, E. (1974). Taxes, spending, property value: supply adjustment in a Tiebout-Oates model. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 941–954.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forgey, F. A., Rutherford, R. C., & Springer, T. M. (1996). Search and liquidity in single-family housing. Real Estate Economics, 24, 273–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harding, J. P., Knight, J. R., & Sirmans, C. F. (2003). Estimating bargaining effects in hedonic models: evidence from the housing market. Real Estate Economics, 31, 601–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haurin, D. (1988). The duration of marketing time of residential housing. AREUEA Journal, 16, 396–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J., & Palmquist, R. B. (2001). Environmental conditions, reservation prices, and time on the market for housing. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22, 203–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwata, S., & Yamaga, H. (2008). Rental externality, tenure security, and housing quality. Journal of Housing Economics, 17, 201–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, H. B., & Gardner, M. J. (1989). Selling price and marketing time in the residential real estate market. Journal of Real Estate Research, 4, 21–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J. R. (2002). Listing price, time on the market, and ultimate selling price: causes and effects of listing price changes. Real Estate Economics, 30, 213–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krainer, J. (2001). A theory of liquidity in residential real estate markets. Journal of Urban Economics, 49, 32–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krumm, R. J. (1980). Neighborhood amenities: an economic analysis. Journal of Urban Economics, 7, 208–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, L., & Kern, C. R. (1987). The cost of quality in existing housing: estimates from an implicit markets model. Journal of Urban Economics, 22, 324–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lippman, S. A., & McCall, J. J. (1976). The economics of job search: a survey. Economic Inquiry, 14, 155–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, N. S. (1981). Rehabilitation decisions in rental housing: an empirical analysis. Journal of Urban Economics, 10, 76–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, N. S. (1985). The impacts of lending, race, and ownership on rental housing rehabilitation. Journal of Urban Economics, 17, 349–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. G. (1978). Time on the market and selling price. Real Estate Economics, 6, 164–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munneke, H. J., & Slawson, V. C., Jr. (1999). A housing price model with endogenous externality location: a study of mobile home parks. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 19, 113–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudel, T. K. (1987). Housing price inflation, family growth, and the move from rented to owner occupied housing. Urban Studies, 24, 258–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2001). The impacts of contract type on broker performance. Real Estate Economics, 29, 389–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shilling, J. D., Sirmans, C. F., & Dombrow, J. F. (1991). Measuring depreciation in single-family rental and owner-occupied housing. Journal of Housing Economics, 1, 368–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, C. F., Turnbull, G. K., & Benjamin, J. D. (1991). The markets for housing and real estate broker services. Journal of Housing Economics, 1, 207–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, C. F., Turnbull, G. K., & Dombrow, J. (1997). Residential development, risk, and land prices. Journal of Regional Science, 37, 613–628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Springer, T. M. (1996). Single-family housing transactions: seller motivations, price, and marketing time. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 13, 237–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Struyk, R. J., & Lynn, R. (1984). Determinants of housing investment in slum areas: Tondo and other Locations in Metro Manila. Land Economics, 59, 444–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stull, W. J. (1975). Community environment, zoning, and the market value of single family homes. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 535–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1978). A note on the value of crime control: evidence from the property market. Journal of Urban Economics, 5, 137–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G. K., & Dombrow, J. (2006). Spatial competition and shopping externalities: evidence from the housing market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 32, 391–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G.K., and V. Zahirovic-Herbert. 2011. Why Do Vacant Houses Sell for Less: Holding Cost, Bargaining Power, or Stigma? Real Estate Economics. 39, forthcoming

  • Turnbull, G. K., Dombrow, J., & Sirmans, C. F. (2006). Big house, little house: relative size and value. Real Estate Economics, 34, 439–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, K., Grissom, T. V., Webb, J. R., & Spellman, L. (1991). The impact of rental properties on the value of single-family residences. Journal of Urban Economics, 30, 152–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wheaton, W. C. (1990). Vacancy, search, and prices in a housing market matching model. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1270–1292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitehead, C. M. E., & Keigman, M. (1985). The private rented sector: a characteristics approach. Urban Studies, 22, 507–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, J. T. (1995). Pricing real assets with costly search. Review of Financial Studies, 8, 55–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yavas, A., & Yang, S. (1995). The strategic role of listing price in marketing real estate: theory and evidence. Real Estate Economics, 23, 347–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zahirovic-Herbert, V. (2008). A STATA program for calculating neighborhood market conditions. URAG Working Paper No. 802, http://aysps.gsu.edu/urag

  • Zahirovic-Herbert, V., & Turnbull, G. K. (2008). School quality, house prices and liquidity. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 37, 113–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors thank, without implicating, an anonymous referee for helpful comments. This paper received the 2009 ARES Award for Best Paper in Innovative Thinking.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Velma Zahirovic-Herbert.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Turnbull, G.K., Zahirovic-Herbert, V. The Transitory and Legacy Effects of the Rental Externality on House Price and Liquidity. J Real Estate Finan Econ 44, 275–297 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-010-9235-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-010-9235-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation